Microeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Microeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools"

Transcription

1 Microeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools NINTH EDITION Chapter 16 External Costs and Environmental Policy

2 Learning Objectives 16.1 Use the marginal principle to describe the optimum level of pollution Describe the role of taxation in promoting efficient environmental policy Explain the superiority of taxation over traditional regulation Describe the virtues of marketable pollution permits and the factors that determine their price List three external costs associated with automobiles.

3 16.1 THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF POLLUTION In a recent report, the International Panel on Climate Change presents three key Concerns Observed Changes in Climate Causes of Change Projected Climate Change and its Impacts

4 16.1 THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF POLLUTION Using the Marginal Principle MARGINAL PRINCIPLE Increase the level of an activity as long as its marginal benefit exceeds its marginal cost. Choose the level at which the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost. From society s perspective, there are many benefits from pollution abatement: Better health. Increased enjoyment of the natural environment. Lower production costs. Costs?

5 16.1 THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF POLLUTION Example: The Optimal Level of Water Pollution The efficient level of pollution abatement, where marginal benefit equals marginal cost, is 300 tons (200 tons of waste). If the polluter has property rights we start with zero abatement and the other party pays for 300 tons of abatement. If the other party has property rights, we start with zero abatement and the polluter pays to increase pollution to 200 tons of waste.

6 16.1 THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF POLLUTION Coase Bargaining Coase bargaining solution, named after economist Ronald Coase, applies to a situation when there is a small number of affected parties, and the transactions costs of bargaining are relatively low. We can illustrate the bargaining solution with our example of a lake shared by a steel mill and a fishing firm. If the steel mill has the property rights to the lake, it can dump waste into the lake. The fishing firm benefits from abatement, and would be willing to pay the mill to reduce pollution. For the first ton of abatement, the fishing firm is willing to pay $21, the cost of abating the first ton is only $3, and the two parties can cut a deal. If they split the difference between the benefit and the cost, the fishing firm will pay $12 to the mill for one ton of abatement, and both will be better off. The fishing firm pays $12 to get $21 in additional fish, while the mill gets $12 to incur an abatement cost of $3.

7 APPLICATION 1 REDUCING METHANE EMISSIONS APPLYING THE CONCEPTS #1: How do we determine the optimum level of pollution? Methane is one of the greenhouse gases that contributes to global warming. It is released into the atmosphere from landfills, natural gas systems, coal mining, and livestock management. Pollution abatement requires capturing methane before it is released and using it to generate electricity. Marginal cost is $10 per ton up to 36 million ton Rising to $150 per ton up to 69 million tons The optimal level of abatement is where the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost

8 16.2 TAXING POLLUTION Private cost of production The production cost borne by a producer, which typically includes the costs of labor, capital, and materials. External cost of production A cost incurred by someone other than the producer. Social cost of production Private cost plus external cost. Pollution tax A tax or charge equal to the external cost per unit of pollution.

9 16.2 TAXING POLLUTION A Firm s Response to a Pollution Tax From the perspective of a firm subject to a pollution tax, the marginal benefit of abatement is the $3,500 pollution tax that can be avoided by cutting pollution by one ton. The firm satisfies the marginal principle at point c, with six tons of abatement, leaving two tons of SO 2 discharged into the atmosphere.

10 16.2 TAXING POLLUTION The Market Effects of a Pollution Tax The production of electricity generates two major pollutants: Sulfur dioxide. Electric power plants are responsible for about two-thirds of SO 2 emissions. As we saw earlier in the chapter, the marginal damage from SO 2 is $3,500 per ton, so that s the appropriate pollution tax. Nitrogen oxides (NO x ). Power plants are also responsible for about one-quarter of the nation s NO x emissions, a contributing factor in acid rain and the most important factor in urban smog. The study cited earlier in the chapter estimated that the appropriate tax for NO x is about $1,100 per ton.

11 16.2 TAXING POLLUTION The pollution tax increases the cost of producing electricity, shifting the market supply curve up. The equilibrium moves from point a to point b. The tax increases the equilibrium price from $64.90 to $67.60 per megawatt-hour and decreases the equilibrium quantity.

