Manufacturing and Inclusive Growth: The Experience in the Rest of the World. 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Manufacturing and Inclusive Growth: The Experience in the Rest of the World. 1"

Transcription

1 Manufacturing and Inclusive Growth: The Experience in the Rest of the World. 1 By Robert Z Lawrence Albert L Williams Professor Harvard Kennedy School, Senior Fellow Peterson Institute for International Economics & Senior Fellow Mastercard Center for Inclusive Growth and Danial Lashkari Harvard University. 1 Support from the MasterCard Center for Inclusive Growth for this research is gratefully acknowledged. This is the second phase report on our project on the global role of manufacturing in inclusive growth. The first phase examined the US experience. 1

2 Overview. This report describes some of the results from the second phase of the research project on the role of manufacturing in inclusive growth. The first phase of the project examined the US experience. In the second phase, undertaken by Robert Lawrence and Danial Lashkari a graduate student in the Harvard Department of Economics, the scope of the analysis has broadened to explore the experience of manufacturing employment growth in the rest of the world. The first section of this report looks at the experience in other advanced economies. We find that all of today s industrial countries are experiencing declines in the share of manufacturing employment that are similar in their percentage declines to that experienced by the United States between 1973 and The explanation for this deindustrialization in these advanced economies is similar to that in the United States. Two forces are in operation. The first is that at higher incomes, consumers allocate increasing shares of their expenditures to purchase services. The second is that as a result of relatively rapid technological change, the prices of manufactured goods have declined relative to services, but the response of consumers to these lower prices is relatively small i.e. inelastic. The combination of these low income and price elasticities has led the share of consumption spending on goods to decline and the share of employment to follow. While international trade has played a role in some countries in leading to higher levels of manufacturing employment in countries with trade surpluses in manufacturing, and somewhat lower levels in countries with trade deficits -- the impact of trade balances has not offset the underlying forces of rapid technological change combined with low income and price elasticities. Thus regardless of whether they have trade deficits or surpluses in manufactured goods, the percentage declines in manufacturing employment in industrial countries have been quite similar. Since the percentage of workers in the agricultural sector is small, the analysis of recent deindustrialization in developed countries can ignore the sector, but developments in agriculture are part of the explanation for the humped shaped relationship that 2

3 characterizes the relationship between manufacturing employment and per capita income growth in less advanced countries. For understanding the behavior of this share, it is necessary, therefore to use a three-sector model, i.e., one that includes agriculture, manufacturing and services. In the initial phases of development, the share of agriculture declines and the shares of manufacturing and services both grow. As the economy becomes richer it reallocates labor away from agriculture to both manufacturing and services. However, over time the size of the agricultural sector diminishes and thus the magnitude of this source of growth for manufacturing and services diminishes. At the same time, however, the share of employment in services continues to grow relative to manufacturing. Thus, boosted by inflows from agriculture, manufacturing s share initially grows, but later contracts as the gains from agriculture are more than offset by the shift from manufacturing to services. It is noteworthy that the relationship between this humped effect and per capita incomes has shifted over time. In particular it appears that compared with the industrial countries, countries that have industrialized later, especially outside of Asia, have experienced their peak in manufacturing employment at lower levels of income. Moreover, the peak share of manufacturing employment has been lower and the rate of growth of these has also economies has been slower than early industrializers. This early deindustrialization (sometimes called premature deindustrialization ) has major implications for the achievement of inclusive growth because it diminishes the role that manufacturing can play both as a source of employment and income opportunities for relatively less educated workers as well as a generator of economic growth. Our analysis of this process indicates that the ability of a country to experience a deep process of industrialization crucially hinges on its ability to go through a very fast transition out of agriculture and into manufacturing. Since services constantly draw workers out of both agriculture and manufacturing, the manufacturing sector has a short window of opportunity for deepening. We find that the key factor explaining the early deindustrialization among developing countries may be their relatively slow reallocation of workers from agriculture to manufacturing. If the industrialization process happens too 3

4 slowly, most of the migration from agriculture moves into, and remains in, services employment. Thus manufacturing loses the chance to constitute a sizable share of the economy. Having identified the importance of this rapid transition our research has now begun to try to explain it. Our first efforts have eliminated the most straightforward explanation. We have explored the simplest mechanisms that can deliver the humped relationship between the share of manufacturing employment and growth by considering an economy in which the size of international trade is not large enough to significantly alter the sectoral composition of employment. Without trade, employment in each sector would be determined by the size of domestic demand for goods produced by that sector and the productivity of that sector. We find however that the standard forces of price and income elasticity alone are not able to rationalize early deindustrialization. In further research, therefore, we will explore alternative explanations for the more sluggish recent transition from agriculture to manufacturing. One possibility is that today s late developing countries face more challenges in promoting export led-growth and in competing with manufactured goods imports because East Asian countries such as China have now made the markets for these products more competitive and difficult to enter. A second possibility is that at any given level of income today, the manufacturing technologies used by developing countries may require fewer inputs per unit of output and thus relatively less labor per unit of output than before. In addition, more modern technologies may also require workers that are more highly skilled. A third possibility is, whether slow growth itself associated with low shares of investment in GDP and thus less demand for industrial equipment and construction could also be part of the explanation. We intend to systematically investigate each of these possibilities in order to explain early deindustrialization and then to able to draw policy implications. In what follows, in this report we present our initial findings in greater depth. The report contains five sections. In Section 1 we provide a brief review of the literature on structural change; in Section 2 we discuss deindustrialization in advanced countries besides the 4

5 United States. In section 3 we present evidence that demonstrates how deindustrialization in poorer countries has taken place with lower employment shares, lower per capita incomes and slower income growth. In section 4 we then highlight the key role played by the pace of the shift from agriculture to manufacturing in the deindustrialization process. In section 5 we report on the inability of the simple closed economy structural model to account for early deindustrialization and outline our ideas for further research. Finally, in Section 6 we lay out our plan for the future work on this topic. Section 1: A Brief Review of the Literature. The hump-shaped evolution of manufacturing is part of a broader set of structural transformations that mark the process of economic growth, namely, a continuous decline in the economy-share of agriculture and a corresponding rise in services. The study of these transformations have a long history in economics and go back to the decades following World War II (Kuznets 1973). For the simple reason that the deindustrialization in developing countries did not begin until the last few decades, the earlier literature mainly focused on the study of the evolution of manufacturing shares in richer countries (for a recent review of this literature, see (Herrendorf, Rogerson, and Valentinyi 2014)). At this earlier stage of deindustrialization, the scale of world trade had not reached the levels that could reasonably explain the magnitude of structural transformations observed in the sectoral shares of output and employment. Moreover, the majority of this trade occurred among developed countries exchanging different varieties of products, as they were simultaneously going through similar patterns of structural change. Therefore, a general consensus emerged that domestic forces of supply and demand were the key to the earlier trend toward deindustrialization (see, e.g., (Rowthorn and Ramaswamy 1999) and the references therein). The main supply-side force that can drive structural transformation is heterogeneity in sectoral rates of technical growth. Empirical estimates for the rates of productivity growth significantly vary across sectors (Martin and Mitra 2001; Nordhaus 2008; Duarte and Restuccia 2010). If sectoral demand is not very responsive to lower prices (i.e., is inelastic) 5

6 fast productivity growth (and the ensuing fall in prices) in a given sector can result in declining shares of spending and employment in that sector. Since productivity growth in manufacturing has historically exceeded that in the service sector, we can use this channel to explain the declining share of manufacturing in rich countries with high productivity manufacturing sectors (Ngai and Pissarides 2007). This phenomenon is often referred to as the Baumol s disease, whereby economic activity shifts from industries with faster productivity growth into more stagnating ones (Baumol 1967). An alternative view of structural transformation focuses on demand-driven forces in explaining the shift away from manufacturing. Economists have long studies systematic variations in the sectoral composition of demand as a function of income through the concept of Engel curves. Typically, income elasticities are higher for services compared to manufacturing products. Therefore, one can use Engel curves as a way to explain the shift of consumer spending from manufacturing into services, which can be observed both in real and nominal terms (Kongsamut, Rebelo, and Xie 2001; Foellmi and Zweimüller 2008; Boppart 2014; Comin, Lashkari, and Mestieri 2015). The recent rise in globalization has further impacted the dynamics of employment shares through patterns of international specialization. Such forces may be stronger for smaller developing countries that cannot plausibly influence world prices and practically act as price takers in world markets. Theory suggests that by disentangling domestic technical growth from domestic demand, international trade can create patterns of structural change distinct from the ones already discussed (Ventura 2005; Matsuyama 2009). Recent studies of the evolution of industrialization have documented much heterogeneity in patterns observed across a wide array of developing countries, attributing them to differential responses to trade. 2 2 Several recent studies have investigated the sectoral impact of international trade on manufacturing employment using micro level data. For instance, (Utar and Ruiz 2013) studies the effect of Chinese competition on Mexican manufacturing plants, while (Menezes-Filho and 6

