Are Standards Effective in Improving Automobile Fuel Economy?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Are Standards Effective in Improving Automobile Fuel Economy?"

Transcription

1 Are Standards Effective in Improving Automobile Fuel Economy? Sofronis Clerides a and Theodoros Zachariadis b* a Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, P.O. Box 20537, 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus b Economics Research Centre, University of Cyprus, P.O. Box 20537, 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus ABSTRACT There is an intense debate over whether fuel economy standards or fuel taxation is the more appropriate policy instrument to raise fuel economy and reduce CO 2 emissions of cars. The aim of this paper is to analyze the impact of standards and fuel prices in new car fuel economy with the aid of cross-section time series analysis of data from 18 countries. We employ a dynamic specification of new car fuel consumption as a function of fuel prices, standards and per capita income. Results are used to address policy questions that are currently in the center of discussions worldwide: to what extent the implementation of fuel economy standards has yielded fuel savings; how much fuel prices should rise in order to increase fuel economy without tightening standards; and whether autonomous fuel economy improvements should be expected in the absence of regulations or fiscal policy instruments. Keywords: CAFE; fuel tax; greenhouse gases; rebound effect; regulation; technical progress JEL classification: Q4; Q5 * Corresponding author. Tel , Fax addresses: Clerides: s.clerides@ucy.ac.cy; Zachariadis: t.zachariadis@ucy.ac.cy. 1

2 1. Introduction The share of transportation in total energy consumption and greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions is increasing, particularly in OECD countries, because of continuous growth in total vehicle kilometers traveled and stagnancy in automobile energy efficiency. This comes in sharp contrast to GHG mitigation achievements in other sectors like power generation and industrial processes. In the European Union (EU), for example, the transport sector almost completely cancels out other progress towards meeting the 8% GHG reduction target under the Kyoto protocol [16]. With the exception of biofuels, which are regarded as CO 2 -neutral and whose production is gradually increasing and encouraged by legislation in some world regions, other fuel/engine combinations are still not mature for mass production and even commercially available hybrid powertrains are experiencing quite slow penetration rates. It therefore becomes imperative for OECD countries to succeed in improving the fuel economy (FE) 1 of conventional gasoline- and diesel-fueled passenger cars if they are to ensure progress in limiting GHG emissions and meeting their Kyoto commitments (where applicable),. One way to raise the fuel economy of new cars is through FE standards, either mandatory or as a voluntary commitment of the automotive industry. An FE standard is usually expressed as the minimum sales-weighted average fuel economy for the new-car fleet entering the market in a given year. A second approach towards improving FE is to increase fuel taxation in order to induce purchases of more efficient cars and discourage private car travel. Mandatory fuel economy standards have been in force in the United States since 1978 (although, with a small exception for light duty trucks, they have not been tightened since 1990). Other countries followed later, and currently Australia, Canada, China, the EU, Japan, Switzerland, South Korea and Taiwan implement some type of FE or CO 2 standard. It is generally acknowledged that the adoption of standards has induced fuel economy improvements, or at least it has ensured that the fuel economy of new cars will not deteriorate despite consumer preferences for extra energy-consuming amenities and safety features. This seems to be confirmed by observing the evolution of fuel economy over time and its close relation to the existence of standards or voluntary targets; Figure 1 shows this relationship for the US and the EU. Post-1982 FE improvements are particularly noteworthy because fuel prices decreased sharply after 1982, so that these improvements cannot be attributed to high fuel prices. Supporters of standards cite the myopic behavior of both consumers and producers and conclude that FE regulations may be more successful than fuel taxes. For example, Glazer and Lave [23] argue that, despite higher fuel prices, both consumers and manufacturers may prefer to wait until uncertainty about technology or gasoline prices is resolved before making purchase decisions or undertaking costly research on more efficient cars respectively. Hence, even if an increase in the price of gasoline has powerful effects, those effects may be delayed and regulation may have a more immediate impact. 1 The equivalent terms fuel economy (expressed in miles per gallon) and fuel consumption (expressed in litres per 100 kilometres) are linked by the following relationship: fuel consumption (l/100 km) = / fuel economy (mpg). 2