12 16.2 TAXING POLLUTION Taxes on SO 2 and NO x cause electricity generators to switch to low-sulfur coal and to alternative energy sources that generate less SO 2 and NO x. SOURCE: Based on Spencer Banzhaf, Dallas Burtraw, and Karen Palmer, Efficient Emission Fees in the U.S. Electricity Sector, Resource and Energy Economics 26 (2004):

13 APPLICATION 2 WASHING CARBON OUT OF THE AIR APPLYING THE CONCEPTS #2: What are the possible responses to a pollution tax? A carbon tax would reduce greenhouse emissions in several ways: The price of gasoline would increase, causing people to drive less and buy more energyefficient vehicles. The tax would increase the price of electricity, decreasing the quantity of electricity demanded and the quantity of fossil fuels burned. The higher price of home heating would cause people to turn down their thermostats and improve the heating efficiency of their homes, perhaps by installing energy-efficient windows or more insulation. Some electricity producers would switch from coal to natural gas, which has a lower carbon content, and thus a lower carbon tax.

14 16.2 TAXING POLLUTION One approach to reducing greenhouse gases is to tax carbon-based fuels A carbon tax of $100 per ton of carbon content = $0.28 per gallon of gasoline $12 per barrel of oil $70 per ton of coal

15 16.3 TRADITIONAL REGULATION Uniform Abatement with Permits Consider an area with two electricity generators, firm L (for low cost) and firm H (for high cost). Suppose that in the absence of pollution-abatement efforts, each firm would discharge five tons of pollution per hour. The government sets a target abatement level of two tons of SO 2 per hour, divided equally between the two firms. Under this uniform abatement policy, the government will issue four pollution permits to each firm, forcing each firm to cut pollution from five tons to four tons. TABLE 16.1 Uniform Reduction versus Pollution Tax Marginal Abatement Cost Abatement Cost Uniform Abatement Policy Pollution Tax = $3,000 per Ton Low-Cost Firm $2,000 $2,000 $4,000 High-Cost Firm $5,000 $5,000 $ 0 Total $7,000 $4,000

16 16.3 TRADITIONAL REGULATION Command and Control The problem with this approach is that the mandated abatement technology the control part of the policy is unlikely to be the most efficient technology for two reasons: The regulatory policy specifies a single abatement technology for all firms. Because the producers of a polluting good often use different materials and production techniques, an abatement technology that is efficient for one firm may be inefficient for others. The regulatory policy decreases the incentives to develop more efficient abatement technologies. The command part of the policy specifies a maximum volume of waste for each firm, so there is no incentive to cut the volume of waste below the maximum allowed.

17 16.3 TRADITIONAL REGULATION Market Effects of Pollution Regulations How do the market effects of pollution regulation compare to the effects of a pollution tax? Recall that the uniform abatement policy achieves the same reduction in pollution at a higher cost because it doesn t exploit differences in abatement costs across firms. In addition, the control part of command and control may lead to relatively costly abatement techniques because there s no incentive to develop better ones. This will cause the supply curve for the polluting good to shift upward by a larger amount than it would with a tax. A larger supply shift causes a larger increase in the equilibrium price and a larger reduction in quantity. The inefficiency of regulations is passed on to consumers, who pay higher prices.

18 16.3 TRADITIONAL REGULATION Lesson from Dear Abby: Options for Pollution Abatement The readers of Dear Abby offered the following suggestions to Dreading Winter: Buy the neighbors a catalytic add-on for the wood stove or a wood-chip gasifier for an oil furnace. In either case, there would be much less air pollution from burning wood. Soak a towel in water, swish it around the room, and watch the smoke disappear. Leave a saucer of vinegar in each room to eliminate the smoke odor. Pay your neighbors to hire a chimney sweep to clean their flue. Seal and caulk your windows to keep the smoke outside at a cost of less than $500. Use the $500 to purchase an air purifier for your home. There is usually more than one way to deal with a pollution problem.