7 A recent line of work has focused attention on deindustrialization across developing countries, documenting pronounced trends toward earlier deindustrialization in recent decades (Dasgupta and Singh 2006). Providing a theory for this so-called premature deindustrialization, Rodrik (2015) has argues for the existence of a fundamental divergence in the mechanisms shaping deindustrialization between developing and developed countries. He focuses on a supply-driven account of structural transformation as the core driver in the earlier phases of deindustrialization in richer countries, whereby the decline of manufacturing stems from the faster productivity growth in this sector relative to the competing service sectors. Since the demand for services is price-inelastic, the resulting rise in the relative price of services results in a rise in the share of expenditures (and therefore employment) for services and a corresponding fall for manufacturing. Rodrik (2015) points out that in a world interconnected by trade, a rise in the productivity of manufacturing in a small developing nation does not influence world prices. Rather, it can improve its comparative advantage in this sector, drawing in workers from other sectors to help sustain increasing exports to foreign markets. He suggests the possibility that deindustrialization may have been imported through globalization, but the exact nature of this channel remains unexplained. Section 2: Evidence from Advanced Economies. Much of the discussion about deindustrialization in the United States focuses on policies and practices that are specifically American, with the presumption that had these been different, the United States might have avoided the shrinking share of manufacturing employment. It is useful therefore to compare the US experience with that of other industrial countries. This exercise shows that the US is by no means unique. Declining Muendler 2011) study the impact of tariff cuts on manufacturing employment in Brazil. The recent rise in the volume of Chinese exports have been large enough to have some impacts on the manufacturing employment in the US and other European countries (for micro level studies, see (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson 2013; Pierce and Schott 2012)). 7

8 employment shares in manufacturing and declining share of spending goods in overall consumption are evident in all major industrial countries. In 2010 the US employment share in manufacturing was actually quite typical of an industrial country. It was the same as in Canada (10.3), and the Netherlands (10.6), somewhat higher than Australia (8.9), and lower than Sweden (12.7) and France (13.1). The US decline in the share of manufacturing employment over the period was also quite typical. All major industrial countries experienced declines between 1973 and As shown in Table 1, these were typically on the order of 15 percentage points. Table 1: Share of employment in manufacturing (percent) Country Change (1) (2) (3) (3) - (1) United States Canada Australia Japan France Germany Italy Netherlands United Kingdom Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. Average Change It is also noteworthy as reported in Table 2 as an average of GDP, several of these countries have run large trade surpluses in their manufacturing trade. In 2010 these include Germany (9.9 percent of GDP), Japan (6.45) and the Netherlands (5.52). Their surpluses do help explain why countries like Germany and Japan have had high manufacturing employment shares. But it is striking that the surpluses have not mitigated these countries declining trends in the manufacturing employment share. These data underscore our argument in the previous section that while reducing the US deficit in manufactured goods could deliver a one-time boost to manufacturing employment, it would not permanently alter the declining trend in the manufacturing employment share. 8

9 Table 2: Manufacturing Trade Balance as Share of GDP Ave rage Australia Canada De nmark France Ge rmany Italy Japan Ne the rland Kore a UK USA Source: UN Statistics; World Bank GDP Data We have also gathered data on the share of overall consumption that is spent on goods in a number of OECD countries. In the US in which consumption spending accounts for about three quarters of overall spending on goods, between 1970 and 2010, the share of goods in consumption fell from a half to just over a third -- implying an annual average decline in the share of 0.42 percent. As shown in the Table 3 below this is almost exactly equal to the average annual decline in the overall sample. While the pace of the US decline has been quite similar to that in other countries, the share of goods in US expenditure is also the lowest in the sample. 9

10 Table 3 Share of Consumption Spending on Goods in Total Consumption (%) Annual Change Australia Canada Denmark France Italy Korea Netherlands UK USA Average Source: OECD National Income Accounts. The international experience in other industrial countries is therefore consistent with the conclusions we have drawn with respect to the United States. Relatively faster productivity growth in the production of manufactured goods has led to declining relative goods prices. In response, however, consumers have chosen to devote more of the money they save to the purchase of services. In addition, richer people have a lower propensity to purchase goods as opposed to services. The result has declining shares of expenditure and employment in the production of goods. Larger trade surpluses or smaller trade deficits are associated with larger shares of manufacturing employment, but over the long run do not change the impact of the forces driving down the overall employment share in manufacturing. 10

11 Figure 1 Section 3: Deindustrialization across the Developing World Figure 1 shows the evolution of the share of manufacturing in the total market economy employment as a function of per capita income for a number of high, middle, and lowincome countries. 3 As we can see, the dynamics of the employment share of manufacturing 3 Since our focus is on the long-run trends, we apply a Hodrick-Prescott filter with λ = 100 to the logarithm of each variable, and use the filtered data for all our analyses. We then find the maximum employment share in each country in the smoothed data to minimize the effect of business cycles and outlier observations. We then use the time series of the employment share in each country to identify and exclude all countries whose employment share in manufacturing either has not yet peaked, or has peaked before beginning of the dataset. We use USA as the reference country. 11

12 in a typical country has a hump-shape pattern. The industrialization process initially results in the rise of the manufacturing share. As income continues to grow, the share of manufacturing in most countries first plateaus and then begins to fall. 4 Figure 2 illustrates how this pattern is not limited to employment, and appears in another measures of the size of the manufacturing sector, the production value added. 5 This rise-and-fall pattern for manufacturing has long been known as an essential component of economic growth (Kuznets 1973). Figure 2 4 Note that the peak of the manufacturing sector in the US happens right around the beginning of the data in We use other sources of data to determine this peak (Buera and Kaboski 2009). 5 In this paper, we focus our attention on employment as the leading measure of the size of each sector, but most of the results remain intact if we perform the analyses reported here on production value added. 12

13 We can also see in Figure 1 and Figure 2 that countries show some degree of heterogeneity in terms of the maximum size of their manufacturing sector and the level of income in which they reach this maximum size. In addition, we note that not every country necessarily follows this exact pattern. While economic and political turmoil in some countries such as Argentina and Nigeria have resulted in major deviations from the standard hump-shape, other countries like China have managed to sustain a high share of their economic activity manufacturing for a long time. Figure 3 Figure 3 presents a key regularity observed in the cross-country variations in the evolution of the manufacturing sector, namely, a trend toward deindustrialization at lower levels of income. The figure focuses on the set of countries for which we observe a peak in the share of manufacturing and we have available data in It shows the income of each country at the point in time that they reached the peak of their manufacturing on the y-axis and 13

14 their income in 1950 on the x-axis (the year in which, roughly speaking, the US reached its peak of manufacturing size). 6 It shows that the countries that were poorer in the 1950 cross section achieve the peak of their manufacturing sector at lower levels of income relative to the point at which the US peaked its share of manufacturing. 7 Error! Reference source not found. shows this relationship with respect to the 1970 cross section, for which we have data available from a broader set of countries. Again, a strong positive relationship between the income in the cross section and income at the peak of the share of manufacturing sector exists here. 6 Ideally, we should have chosen the cross section of income in the year in which the US has peaked its share of manufacturing (which is 1948 according to our calculation). Unfortunately, we do not have data for most development countries that goes that far back in time, and therefore, we choose the 1950 cross section, a year for which the data provides broader coverage. 7 We emphasize that this pattern is robust with respect to the measure we use to determine the peak of the share of manufacturing. Using value added produces a very similar relationship. 14

15 Figure 4 Figure 5 shows the highest share of the manufacturing sector reached by each country, again as a function of their relative income in the 1970 cross section. Although the relationship is weaker here, we still observe a negative relationship between the cross section of income and the peak share of manufacturing in total employment. Thus, countries that are poorer in 1970 not only reach their peak at lower levels of income, but they also begin the process of deindustrialization at lower levels of industrial penetration into the labor force. It is the combination of these two facts that has come to be referred to as premature deindustrialization in developing countries (Lawrence and Edwards 2013; Rodrik 2015). The idea is that if all countries were following an identical path of development, we would expect the relationship between the industrializationdeindustrialization process and the country s income to remain intact over time. The trends observed here suggest that, in so far as we are concerned with the role of manufacturing, the trajectories of development evolve over time. 15