3 (a) Fuel Consumption (liters per 100 km) Constant Brent price (US$'2004) US Cars US CAFE Car Standard EU Cars EU voluntary target Brent price Model Year (b) 11 (liters / 100 km) France Germany Sweden UK Japan Figure 1: (a) Evolution of new-car fuel consumption in the US and the EU and the corresponding CAFE standard (for the US) and voluntary CO 2 target (for the EU). US data come from [32]; for compilation of EU data see [49]. The international oil price in real terms, taken from [8], is also shown. (b) New-car fuel consumption in Japan and four EU countries. 3

4 A similar argument for standards is provided by [27] and [30], who claim that standards are effective because of failures in the market for fuel economy. They cite several studies reporting that consumers are myopic, i.e. they undervalue the potential cost savings of fuel efficient cars, so that higher fuel prices would have a smaller impact on fuel economy than regulations. Modeling studies such as [24] and [29], which did not find strong evidence for or against standards in terms of their welfare impact, can also be cited as results favoring FE regulations. [24] found also that a high gasoline tax (of the order of 80 US cents per gallon), which is unlikely to be accepted in the US, would be required to yield the same fuel saving benefit as CAFE standards. However, there are voices in the US (where most of the experience has been gathered) arguing against standards and favoring increases in fuel taxes instead. Among opponents of FE regulations, some analysts express doubts whether the current type of Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards are appropriate. For example, NRC [39] and Portney et al. [43] suggest that, if the CAFE system is to be retained, a number of improvements should be introduced such as: enabling the use of tradable FE permits among manufacturers, revising the distinction between cars and light trucks, removing distinctions between domestic and imported vehicle fleets, or allowing for differentiation of standards based on vehicle attributes. Other analysts reject the idea of any type of standard whatsoever. Thorpe [46], for instance, applied a general equilibrium model and found that CAFE actually reduces fuel economy as it shifts automobile sales towards less efficient vehicles. Kleit [38] estimated that increasing gasoline tax by 11 US cents per gallon would yield the same energy conservation effect with raising the current CAFE standards by 3 mpg, at significantly lower welfare costs. Austin and Dinan [5] reached a similar conclusion, and Parry et al. [40] found that tightening the standards would raise welfare only under severe consumer myopia, i.e. if consumers greatly undervalue fuel savings. [5], [38] and [42] have also countered the argument of market failures (which is mentioned by supporters of standards), noting that consumers are very well informed about automobile fuel costs because of ample information on both new car fuel economy and fuel prices, so that it is unlikely for this market to be inefficient. There is also currently an intense debate on fuel economy regulations in the EU. In a voluntary agreement with the European Commission in the late 1990s [13], the automobile industry made a commitment that by 2008/2009 the average (sales-weighted) new passenger car will emit 140 grams of CO 2 per kilometer, compared to the 1995 average of 185 g/km. As the deadline approaches and this target will most probably not be met [37, 49], discussions among stakeholders have become intensive again. In Europe, however, the question is not whether to impose higher fuel taxes or standards as fuel taxation is already quite high: in 2003, excise taxes alone accounted on average for about 60% and 50% of the retail price of gasoline and automotive diesel oil respectively [19]. EU-wide discussions focus on whether the automotive industry s commitment should be expanded in the future and whether a mandatory standard should be imposed: a target of 120 CO 2 g/km is mentioned for the year 2012 or later. In view of these and similar discussions around the world, the aim of this paper is to analyze the impact of FE standards and fuel prices on new car fuel economy with the aid of time series analysis of data from several countries worldwide. Similar work was previously 4