19 APPLICATION 3 OPTIONS FOR REDUCING CO2 EMISSIONS FROM INTERNATIONAL SHIPPING APPLYING THE CONCEPTS #3: What is the most efficient way to reduce pollution? International shipping is responsible for about 3% of global CO2 emissions, and there are many ways to reduce (abate) CO2 emissions. As a tool for comparing the cost of alternative reduction methods, policy analysts compute the marginal abatement cost (MAC) of each method, defined as the cost per ton of CO2 abated. For low-cost methods such as propeller maintenance and weather-sensitive routing, the fuel savings cover the cost of the abatement method, so the MAC for these methods is close to zero. For other abatement methods, the MAC are higher: Switch from diesel to gas-powered engines: $20 per ton Reduce speed and increase fleet size: $90 per ton Install fixed sails and wings to tap wind power: $105 per ton

20 16.4 MARKETABLE POLLUTION PERMITS Marketable pollution permits A system under which the government picks a target pollution level for a particular area, issues just enough pollution permits to meet the pollution target, and allows firms to buy and sell the permits; also known as a cap-andtrade system.

21 16.4 MARKETABLE POLLUTION PERMITS Voluntary Exchange and Marketable Permits Making pollution permits marketable is sensible because it allows mutually beneficial exchanges between firms with different abatement costs. PRINCIPLE OF VOLUNTARY EXCHANGE A voluntary exchange between two people makes both people better off.

22 16.4 MARKETABLE POLLUTION PERMITS Supply, Demand, and the Price of Marketable Permits The equilibrium price of permits is shown by the intersection of the demand curve and the vertical supply curve. The supply curve is vertical because each year the government specifies a fixed number of permits. A decrease in the number of permits shifts the supply curve to the left, increasing the equilibrium price.

23 APPLICATION 4 WEATHER AND THE PRICE OF POLLUTION PERMITS APPLYING THE CONCEPTS #4: How is the price of pollution permits determined? The European Climate Exchange is a market for pollution allowances issued to European Union countries under the EU cap-and-trade system The equilibrium price is determined by supply and demand The EU determines supply and issues the permits to energy intensive industries Demand is based on the level of economic activity, fuel prices and the weather. The Nordic countries shift from hydro electric to coal fired electric generation in dry years, increasing demand and so the cost of allowances.

24 16.5 EXTERNAL COSTS FROM AUTOMOBILES External Costs from Pollution A gasoline tax of $0.68 per gallon shifts the supply curve upward by the amount of the tax. The equilibrium price increases by $0.40. The tax is shifted forward onto consumers, who pay $0.40 more per gallon, and backward onto input suppliers, who receive lower prices for crude oil.

25 16.5 EXTERNAL COSTS FROM AUTOMOBILES External Costs from Congestion The economic approach to congestion is to internalize the external cost by imposing a tax on drivers equal to the external costs they impose on others. Modern technology allows the efficient collection of congestion taxes. The use of congestion taxes and other timesensitive pricing of highways is spreading. External Costs from Collisions In the United States, the annual cost of property damage, injuries, and deaths from traffic collisions is about $300 billion per year. About two-thirds of these costs are incurred by the driver who causes the accident, and the other third is borne by someone else. In other words, traffic collisions have substantial external costs. On average, the collision-related external cost of travel is about 4.4 cents per mile driven. By way of comparison, the fuel cost per mile is about 10 to 15 cents. The direct approach to internalize this externality would be to impose a tax of 4.4 cents per vehicle-mile traveled, a VMT tax. Such a tax would improve traffic safety by reducing the number of miles driven. Alternatively, the premium for automobile insurance could be based on miles driven or a gasoline tax could be imposed.

26 APPLICATION 5 YOUNG DRIVERS AND COLLISIONS APPLYING THE CONCEPTS #5: What is the external cost of young drivers? A VMT tax of 4.4 cents per mile would internalize the external cost from collisions on average, but the external cost varies with the age of the driver. The external cost per mile is 11 cents for young drivers (age less than 25 years), 3.4 cents for middle-aged drivers (age 25 to 70), and 5.4 cents for older drivers. A precise VMT tax would involve a higher tax rate for young drivers and generate a relatively large decrease in the miles driven by drivers with the highest collision rates and external costs.

27 Learning Objectives 16.1 Use the marginal principle to describe the optimum level of pollution Describe the role of taxation in promoting efficient environmental policy Explain the superiority of taxation over traditional regulation Describe the virtues of marketable pollution permits and the factors that determine their price List three external costs associated with automobiles.

28 KEY TERMS External cost of production Marketable pollution permits Pollution tax Private cost of production Social cost of production

29 Questions?