16 Error! Reference source not found. and Error! Reference source not found. starkly illustrate why the industrial penetration matters for countries. They show a strong relationship between the maximum size of the manufacturing sector, on the one hand, and the income of the country in both level and growth terms, on the other. These figures suggest that historical data indeed corroborates the view, widely held among policy makers and commentators concerned with growth, that early deindustrialization might be detrimental to development. Figure 5 16

17 Figure 6 Figure 7 17

18 Section 4: A 3-Sector Framework for Understanding Deindustrialization We now turn to exploring potential determinants of the patterns we observed in the previous section. To this end, we will consider the evolution of manufacturing and income in the context of broader structural transformations that countries experience along the process of development. In particular, as we discussed in the introduction, the process of industrialization and deindustrialization is commonly rationalized in a 3-sector framework: the industrialization and deindustrialization phases involve movement of labor from agriculture into manufacturing, and out of manufacturing into services, respectively. Therefore, we will first study how the combination of these two forces determines the timing of deindustrialization in a given country. Figure 8 18

19 For the same group of 16 countries we saw in Figure 1, Error! Reference source not found. and Figure 9 show the trends in the size of employment in agriculture and services, respectively, both relative to the manufacturing size of employment. Error! Reference source not found. shows that the size of employment relative to agriculture almost universally falls throughout the second half of the twentieth century. Roughly speaking, we can interpret this trend as the rate at which the relative size of manufacturing grows relative to agriculture by drawing workers from that sector. 8 The downward trend is the strongest among countries that have experienced very fast episodes of industrialization, countries like Mauritius or East Asian countries such as Korea and Taiwan. While we might find more exceptions in Figure 9, the trends here also appear common across most countries: employment in services grows relative to that in manufacturing. In other words, a net growth in the size of services relative to manufacturing over time characterizes the evolution of sectors at all levels of income. The major exceptions are temporary periods in countries such as Korea, Mauritius, or more recently Kenya, where the economy experiences an accelerated industrialization. 9 8 Of course, these size trends do not have to involve direct movement of workers from agriculture into manufacturing. For instance, one can imagine a situation whereby the relative shrinking of agriculture is solely driven by a trend out of agriculture into services that is faster relative to a parallel trend out of manufacturing, without a direct agriculturemanufacturing flow of workers. However, the statement made here still holds in net terms. In addition, our interpretation is broadly reflective of a large body of work documenting the migration of rural agricultural workers into urban centers of manufacturing plants, as countries industrialize. 9 In the original unsmoothed data, a regression of the logarithm of relative employment in the two sectors on time, accounting for a constant effect for each country, gives an estimate of for agriculture, and for services. The robust standard errors for the estimates for agriculture and services are and 0.001, respectively, where the errors are clustered at the country level. 19

20 We rely on our observations in Error! Reference source not found. and Figure 9 to derive predictions about when a country begins to deindustrialize. If at all levels of income, the employment in services grows relative to manufacturing and that of agriculture falls, how would the evolution of the share of manufacturing look like along the path of development? Early in the process, when the employment share of agriculture is large, employment gains of manufacturing relative to agriculture (resulting form the movement of labor from agriculture to manufacturing) is larger than the employment losses to services. This is the industrialization phase whereby the overall share of value added and employment rises for manufacturing. The deindustrialization process begins at the point where the relative employment in services relative to agriculture grows enough such that the losses of manufacturing to services surpasses its gains from agriculture. The discussion above suggests that there should be a threshold on the size of service sector employment relative to that of agriculture, such that reaching the threshold triggers the beginning of the deindustrialization process. This is the point in which the employment gains from agriculture equates the losses to manufacturing, that is, ( 1 ) Rate of EMP Decline Agr/Man Agr Share of EMP = Rate of EMP Growth Ser/Man Ser Share of EMP The discussion above leads us to focus on the evolution of the gap in employment between services and agriculture as the key force determining the timing of the deindustrialization process. In particular, in any cross section of time, poor and rich countries show gaps both in income and in their relative size of the service sector. Whether or not the income of a poor country at its peak of the manufacturing sector is the same as that of a richer country crucially depends on the rate at which the two gaps are closed. 20

21 Figure 9 Error! Reference source not found. shows how Equation ( 1 ) holds in the data. On the x- axis, we have shown the share of employment in services relative to agriculture in the year in which each country begins to deindustrialize, while on the y-axis, we have shown the ratio of the rate of decline of employment in agriculture to manufacturing by the rate of growth of employment in services relative to manufacturing. 10 Given that the relationship is a mechanical equality, it is not surprising that, as the figure shows, it indeed holds fairly accurately in the data. 11 Therefore, we conclude that this relation provides a precise characterization of the timing of the beginning of the deindustrialization process. 10 We compute the rate of growth over a 10-year window around the time when the country peaks its share of employment in manufacturing. 11 We have removed Singapore from this figure, for which both of these ratios are much higher relative to all other countries. In 1984, the year in which Singapore reaches the height of its industrialization, the share of employment in services relative to agriculture 21

22 Figure 10 Consider now a country that in a given cross section, say the year 1950, is characterized by an initial level of income and an initial size of services relative to agriculture. The relative size of services to agriculture is larger in richer countries in this cross section. From Error! Reference source not found. and Figure 9 we know that this relative size grows over time for all countries. Equation ( 1 ) then suggests that there is a country-specific constant threshold on the relative size of services to agriculture such that, upon reaching this level, the share of manufacturing in the country s employment begins to fall. 51.7, while the relative growth rates are The reason for this outlier behavior is simply the fact that Singapore does not have enough land endowment to allow for a sizable agricultural sector. We remove Singapore from all the results reported in this section. 22

23 Figure 11 Error! Reference source not found. provides another crucial fact about the heterogeneity across countries in deindustrialization. We can see that at the peak of their industrialization, countries show wide variations in the ratio of the rate of decline of agricultural employment relative to manufacturing to the rate of growth of services employment relative to manufacturing. This gives us an important clue about the determinants of heterogeneity in industrialization experiences across countries. We will next investigate the degree to which this heterogeneity is related to the heterogeneity in the timing of deindustrialization. 23

24 Figure 12 If the rates of relative employment growth were the same across countries, potential variations would have been driven solely by the sectoral composition in the initial cross section. 12 According to this scenario, countries that show early deindustrialization are those that start with a larger service sector relative to agriculture. Figure 11 and Figure 12 clearly refute this hypothesis. In both figures, we show for the cross section of 1950, the 12 Consider, for instance, a model whereby the trends in relative size of employment are driven by relative states of technology across sectors. Furthermore, the frontier technology diffuses from rich to poor countries in all sectors with a constant time lag. In such a model, even though Mexico in 1950 has the same level of income as the US in 1900, the sectoral composition of Mexico in 1950 is different from the US in In particular, since the sectoral technological gap in Mexico in 1950 reflects that of the US, services are already much larger in 1950 in Mexico compared to the US in As a result, starting from 1950, it takes Mexico less than 50 years to reach its peak of manufacturing. 24

25 residual of a regression of the logarithm of the size of services (relative to agriculture) on log income on the x-axis. While Figure 11 shows countries that begin with a larger size gap in fact reach the maximum earlier, this difference is not reflected in their maximum share of manufacturing, as we see in Figure 12. Therefore, we conclude that among the terms contributing to Equation ( 1 ), the rates of employment growth are more likely than the initial sizes of the sectors to reflect key structural parameters that drive the deindustrialization process. Figure 13 25

26 Figure 14 Next, we investigate whether the heterogeneity reflected in Error! Reference source not found. also matters for explaining the income at the peak and the highest level of industrialization achieved. Figure 13 and Figure 14 document that this is indeed the case. Countries where the rate of decline of agriculture/manufacturing employment is larger relative to the rate of growth of services/manufacturing employment are exactly those that experience a deeper penetration of industrialization (Figure 14). We then unpack this effect by separately exploring the relationship for the rate of decline of the relative agriculture/manufacturing employment and the rate of growth of the relative services/manufacturing employment. Figure 15 and Figure 16 explore these relationships. While we do not find a strong relationship between the maximum penetration of manufacturing and the growth rate of relative services/manufacturing employment, the relationship appears very strong for the rate of decline of the relative agriculture/manufacturing employment. 26