5 undertaken by Espey [18], who addressed fleet-wide fuel consumption using data from 8 OECD countries from 1975 to Only the US had FE standards during that period and even these standards correlated closely with the time trend because standards had been rising fairly steadily until Therefore the impact of the FE standard in that work could not be separated from the overall time trend that may represent technical progress or other change. Johansson and Schipper [36] conducted a similar analysis with cross-section time series models including 12 OECD countries for the period , but using again fleet-average FE as the dependent variable and without addressing standards explicitly. Using countryspecific time trends, the authors found that FE improvements had been much faster in the US than in any other country since 1978, but they were reluctant to attribute all the improvement to the CAFE program. Storchmann [45] also employed a pooled model to estimate fleetaverage fuel consumption using several explanatory variables such as private income, population density, urbanization rates, fuel prices and automobile costs. He focused on the effect of income distribution on worldwide gasoline demand and did not address the issue of FE standards. Greene [26] tackled the same question using a different methodology. He modeled the automobile manufacturers decision-making process and concluded that CAFE standards played a greater role than fuel prices in improving new-car FE levels in the US. Data came from the US only and, as in [18], involved a period of monotonously rising standards. Gately [22] tested equations of fleet-average FE as a function of prices and CAFE standards, allowing for potentially asymmetric price elasticities in US gasoline consumption. He found that standards were not statistically significant and gasoline prices alone (with lags of up to 10 years) could sufficiently explain the evolution of FE over the years. The effect of standards, however, is diluted when fleet-average FE is the dependent variable because of slow vehicle retirement rates. In order to account properly for the effect of standards, not only the current value of the standard but a sufficient number of lags of the standard variable has to be included. If Gately [22] had longer time series available in order to include the lagged effect of standards in his model his results might have been different. Small and van Dender [44] include a CAFE variable in their analysis, which turns out to be significant for determining fuel economy. However, as their main concern is the extent of the rebound effect, i.e. how much vehicle travel will increase if fuel economy decreases, they only use the CAFE variable (defined as the difference between regulated and desired fuel economy levels) in order to derive more stable estimates of the rebound effect. This paper extends previous analyses in several ways. First, it addresses new-car (instead of fleet-averaged) fuel economy, which is a variable that is easier to follow and is not compounded by assumptions on vehicle turnover rates. Second, it includes US data from 1975 to 2004, thus enriching the sample with periods of rising as well as falling oil prices and rising as well as stagnant CAFE standards. Third, it includes data from several world regions (North America, Europe, Japan and Australia); thereby it extends the discussion beyond the US and places results in the context of ongoing policy discussions worldwide. The international analysis presented here has to rely on reduced form time series relationships as it cannot employ micro level data on the producer s side. The voluntary agreement that is in place in the EU does not include any requirements for individual automobile manufacturers, hence it is not possible to analyze this issue in Europe on the basis of 5

6 simulations of a firm s behavior (such as many of the studies mentioned above). Nonetheless, the wide international and temporal coverage of the sample yields interesting and policyrelevant results. 2. Methodology As mentioned in the literature review above, using fleet-average FE as the dependent variable complicates the analysis because this is a derived quantity influenced both by new-car fuel economy and the rate at which new cars enter the market. Fleet-average FE changes very slowly, hence it becomes difficult to discern the potential impact of a standard or a new technology; this was also the result of estimations of [18] and [36]. Conversely, fuel prices affect fuel consumption of both new and old cars, in the latter case through changes in vehicle utilization (i.e. distance traveled) or maintenance levels. This wider and direct impact of prices may conceal the influence of other factors and hence, as explained in the previous section, the effect of tighter FE standards or technical progress can only be identified if lagged values of the corresponding variables are included. Therefore, in order to examine the impact of FE standards without using a large number of lagged variables that may lead to a considerable loss of degrees of freedom, it is preferable to use new-car FE as a dependent variable. It is reasonable to include fuel prices and FE standards as explanatory variables as these may be the two most important mechanisms that induce FE improvements. High fuel prices push consumers to purchase more fuel efficient cars and thus indirectly give manufacturers an incentive to increase vehicle efficiency. FE standards or voluntary targets encourage (or force) manufacturers to introduce efficient cars and to make them attractive to their customers, while they may also increase consumer awareness of fuel economy issues. It is important to include lagged prices in the model and perhaps also lagged FE standards as producers will need to gradually adjust their vehicles to meet future FE requirements. Income may also significantly affect fuel economy, although the direction may not be a priori obvious. Existing studies provide conflicting evidence. Dahl [11], based on US data, estimates a mostly negative impact of income on fuel consumption. This result is confirmed by [36] for their panel of 12 OECD countries. Others studies like [18], with data from 8 OECD countries, find income to be insignificant for fuel consumption, or do not even include income among the explanatory variables [22]. On the other hand, [45] finds a small but significant and positive income elasticity in his panel of 90 countries, which includes data from several low-income world regions 2. The diversity of these findings implies that it is not simple to interpret the income effect: cars that consume more fuel may be bigger and more luxurious (positive income effect) or older and not technologically advanced (negative effect). In physical terms, fuel consumption depends on the forces exerted on a vehicle while it is driven (inertia, rolling resistance and aerodynamic drag), the thermal efficiency of its engine and the mechanical efficiency of its power transmission system. Observable variables that could partly reflect these physical factors are the average mass or engine size and the 2 All these findings refer to fleet-average and not new-car fuel consumption. 6