27 Figure 15 Figure 15 captures the key result of our investigation in this section. It captures the following simple intuition: the ability of a country to experience a deep process of industrialization crucially hinges on its ability to go through a very fast transition out of agriculture and into manufacturing. In other words, the trends toward premature deindustrialization may be due to the fact that developing countries outside East Asia have not been able to experience an accelerated shift from agriculture into manufacturing. Since services continue to draw workers out of agriculture at all levels of income, a slow industrialization process results in a situation whereby agriculture shrinks by losing its workers to services rather than manufacturing. So far, we have solely focused on patterns of relative employment and have abstracted away from deeper forces that have shaped the observed rates of growth. In the next section, we briefly overview some of these potential drivers the forces that give rise to systematic reallocation of employment and value added across sectors as we have seen in this section. 27

28 Figure 16 Section 5: Sectoral Price and Income Elasticity We now turn our attention to the determinants of the patterns we observed in the previous section. As we saw, the share of the manufacturing sector in employment and production value added for the most part move in tandem. Most of the patterns appear qualitatively the same whether we express them in terms of employment and value added. This suggests that the trends in factors such as the sectoral labor share of output or sectoral wages may not make a large contribution to the patterns of deindustrialization. 13 Therefore, we follow 13 To see this point more clearly, consider the identity αy = wl where Y and L denote the value added and employment at the sectoral level, α stands for the share of labor in output, and w stands for wages. The fact that most of our patterns of interest appear similarly in Y and L suggests that the variations over time and across sectors in labor share and the wages may not be first order. We will investigate this point in more detail in the appendix. 28

29 the literature on structural change and focus our attention on the drivers of demand for the size of different sectors, and in particular the sectoral prices. Let us begin by applying the logic of the price-based theories of structural change to our problem. First, let us assume that the size of trade is not large enough to make an impact on the sectoral composition of the economy. Thus, the size of each sector is determined by the total demand for the output of that particular sector from the consumers in each country. Demand for sectoral goods is in turn shaped by the evolution of sectoral prices and income. The relationship between the trends in relative demand and the trends in relative prices crucially hinges on the elasticity of substitution across sectors. If sectoral demand is elastic (inelastic) and sectoral goods are highly substitutable (complementary), the relative demand for a sector whose relative prices are rising falls (rises). Most studies have taken the view that the demand elasticity of substitution across broadly defined sectoral goods is below unity, implying inelastic demand (Ngai and Pissarides 2007; Acemoglu and Guerrieri 2008; Buera and Kaboski 2009). The estimates reported rarely, if ever, exceed 1 (Stockman and Tesar 1995; Herrendorf, Rogerson, and Valentinyi 2013; Comin, Lashkari, and Mestieri 2015). Therefore, the available evidence point to positive relationship between relative prices and relative demand (and therefore relative employment). 29

30 Figure 17 Figure 18 30

31 Figure 19 The trends in relative prices in the US match this picture: relative (production) prices of agriculture to manufacturing falls at an average rate of 1% between , while the relative (production) prices of services to manufacturing goods rise at an average rate of 0.9% within the same period. 14 Therefore, trends in relative employment are aligned with the trends in relative prices for the US. However, Error! Reference source not found. and Figure 18 show that the trends in sectoral relative prices show a larger degree of heterogeneity across countries when contrasted with patterns in relative employment growth in Error! Reference source not found. and Figure We define the price for each sector as the ratio of nominal value added to real value added in constant (2005) prices. The growth rates are found by regressing the logarithm of relative prices by time, and the t-statistics for the two estimates are 7.55 and 24.71, respectively. 31

32 Figure 20 If the trends in relative prices in fact drive the trends in relative employment, they should also explain the patterns we observed in maximum share of employment in the previous section. Figure 19 suggests that this is not the case. It shows that the rate of growth of the relative prices of agriculture to manufacturing around the beginning of the deindustrialization process does correlate with the peak size of the manufacturing sector. 15 Another demand-side factor that can potentially influence the trends in relative employment is the income elasticity of sectoral goods. As discussed above, a series of recent papers have highlighted the fact that demand nonhomotheticities do not have to be 15 Similarly, Figure 20 shows that relative sectoral productivity growth may not play a crucial role in this process. Here, we have defined sectoral productivity by dividing real value added by employment in each sector. 32

33 a transient feature of consumer preferences (Boppart 2014; Comin, Lashkari, and Mestieri 2015). However, we cannot use variations in income elasticity of demand to explain the patterns observed in the previous section. Most reliable estimates of income elasticities imply that the income elasticities are the highest for the service sector and the lowest for agriculture. Depending on the specifications of demand, either the income elasticity of relative demand falls with income (Kongsamut, Rebelo, and Xie 2001; Herrendorf, Rogerson, and Valentinyi 2013) or remains stable (Boppart 2014; Comin, Lashkari, and Mestieri 2015). Neither case can explain why countries that have higher income at the peak of their manufacturing also show a faster rate of decline in their size of agriculture relative to manufacturing. We conclude that the standard theories of structural change that rely on demand-side forces operating through price and income elasticity may not rationalize the patterns observed in the previous section. Section 6: Future Work A adopting a 3-sector framework can help us derive predictions about the timing of deindustrialization. We have shown that the root causes of premature deindustrialization may be tied to the relatively slow movement of workers from agriculture into manufacturing in developing countries. However, a brief overview of the traditional demand-side drivers of structural change suggested that they cannot readily explain the patterns identified here. Therefore, our future research will explore the alternative causes that may explain the relatively slower process of industrialization among developing countries. One key force that we have not discussed here is international trade. Rodrik (2015) argues that trade competition has played a major role in curbing the growth of manufacturing in Latin America and Africa. We find evidence that the growth of manufacturing can be driven by short episodes of fast industrialization, as can be seen in the case of East Asian growth miracles. Even in the United States, the rate of decline of agriculture relative to 33

34 manufacturing has significantly fallen from its peak numbers around the mid-twentieth century when it completed its deindustrialization process. Exploring the potential role of trade in explaining premature deindustrialization will be an important element of our future research plan around this topic. A second force is the international diffusion of technology and the increased demand for skilled workers in the production of manufactured goods. As technology has diffused global it is possible that on the one hand countries can meet their demand for goods at given income levels with fewer inputs (i.e. workers). It is also possible that countries run into constraints and experience skills shortages that prevent them from achieving peak employment shares that were possible earlier. These and other possible explanations will be explored in our subsequent research. Bibliography Acemoglu, Daron, and Veronica Guerrieri Capital Deepening and Non-Balanced Economic Growth. Journal of Political Economy 116 (3): Autor, David H., David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. American Economic Review 103 (6): doi: /aer Baumol, William J Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis. American Economic Review 57 (3): Boppart, Timo Structural Change and the Kaldor Facts in a Growth Model with Relative Price Effects and Non-Gorman Preferences. Econometrica 82 (6): doi: /ecta Buera, Francisco J, and Joseph P Kaboski Can Traditional Theories of Structural Transformation Fit the Data? Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (2-3): Comin, Diego, Danial Lashkari, and Marti Mestieri Structural Change with Long-Run Income and Price Effects. w Working Paper Series. 34

35 Dasgupta, Sukti, and Ajit Singh Manufacturing, Services and Preamature Deindustrialization in Developing Countries. 2006/49. UNU-Wider. Duarte, Margarida, and Diego Restuccia The Role of Structural Transformation in Aggregate Productivity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, no. February. Foellmi, Reto, and Josef Zweimüller Structural Change, Engel s Consumption Cycles and Kaldor's Facts of Economic Growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (7): doi: /j.jmoneco Herrendorf, Berthold, Richard Rogerson, and Akos Valentinyi Growth and Structural Transformation. In Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol 2B, Elsevier B.V. Herrendorf, Berthold, Richard Rogerson, and Ákos Valentinyi Two Perspectives on Preferences and Structural Transformation. American Economic Review 103 (7): doi: /aer Inklaar, Robert, and Marcel P. Timmer The Relative Price of Services. Review of Income and Wealth 60 (4): doi: /roiw Jorgenson, Dale W., and Marcel P. Timmer Structural Change in Advanced Nations: A New Set of Stylised Facts. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113 (1): doi: /j x. Kongsamut, Piyabha, Sergio Rebelo, and Danyang Xie Beyond Balanced Growth. The Review of Economic Studies 68: doi: / Kuznets, Simon Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reflections. American Economic Review 63 (3): Lawrence, Robert Z, and Lawrence Edwards US Employment Deindustrialization : Insights from History and Internatiol Experience. Martin, Will, and Devashish Mitra Productivity Growth and Convergence in Agriculture versus Manufacturing. Economic Development and Cultural Change 49 (2): doi: / Matsuyama, Kiminori Structural Change in an Interdependent World: A Global View of Manufacturing Decline. Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (May): doi: /jeea Menezes-Filho, Naércio Aquino, and Marc-Andreas Muendler Labor Reallocation in 35

36 Response to Trade Reform. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No (858). doi: /w Ngai, L Rachel, and Christopher A Pissarides Structural Model of Growth Change in a Multisector. American Economic Review 97 (1): Nordhaus, William D Baumol s Diseases: A Macroeconomic Perspective. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 8 (1). Pierce, Justin R, and Peter K Schott The Surprisingly Swift Decline of US Manufacturing Employment. NBER Working Paper Series. doi: /s Rodrik, Dani Premature Deindustrialization NBER Working Paper. Rowthorn, Robert, and Ramana Ramaswamy Growth, Trade, and Deindustrialization. Vol. 46. IMF Staff Papers. Stockman, Alan C, and Linda L Tesar Tastes and Technology in a Two-Country Model of the Business Cycle: Explaining International Comovements. American Economic Review 85 (1): Timmer, Marcel, Gaaitzen de Vries, and Klaas de Vries Patterns of Structural Change in Developing Countries. GGDC Research Memorandum 149 (July): 31. Utar, Hale, and Luis B. Torres Ruiz International Competition and Industrial Evolution: Evidence from the Impact of Chinese Competition on Mexican Maquiladoras. Journal of Development Economics 105. Elsevier B.V.: doi: /j.jdeveco Ventura, Jaume A Global View of Economic Growth. Handbook of Economic Growth. Vol. 1B. Elsevier Masson SAS. doi: /s (05)

Industrial Convergence in East Asia. July 1, Akira Kohsaka. Jun-ichi Shinkai

Industrial Convergence in East Asia. July 1, Akira Kohsaka. Jun-ichi Shinkai OSIPP Discussion Paper : DP-2018-E-009 Industrial Convergence in East Asia July 1, 2018 Akira Kohsaka Professor Emeritus, Osaka School of International Public Policy Osaka University Jun-ichi Shinkai Lecturer,

More information

CAN TRADITIONAL THEORIES OF STRUCTURAL CHANGE FIT THE DATA?

CAN TRADITIONAL THEORIES OF STRUCTURAL CHANGE FIT THE DATA? CAN TRADITIONAL THEORIES OF STRUCTURAL CHANGE FIT THE DATA? Francisco J. Buera University of California at Los Angeles Joseph P. Kaboski Ohio State University and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Abstract

More information

Convergence or Divergence: Discussing Structural Transformation in Africa

Convergence or Divergence: Discussing Structural Transformation in Africa Convergence or Divergence: Discussing Structural Transformation in Africa 2 Amadou Sy Senior Fellow, Africa Growth Initiative, The Brookings Institution Africa s Convergence 3 Outline 1. Economic growth:

More information

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing Summary Freeing up resources so that they can be used more productively in other industries is the logic behind international

More information

University of Johannesburg

University of Johannesburg University of Johannesburg New Structural Economics: A Framework for Rethinking Development Justin Yifu Lin Chief Economist and Senior Vice President the World Bank March 16, 2011 1 Overview of Presentation

More information

Rural-Urban Interdependence, Structural Change, and Development. Keigo Nishida

Rural-Urban Interdependence, Structural Change, and Development. Keigo Nishida CAES Working Paper Series Rural-Urban Interdependence, Structural Change, and Development Keigo Nishida Faculty of Economics Fukuoka University WP-2015-004 Center for Advanced Economic Study Fukuoka University

More information

China: growth, urbanisation and mineral resource demand

China: growth, urbanisation and mineral resource demand : growth, urbanisation and mineral resource demand Jin Liu and Tony McDonald 1 Over recent decades, has experienced rapid economic growth and a related sharp increase in its rate of urbanisation. The speed

More information

Trade and Inequality. Clausen Conference on Global Economic Issues 2017 Bob Koopman Chief Economist, World Trade Organization

Trade and Inequality. Clausen Conference on Global Economic Issues 2017 Bob Koopman Chief Economist, World Trade Organization Trade and Inequality Clausen Conference on Global Economic Issues 2017 Bob Koopman Chief Economist, World Trade Organization Context Trade has come under increasing fire in some developed countries Mixed

More information

The Role of the Structural Transformation in Aggregate Productivity

The Role of the Structural Transformation in Aggregate Productivity The Role of the Structural Transformation in Aggregate Productivity Margarida Duarte University of Toronto Diego Restuccia University of Toronto February 29 Abstract We investigate the role of sectoral

More information

Is Globalization Causing A 'Race To The Bottom' In Environmental Standards? (Part 4 of a four part series)

Is Globalization Causing A 'Race To The Bottom' In Environmental Standards? (Part 4 of a four part series) Is Globalization Causing A 'Race To The Bottom' In Environmental Standards? (Part 4 of a four part series) If globalization promotes growth, won't that mean more environmental degradation? Some critics

More information

IMF MACRO CONFERENCE RODRIK PRESENTATION

IMF MACRO CONFERENCE RODRIK PRESENTATION IMF MACRO CONFERENCE Before this panel, we were talking with Mike Spence, and he said he was glad we were having this session on growth. Of course, it s not as if the crisis completely eradicated the field.

More information

Beyond Manufacturing: Structural Change in Africa Reconsidered

Beyond Manufacturing: Structural Change in Africa Reconsidered Beyond Manufacturing: Structural Change in Africa Reconsidered John Page The Brookings Institution, IGC and UNU-WIDER Governor s Lecture Bank of Uganda Kampala, 21 September 2018 Rediscovering Structural

More information

U.S. Trade and Inventory Dynamics

U.S. Trade and Inventory Dynamics U.S. Trade and Inventory Dynamics By GEORGE ALESSANDRIA, JOSEPH P. KABOSKI, VIRGILIU MIDRIGAN We examine the substantial drop and rebound in international trade by the U.S. 1 in the period 2008 to 2010,

More information

The Structural Transformation and Aggregate Productivity in Portugal

The Structural Transformation and Aggregate Productivity in Portugal The Structural Transformation and Aggregate Productivity in Portugal Margarida Duarte University of Toronto Diego Restuccia University of Toronto November 2006 Abstract We document the substantial process

More information

Has there been a structural improvement in US productivity?

Has there been a structural improvement in US productivity? Has there been a structural improvement in US productivity? By Stuart Berry of the Bank s International Economic Analysis Division and David England of the Bank s Monetary Assessment and Strategy Division.

More information

I D R C - T T I I n s t i t u t e o f R u r a l M a n a g e m e n t A n a n d G u j a r a t

I D R C - T T I I n s t i t u t e o f R u r a l M a n a g e m e n t A n a n d G u j a r a t I D R C T T I P a p e r P r e s e n t a t i o n I D R C - T T I Wo r k s h o p o n R u r a l - U r b a n L i n k a g e s 21 st & 2 2 nd A u g u s t 2 0 1 2 I R M A A n a n d S e r v i c e S e c t o r G

More information

AI and Jobs: the role of demand

AI and Jobs: the role of demand AI and Jobs: the role of demand By James Bessen, Boston University School of Law Abstract: In manufacturing, technology has sharply reduced jobs in recent decades. But before that, for over a century,

More information

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series. Openness and Urbanization: The Case of the People s Republic of China.