7 maximum engine power of new cars, or the share of diesel cars in annual sales. Each variable, however, can only explain some of these effects on fuel consumption, so that none of them may be appropriate for our model. Besides these variables may be themselves a result of tighter FE standards, high fuel prices or technical progress rather than a cause of improved fuel economy; this means that they should not be treated as exogenous in the model. Therefore, it may be simpler and more appropriate to include a deterministic time trend in the model instead of these individual variables, which also exhibit an almost monotonous increase over time as shown in Figure 2. Technical progress is another important and controversial aspect. There are, for example, different views as to whether price elasticities of energy demand are asymmetric (with price increases having a stronger impact than decreases) or this apparent asymmetry is just the composite effect of symmetric price elasticities and price-induced technical change ([31, 33]). In the context of this study, the inclusion of prices and FE standards means that priceinduced and regulation-induced technical progress is captured by these two variables. In order to allow for the additional possibility of autonomous fuel economy improvements, it is appropriate to use a deterministic time trend in the model. This means that the time trend is intended to capture this kind of technical progress as well as changes in consumer preferences as outlined in the previous paragraph to the extent that they are not related to income. Having selected the major explanatory variables, we applied the dynamic panel model described in equation (1). The autoregressive formulation of the dependent variable, applied also in [18] and [36], enables the identification of both short-run and long-run effects and is therefore useful for policy simulations: L FCi, t = λ FCi, t 1 + α1 t + α 2, j pi, t j + α 3 STDi, t + α 4 INCi, t + ν i + ε i, t (1) j= 0 where indices i and t denote cross-section (country) and time respectively. All variables are expressed in natural logarithms. FC is average sales-weighted fuel consumption of new cars in liters per 100 kilometers (l/100 km), λ is the autoregressive coefficient of the dependent variable, α 1 is the time trend coefficient, p is real gasoline price expressed in Euros at 1995 prices per liter, STD is the level of the country-specific FE standard of that year, expressed in l/100 km, INC is real per capita GDP expressed in Euros at 1995 prices, and ε is a residual term that is independently and normally distributed with zero mean and constant variance. To account for lagged price effects, we selected a maximum lag length of L=5 to allow for the possibility that consumer decisions on the fuel consumption of their new car are affected by price fluctuations over the last 5 years. In such a model the short-run effect of each variable is given by the values of the corresponding coefficients α 2 through α 4, while the long-run effect is given by the corresponding coefficients divided by (1- λ). There are several reasons why such a model should include country effects, ν i ; national particularities in vehicle fuel consumption that persist over the years will affect model estimation. Examples include population density and urbanization rates, which influence average automobile size and hence fuel consumption [45]; vehicle taxes and how these increase progressively for bigger cars [18, 36]; and the price ratio of diesel fuel to gasoline per country, which has a direct impact on the share of diesel car sales. 7