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series. Openness and Urbanization: The Case of the People s Republic of China. ADBI Working Paper Series Openness and Urbanization: The Case of the People s Republic of China Chu-Ping No. 561 March 2016 Asian Development Bank Institute Chu-Ping is an associate professor at the Department

More information

Enhancing Productivity Growth. Philippe Aghion

Enhancing Productivity Growth. Philippe Aghion Enhancing Productivity Growth Philippe Aghion Basic questions How to enhance productivity growth in advanced and in emerging market economies? Schumpeterian growth theory Long-run growth driven by innovations

More information

Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality

Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality Robert Z. Lawrence In the first half of this stimulating paper, Dennis Snower gives us a review of the existing academic literature on inequality. His

More information

Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run

Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run General Observations about Growth Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run Growth is an increase in the amount of goods and services an economy produces. Chapter 7 Growth is an increase in potential

More information

Structural Transformation and Growth

Structural Transformation and Growth Structural Transformation and Growth Diego Restuccia University of Toronto and NBER University of Oslo August 4-8, 27 Restuccia Macro Growth and Development University of Oslo / 49 Overview Structural

More information

Literature Review: Long-Run Economic Growth

Literature Review: Long-Run Economic Growth Literature Review: Long-Run Economic Growth Effendy Juraimin California State University, Hayward Focusing on aggregate demand will only affect output level in the short run. When economy runs below capacity

More information

HAS SUSTAINED GROWTH DECOUPLED FROM INDUSTRIALIZATION? Dani Rodrik February 2014

HAS SUSTAINED GROWTH DECOUPLED FROM INDUSTRIALIZATION? Dani Rodrik February 2014 HAS SUSTAINED GROWTH DECOUPLED FROM INDUSTRIALIZATION? Dani Rodrik February 2014 Recent growth performance in the developing world Growth performance of country groups since 1980 10.0% 1980-1990 8.0% 1990-2000

More information

THE NEXT-11 AND THE BRICS: ARE THEY THE FUTURE MARKETS FOR AGRIFOOD TRADE?

THE NEXT-11 AND THE BRICS: ARE THEY THE FUTURE MARKETS FOR AGRIFOOD TRADE? THE NEXT-11 AND THE BRICS: ARE THEY THE FUTURE MARKETS FOR AGRIFOOD TRADE? CATPRN Trade Policy Brief 2012-03 December 2012 Alexander Cairns Karl D. Meilke Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource

More information

Introduction. H E A P P R O A C H O F a new millennium aff o rds an opportunity to

Introduction. H E A P P R O A C H O F a new millennium aff o rds an opportunity to Introduction 1 H E A P P R O A C H O F a new millennium aff o rds an opportunity to Tcontemplate long-term trends. No phenomenon in economic history is more striking than the diff e rence between the past

More information

Overview of the EU industrial sector

Overview of the EU industrial sector Overview of the EU industrial sector This note describes the current state of EU industry based on a selection of indicators. Aiming to feed into the discussion on the future industrial strategy, the note

More information

PRODUCTIVITY CONCEPTS AND MEASURES

PRODUCTIVITY CONCEPTS AND MEASURES PRODUCTIVITY CONCEPTS AND MEASURES Productivity is an overall measure of the ability to produce a good or service. More specifically, productivity is the measure of how specified resources are managed

More information

Introduction to Economics, ECON 100:11 & 13 Economic Growth, Business Cycles, Unemployment, and Inflation. Macroeconomics

Introduction to Economics, ECON 100:11 & 13 Economic Growth, Business Cycles, Unemployment, and Inflation. Macroeconomics Macroeconomics What is Macroeconomics? It is the examination of an economy on the aggregate, and not just pertaining to a particular market or industry, but all markets, and industry. It typically focuses

More information

Extended Abstract: Inequality and trade in services in the UK

Extended Abstract: Inequality and trade in services in the UK Extended Abstract: Inequality and trade in services in the UK Martina Magli July, 2017 The present study investigates the role of rise in services offshoring on UK local wages inequality for the period

More information

De-industrialization of the Riches and the Rise of China

De-industrialization of the Riches and the Rise of China De-industrialization of the Riches and the Rise of China Murat Üngör February 8, 2012 Abstract This paper studies the impact of the industrialization of China on the U.S. industrial employment share between

More information

The East Asian Economic Crisis: It's not All Bad News

The East Asian Economic Crisis: It's not All Bad News Purdue University Purdue e-pubs GTAP Working Papers Agricultural Economics 1-1-1999 The East Asian Economic Crisis: It's not All Bad News Elena Ianchovichina World Bank Thomas Hertel Purdue University

More information

TUAC Comments on the OECD Employment Outlook Making the case for coordinated and multi-employer collective bargaining systems

TUAC Comments on the OECD Employment Outlook Making the case for coordinated and multi-employer collective bargaining systems TUAC Comments on the OECD Employment Outlook 2018 - Making the case for coordinated and multi-employer collective bargaining systems Table of contents Arguments in favour of decentralised bargaining...

More information

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY MULTIPLE-CHOICE QUESTIONS 1. The mercantilists would have objected to: a. Export promotion policies initiated by the government b. The use of tariffs or quotas

More information

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Figure 2 Shares of Natural Wealth in Low-Income Countries, Figure 1 Shares of Total Wealth in Low-Income Countries, 2000

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Figure 2 Shares of Natural Wealth in Low-Income Countries, Figure 1 Shares of Total Wealth in Low-Income Countries, 2000 With this volume, Where Is the Wealth of Nations? the World Bank publishes what could be termed the millennium capital assessment: monetary estimates of the range of assets produced, natural, and intangible

More information

CANADIAN AGRIFOOD EXPORT PERFORMANCE AND THE GROWTH POTENTIAL OF THE BRICS AND NEXT- 11

CANADIAN AGRIFOOD EXPORT PERFORMANCE AND THE GROWTH POTENTIAL OF THE BRICS AND NEXT- 11 CANADIAN AGRIFOOD EXPORT PERFORMANCE AND THE GROWTH POTENTIAL OF THE BRICS AND NEXT- 11 CATPRN Trade Policy Brief 2012-05 December 2012 Alexander Cairns Karl D. Meilke Department of Food, Agricultural

More information

Econ 366. Fall 2012 Energy Prices, Energy Booms, and the Macro Economy

Econ 366. Fall 2012 Energy Prices, Energy Booms, and the Macro Economy Econ 366 Fall 2012 Energy Prices, Energy Booms, and the Macro Economy Energy Prices: Oil Energy Prices: Natural Gas Energy Prices: Coal Energy Price Trends From the preceding slides, we see that there

More information

Main concepts: Economic growth around the world, the role and determinants of productivity, economic growth and public policy.

Main concepts: Economic growth around the world, the role and determinants of productivity, economic growth and public policy. Lecture 2. Production and Growth Prof. Samuel Moon Jung 1 Main concepts: Economic growth around the world, the role and determinants of productivity, economic growth and public policy. 1. Introduction

More information

ISSN Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports. Modelling the Global Diffusion of Energy Efficiency and Low Carbon Technology

ISSN Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports. Modelling the Global Diffusion of Energy Efficiency and Low Carbon Technology ISSN 1835-9728 Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports Modelling the Global Diffusion of Energy Efficiency and Low Carbon Technology David I. Stern Research Report No. 20 February 2009 About

More information

Business Cycle Theory Revised: March 25, 2009

Business Cycle Theory Revised: March 25, 2009 The Global Economy Class Notes Business Cycle Theory Revised: March 25, 2009 We ve seen that economic fluctuations follow regular patterns and that these patterns can be used to forecast the future. For

More information

Consumer Confidence Surveys: Can They Help Us Forecast Consumer Spending in Real Time?

Consumer Confidence Surveys: Can They Help Us Forecast Consumer Spending in Real Time? University of Richmond UR Scholarship Repository Economics Faculty Publications Economics 7-2006 Consumer Confidence Surveys: Can They Help Us Forecast Consumer Spending in Real Time? Dean D. Croushore

More information

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria Mariya Neycheva Burgas Free University April 2014 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/55633/ MPRA Paper

More information

Cambridge-INET Institute

Cambridge-INET Institute Faculty of Economics Cambridge-INET Institute Cambridge-INET Working Paper Series No: 17/ Cambridge Working Papers in Economics: 17 WHY IS EUROPE FALLING BEHIND? STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION AND SERVICES'

More information

Views from the ground: remarks on the BPM6 adoption 1

Views from the ground: remarks on the BPM6 adoption 1 IFC Satellite meeting at the ISI World Statistics Congress on Assessing international capital flows after the crisis Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 24 July 2015 Views from the ground: remarks on the BPM6 adoption

More information

GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY DIRECT AND INDIRECT EXPORTS

GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY DIRECT AND INDIRECT EXPORTS GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS Peter Beck Nellemann and Karoline Garm Nissen, Economics INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY A final product is created through a chain of activities such as design, production, marketing and

More information

CAMA Working Paper Series September, 2011 SECTORAL PRODUCTIVITY, STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND CONVERGENCE

CAMA Working Paper Series September, 2011 SECTORAL PRODUCTIVITY, STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND CONVERGENCE CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS The Australian National University CAMA Working Paper Series September, 2011 SECTORAL PRODUCTIVITY, STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND CONVERGENCE Alison Stegman Research School

More information

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE MULTIPLE CHOICE 1. The mercantilists would have objected to: a. Export promotion policies initiated by the government b. The use of tariffs

More information

Comments on Oil and Global Adjustment, by Brad Setser

Comments on Oil and Global Adjustment, by Brad Setser Comments on Oil and Global Adjustment, by Brad Setser Trevor Reeve February 8, 27 The author is to be commended for pulling together a great many interesting facts and observations. The paper discusses

More information

China s Changing Economic Growth Modes in Historical Perspective

China s Changing Economic Growth Modes in Historical Perspective Chapter 1 China s Changing Economic Growth Modes in Historical Perspective Liu Wei and Cai Zhizhou School of Economics, Peking University, Beijing, PRC China has kept a long-term rapid economic growth

More information

Statistics Brief. Global Freight Figures Suggest Weak Growth Ahead. Global Trade and Transport. September

Statistics Brief. Global Freight Figures Suggest Weak Growth Ahead. Global Trade and Transport. September Statistics Brief Global Trade and Transport September 2011 Global Freight Figures Suggest Weak Growth Ahead The latest global freight data collected by the International Transport Forum at the OECD, through

More information

Meeting of G20 Ministers of Trade April 2012, Mexico. Trade, Growth and Jobs Discussion Note 2

Meeting of G20 Ministers of Trade April 2012, Mexico. Trade, Growth and Jobs Discussion Note 2 Meeting of G20 Ministers of Trade 19-20 April 2012, Mexico Trade, Growth and Jobs Discussion Note 2 Introduction 1. Over the course of the last half century, the global expansion of trade has reshaped

More information

Dynamic Transition and Economic Development

Dynamic Transition and Economic Development Dynamic Transition and Economic Development Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis January 2016 1 A. Introduction 1. The big picture! Prior to 1800: output/consumption per

More information

A GATïà ^ GÉNÉRAL SUR LES TARIFS DOUA RS ET LE COMMEM

A GATïà ^ GÉNÉRAL SUR LES TARIFS DOUA RS ET LE COMMEM Press Relea ommuniqu iepr< GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE A GATïà ^ GÉNÉRAL SUR LES TARIFS DOUA RS ET LE COMMEM >ntre William Rappard, Rue de Lausanne 154, 1211 Genève 21 M W Tél. (022M 31 02 31

More information

10 ECB HOW HAVE GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS AFFECTED WORLD TRADE PATTERNS?

10 ECB HOW HAVE GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS AFFECTED WORLD TRADE PATTERNS? Box 1 HOW HAVE GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS AFFECTED WORLD TRADE PATTERNS? In recent decades, global trade has undergone profound changes. Relative to global output, trade has risen sharply and cross-country linkages

More information

Helping Infant Economies Grow: Foundations of Trade Policies for Developing Countries

Helping Infant Economies Grow: Foundations of Trade Policies for Developing Countries Helping Infant Economies Grow: Foundations of Trade Policies for Developing Countries By BRUCE GREENWALD AND JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ* Conventional wisdom has it that trade enhances economic efficiency and thus

More information

Commentson\CatchingUpwiththeLeaders: The Irish Hare", by Patrick Honohan and Brendan Walsh

Commentson\CatchingUpwiththeLeaders: The Irish Hare, by Patrick Honohan and Brendan Walsh Commentson\CatchingUpwiththeLeaders: The Irish Hare", by Patrick Honohan and Brendan Walsh Olivier Blanchard April 2002 This paper is wise, informative, and contains two important warnings: ² Beware of

More information

Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design.

Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design. Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design. Miguel Rodríguez http://webs.uvigo.es/miguel.r Yolanda Pena Universidade de Vigo & rede (Research in Energy, Innnovation

More information

> SUMMARY < DOCTORAL THESIS THE RECONFIGURATION OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC POWER CENTRES IN THE WORLD ECONOMY AT THE BEGINNING OF THE XXI CENTURY

> SUMMARY < DOCTORAL THESIS THE RECONFIGURATION OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC POWER CENTRES IN THE WORLD ECONOMY AT THE BEGINNING OF THE XXI CENTURY "ALEXANDRU IOAN CUZA" UNIVERSITY OF IAŞI FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION DOCTORAL SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION > SUMMARY < DOCTORAL THESIS THE RECONFIGURATION OF THE

More information

Boosting economic dynamics and job growth: The potential of industrial policies. Setting the scene: New industrial policies for catching up

Boosting economic dynamics and job growth: The potential of industrial policies. Setting the scene: New industrial policies for catching up Boosting economic dynamics and job growth: The potential of industrial policies Joint workshop of the Friedrich Ebert Foundation and ILO 4-5 March 2013 The Jiva Hill Hotel, Crozet, France Setting the scene:

More information

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence ECB - BoC Workshop : Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Adjustment 15-16 June 2011 Christiane Baumeister Ehsan U. Choudhri Lawrence Schembri

More information

R&D Investments, Exporting, and the Evolution of Firm Productivity

R&D Investments, Exporting, and the Evolution of Firm Productivity American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2008, 98:2, 451 456 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.98.2.451 R&D Investments, Exporting, and the Evolution of Firm Productivity By Bee

More information

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF IT, SOFTWARE, AND THE MICROSOFT ECOSYSTEM ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF IT, SOFTWARE, AND THE MICROSOFT ECOSYSTEM ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Addendum THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF IT, SOFTWARE, AND THE MICROSOFT ECOSYSTEM ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY METHODOLOGY AND DEFINITIONS Global Headquarters: 5 Speen Street Framingham, MA 01701 USA P.508.872.8200 F.508.935.4015

More information

Challenges for Japanese companies to grow in the expanding global technology frontier

Challenges for Japanese companies to grow in the expanding global technology frontier Mizuho Economic Outlook & Analysis May 10, 2016 Challenges for Japanese companies to grow in the expanding global technology frontier < Summary > Over the past decade, the productivity of Japanese companies

More information

TRADE STRUCTURE OF INDIA AND CHINA

TRADE STRUCTURE OF INDIA AND CHINA CHAPTER - IV TRADE STRUCTURE OF INDIA AND CHINA 4.1 Introduction : As noted in the discussion in chapter-3, highlights the fact that trade liberalization journey has been quite diverse in India and China.

More information

Business Cycle Facts

Business Cycle Facts Sectoral Employment and Aggregate Labor Market Business Cycle Facts Carol Cui Abstract This paper studies the slow job market recovery in the U.S. after each post-1990 recession from a sectoral perspective.

More information

Chapter 16 Economic Growth

Chapter 16 Economic Growth Chapter Overview Chapter 16 Economic Growth In Chapter 7 we looked at the impact of economic growth in general and concentrated on the causes of short-run fluctuations in employment and price levels and

More information

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum Preliminary version Abstract This paper

More information

World KLEMS initiative: the future

World KLEMS initiative: the future World KLEMS initiative: the future Marcel Timmer Groningen Growth and Development Centre University of Groningen (presentation at World KLEMS conference, Harvard, 9-10 August, 2012) World KLEMS Aim of

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice Paul A Johnson Economics 304 Advanced Topics in Macroeconomics Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice A: The Two-Period Model Consider an individual who faces the problem of allocating their available

More information

Lecture 10: THE AD-AS MODEL Reference: Chapter 8

Lecture 10: THE AD-AS MODEL Reference: Chapter 8 Lecture 10: THE AD-AS MODEL Reference: Chapter 8 LEARNING OBJECTIVES 1.What determines the shape of the aggregate demand (AD) curve and what factors shift the entire curve. 2.What determines the shape

More information

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Zahoor Haq Post-Doctoral Fellow, Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Guelph, Canada and Lecturer, WFP

More information

PART I. COUNTRY-BASED DATA AND INDICATORS

PART I. COUNTRY-BASED DATA AND INDICATORS PART I. COUNTRY-BASED DATA AND INDICATORS Ch. 2 GHG Emissions and Trends 11 Ch. 3 Emissions Projections 17 Ch. 4 Per Capita Emissions 21 Ch. 5 Emissions Intensity 25 Ch. 6 Cumulative Emissions 31 Ch. 7

More information

Three African Futures. John Page The Brookings Institution University of Nevada at Las Vegas 7 April 2014

Three African Futures. John Page The Brookings Institution University of Nevada at Las Vegas 7 April 2014 Three African Futures John Page The Brookings Institution University of Nevada at Las Vegas 7 April 2014 The Next Frontier? Africa has become the new frontier market Africa is the world s fastest-growing