8 180 (a) Mass (1842 kg) Power (102 kw) (b) Mass (980 kg) Power (55 kw) Size (1.5 l) Figure 2: Evolution of new vehicle attributes (average vehicle mass, maximum engine power and average engine size) (a) in the US and (b) in Europe. In each case the attributes of year 1975 are the basis (1975=100), and legends provide the actual figures for the base year. See Figure 1 for description of data sources. Before arriving at a model that uses the STD variable as shown in equation (1), we considered alternative ways to formulate the variable that describes FE standards. One could argue that, instead of using STD i,t one should use the standard of a few years ahead since FE standards will mainly influence forward-looking decisions of manufacturers who gradually adjust the 8

9 fuel economy of cars they introduce in the market depending on the level of FE standards that will be in force in the near future. We addressed this possibility by defining the year-by-year STD variable (as described in the Appendix) in a way that already incorporates this forwardlooking behavior because of the assumption that STD evolves each year in order to gradually approach a future standard or target. We therefore considered it more appropriate to use STD i,t in the model. Bratberg et al. [9] used a difference in difference estimator to assess the effectiveness of international environmental agreements: for each country they compared the change of the dependent variable over time (before and after the implementation of the agreement) with the corresponding evolution of the variable in a country that has not implemented this agreement. In our case, however, this was not possible because we could not find fuel consumption data for countries that have not implemented FE standards or targets; section 3 provides more information on data availability. We therefore relied on the usual expression of the STD variable in levels as shown in equation (1). An alternative way to address the effect of standards would be to express the STD variable as a difference between the value of the FE standard in a given year and the observed FE level one year before (or with a different lag/lead combination). This approach might be justified because, theoretically, average new-car fuel consumption should be lower than or equal to the level of the corresponding standard in each year. In practice, however, average fuel consumption levels may be different because of the way that standards are implemented. In the US, for example, average fuel economy of Japanese cars was always higher than the corresponding CAFE standard, so that fuel economy averaged across cars from all manufacturers was higher than the standard although American and European manufacturers had to strive to reach the standard. In the EU, the CO 2 target value (which is voluntary in any case) applies to Europe-wide automobile sales, so that in some countries with bigger cars and lower diesel sales (e.g. Sweden) average CO 2 emissions are always higher than the target, while in other countries (e.g. France or Spain) emissions are consistently lower than the European average target. For these reasons this approach too had to be rejected as inappropriate. 3. Data For the variables included in equation (1), data were obtained from official national and international sources. New-car fuel consumption is not routinely recorded in many countries, and in most cases it was only after the implementation of some FE standards that this variable started being systematically measured in countries with regulations in place. There are, however, OECD countries where such information has been gathered since the late 1970s, primarily through initiatives of the International Energy Agency (IEA) with the aid of data collected from automobile manufacturers. We were able to construct consistent time series for 18 countries. We thus built an unbalanced panel consisting of 20 cross-sections: the US (cars and light duty trucks separately), Canada (cars and light duty trucks separately), Australia, Japan, Switzerland and 13 EU countries 384 observations in total. Table 1 provides more details of this panel. 9

10 Table 1: Overview of the sample used in the study. Country Vehicle category Sample period Type of standards Enforcement type First decision for the adoption of standards/targets First year of implementation or first target year Australia Cars FE Voluntary Austria Cars CO 2 Voluntary Belgium Cars CO 2 Voluntary Canada Cars FE Voluntary Canada Light duty trucks FE Voluntary Denmark Cars CO 2 Voluntary France Cars CO 2 Voluntary Germany Cars CO 2 Voluntary Ireland Cars CO 2 Voluntary Italy Cars CO 2 Voluntary Japan Cars FE Mandatory Luxembourg Cars CO 2 Voluntary Netherlands Cars CO 2 Voluntary Portugal Cars CO 2 Voluntary Spain Cars CO 2 Voluntary Sweden Cars CO 2 Voluntary Switzerland Cars FE Voluntary United Kingdom Cars CO 2 Voluntary United States Cars FE Mandatory United States Light duty trucks FE Mandatory