More information

Production and Growth

Production and Growth C H A P T E R 25 Production and Growth Economics P R I N C I P L E S O F N. Gregory Mankiw Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved

More information

THE FUTURE OF GLOBAL MEAT DEMAND IMPLICATIONS FOR THE GRAIN MARKET

THE FUTURE OF GLOBAL MEAT DEMAND IMPLICATIONS FOR THE GRAIN MARKET 1 THE FUTURE OF GLOBAL MEAT DEMAND IMPLICATIONS FOR THE GRAIN MARKET Mitsui Global Strategic Studies Industrial Studies Dept. II Yukiko Nozaki In the 2000s, the growing demand for meat pushed up the demand

More information

Trade Liberalisation and Its Impact on Employment: An Analysis of Indian Experiences (With Special References of Indian Manufacturing Industries)

Trade Liberalisation and Its Impact on Employment: An Analysis of Indian Experiences (With Special References of Indian Manufacturing Industries) MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Trade Liberalisation and Its Impact on Employment: An Analysis of Indian Experiences (With Special References of Indian Manufacturing Industries) Avnesh Kumar Gupta Kalindi

More information

The Productivity of Unskilled Labor in Multinational Subsidiaries from Di erent Sources

The Productivity of Unskilled Labor in Multinational Subsidiaries from Di erent Sources The Productivity of Unskilled Labor in Multinational Subsidiaries from Di erent Sources Ben Li Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder Tel: 720-475-6493 Fax: 303-492-8960 E-mail: guanyi.li@colorado.edu

More information

Chapter I. Emerging Structure of Indian Economy Growing Inter-Sectoral Imbalances (Perspectives)

Chapter I. Emerging Structure of Indian Economy Growing Inter-Sectoral Imbalances (Perspectives) Chapter I Emerging Structure of Indian Economy Growing Inter-Sectoral Imbalances (Perspectives) I. Introduction Over past decades, particularly since the beginning of economic reforms and acceleration

More information

Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1 Page 1 1. Introduction a. We now turn to a short term view of fluctuations in the economy. b. This is the chapter that made this book controversial as Mankiw tends to ignore the Keynesian framework contained

More information

Do cognitive skills Impact Growth or Levels of GDP per Capita?

Do cognitive skills Impact Growth or Levels of GDP per Capita? Do cognitive skills Impact Growth or Levels of GDP per Capita? March 2, 2017 Abstract The Great Recession has raised concerns about future economic growth. A possible remedy that was suggested was an educational

More information

Policy Brief No. 11/ July 2013

Policy Brief No. 11/ July 2013 Policy Brief No. 11/ July 2013 Export Supply Response Capacity Constraints: A focus on the Uganda s Export Performance By Mwebaze, T., Kavuma, S. and Hisali, E Problem investigated Macroeconomic stability

More information

ECO2303H1 LEC0101: International Macroeconomics, Fall 2014

ECO2303H1 LEC0101: International Macroeconomics, Fall 2014 Joseph B. Steinberg Department of Economics University of Toronto ECO2303H1 LEC0101: International Macroeconomics, Fall 2014 Lectures: Wednesdays, 11am 1pm, in KP 113 Email: joseph.steinberg@utoronto.ca

More information

56 ECB RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN STOCK BUILDING

56 ECB RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN STOCK BUILDING Box 5 RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN STOCK BUILDING This box discusses available evidence regarding recent developments in inventories and considers the implications for the assessment of the current economic

More information

The Beveridge Curve. IZA DP No Eran Yashiv. December 2006 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Beveridge Curve. IZA DP No Eran Yashiv. December 2006 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2479 The Beveridge Curve Eran Yashiv December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor The Beveridge Curve Eran Yashiv Tel Aviv

More information

LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA: AGGREGATE TRENDS AND SECTORAL PATTERNS

LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA: AGGREGATE TRENDS AND SECTORAL PATTERNS ARTICLES LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA: AGGREGATE TRENDS AND SECTORAL PATTERNS This article reviews the trends in aggregate labour productivity in the euro area since the early 1980s

More information

CH 1-2. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CH 1-2. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. Class: Date: CH 1-2 Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1. The inability of society to provide senior citizens with all of the prescription drugs

More information

Education and Economic Growth: Is Tertiary Education for all Workers Optimal?

Education and Economic Growth: Is Tertiary Education for all Workers Optimal? Vol. 3, No. 4, December 2017, pp. 29 34 ISSN 2393-4913, ISSN On-line 2457-5836 Education and Economic Growth: Is Tertiary Education for all Workers Optimal? Fulgence Dominick Waryoba School of International

More information

Changes in Total Demand, Productivity, and Offshoring Their Relationship with Declining Employment in U.S. Textile Industry,

Changes in Total Demand, Productivity, and Offshoring Their Relationship with Declining Employment in U.S. Textile Industry, Changes in Total Demand, Productivity, and Offshoring Their Relationship with Declining Employment in U.S. Textile Industry, 2002-2011 Zahra Saki Ph.D. Program in Textile Technology Management College

More information

World KLEMS initiative

World KLEMS initiative World KLEMS initiative Marcel Timmer Groningen Growth and Development Centre University of Groningen (presentation at World KLEMS conference, Harvard, 9-10 August, 2012) Extensions and applications World

More information

INTA 630: International Economic Development LECTURE 3: THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT I THE CLASSIC THEORIES OF GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

INTA 630: International Economic Development LECTURE 3: THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT I THE CLASSIC THEORIES OF GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT INTA 630: International Economic Development LECTURE 3: THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT I THE CLASSIC THEORIES OF GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT LECTURE 3: THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT I FOUR MAJOR CLASSIC THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT

More information

What Is Development? How do we. determine which countries are more developed. which less? Goals and Means of Development

What Is Development? How do we. determine which countries are more developed. which less? Goals and Means of Development 1 What Is Development? Are you sure that you know what development really means with respect to different? And can you determine which are more developed and which are less? It is somewhat easier to say

More information

Research on Theoretical Analysis of Unemployment Rates Interim Report. Summary

Research on Theoretical Analysis of Unemployment Rates Interim Report. Summary Research on Theoretical Analysis of Rates Interim Report Summary Authors Hirokazu Fujii Research Director, The Japan Institute for Labour Policy and Training (JILPT) (Chapters 1 and 2) Hiroshi Amari Assistant

More information

U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices

U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices James K. Jackson Specialist in International Trade and Finance 1, 2015 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RS22204 Summary Imported

More information

Effects of Human Capital and Openness on Economic Growth of Developed and Developing Countries: A Panel Data Analysis

Effects of Human Capital and Openness on Economic Growth of Developed and Developing Countries: A Panel Data Analysis Effects of Human Capital and Openness on Economic Growth of Developed and Developing Countries: A Panel Data Analysis Fatma Didin Sonmez, Pinar Sener Abstract Technology transfer by international trade

More information

Topic 2: Empirical Evidence on Cross-Country Growth

Topic 2: Empirical Evidence on Cross-Country Growth EC4010 Notes, 2007/2008 (Prof. Karl Whelan) 1 Topic 2: Empirical Evidence on Cross-Country Growth Over the last few weeks, we examined the dynamics of output per worker in the Solow model using the decomposition

More information

U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices

U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices James K. Jackson Specialist in International Trade and Finance 16, 2016 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RS22204 Summary Imported

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SKILL BIASED STRUCTURAL CHANGE. Francisco J. Buera Joseph P. Kaboski Richard Rogerson

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SKILL BIASED STRUCTURAL CHANGE. Francisco J. Buera Joseph P. Kaboski Richard Rogerson NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SKILL BIASED STRUCTURAL CHANGE Francisco J. Buera Joseph P. Kaboski Richard Rogerson Working Paper 21165 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21165 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series Social Rate of Return to R&D on Various Energy Technologies: Where Should We Invest More? A Study of G7 Countries Roula Inglesi-Lotz

More information

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series AGRICULTURAL TRADE AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE: THE CASE OF PARAGUAY.

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series AGRICULTURAL TRADE AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE: THE CASE OF PARAGUAY. ADBI Working Paper Series AGRICULTURAL TRADE AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE: THE CASE OF PARAGUAY Cesar Blanco No. 701 March 2017 Asian Development Bank Institute Cesar Blanco is senior economist at the Central

More information

Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and. Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping *

Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and. Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping * Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping * Francisco A. Gallego Christian A. Johnson December Abstract This article generates innovative

More information