11 We used information from the US Environmental Protection Agency [32] and the US Transportation Energy Data Book [12]; the IEA (see e.g. [34]; and additional material that is available on the World Wide Web 3 ); the European Commission ([14] and similar earlier documents reporting for years ); the European Conference of Ministers of Transport [15]; Natural Resources Canada (various publications available on the World Wide Web 4 ); the Japanese Automobile Manufacturers Association (JAMA) 5 ; the Association of Swiss Vehicle Importers [6]; and an international study [1]. Data on real GDP per capita were obtained by the EU Statistical Service [20] and fuel prices from the IEA [35]. Since some countries enforce FE standards while EU Member States apply CO 2 emission targets, some transformations are necessary in order to arrive at the common STD variable of equation (1). We therefore converted all standards expressed in mpg to l/100 km and transformed the targets expressed in grams of CO 2 per km to liters of gasoline equivalent per 100 km by applying the commonly used conversion factor of 23.7 [14]. Moreover, the experimental method used to determine FE has changed twice in Europe since the mid-1990s: once in 1997, where a cold start phase was added to the test cycle, and once in 2001, where an idling period on engine start up was removed from the test [15]. We applied appropriate correction factors in order to obtain consistent time series of FE data in those countries where earlier data were available. A detailed description of the approach we followed in order to arrive at a meaningful time series for the STD variable is provided in the Appendix. 4. Results Estimation of the dynamic model of equation (1) has to be treated with care. The presence of a lagged dependent variable among the regressors means that not only the OLS estimator but also the usual within estimator is biased and inconsistent because the lagged endogenous variable is correlated to the error term [7]. One solution to this problem is to apply a two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimation, differencing the data and employing as an instrumental variable the level of the endogenous variable two periods lagged [2, 3]; [36] have applied this technique. Arellano and Bond [4] have proposed a generalized method of moments (GMM) procedure that is more efficient than the Anderson and Hsiao [2] estimator because it utilizes many more instruments by taking advantage of the orthogonality conditions that exist between lagged levels of the dependent variable and the disturbance term. We used this GMM estimator and report results in Table 2 6. The model was estimated for the whole sample as well as for two sub-samples comprising North American and European data respectively, 3 See e.g. IEA s Energy Information Centre focusing on transport: 4 See e.g. 5 See 6 We also performed estimations based on OLS, the Within estimator with OLS and the Within estimator with two stage least squares. As the GMM procedure is clearly superior to these methods for the reasons mentioned above, we do not report their results for the sake of brevity. 11

12 since these are the regions whose data dominate in the whole sample. In all cases we report heteroskedasticity and serial correlation consistent standard errors. The hypothesis of no second-order autocorrelation in the residuals, which is fundamental for the consistency of the Arellano Bond estimator, cannot be rejected. Table 2: Regression results for equation (1). Countries Crosssections Sample size λ α 1 α 2,0 α 3 α 4 Autocorrel. All *** *** *** [20.270] -[1.350] -[6.580] [2.490] -[0.130] N. America *** *** * [9.180] [0.160] -[3.180] [1.770] -[0.170] EU *** *** *** [26.760] -[1.000] -[4.190] [3.760] [0.320] Notes: See text for explanation of coefficients. Estimation was carried out with the Arellano and Bond [4] GMM procedure. t-statistics, calculated with heteroskedasticity and serial correlation robust standard errors, are shown in brackets. *, ** and *** denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively. The last column reports the probability of the Arellano- Bond test for second order serial correlation of the residuals. Out of the five price lags included in equation (1) only current prices (lag order zero) were found to be significant, both in the whole sample and in the American and European subsets; this suggests that any longer term effects are captured by the autoregressive endogenous term. The autoregressive coefficient λ varies between 0.65 (for North America) and 0.78 (for Europe). This implies that between 22% and 35% of the long-term adjustment of fuel consumption due to prices, income and standards takes place in the first year. This quite high adjustment rate is expected because newcar FE is the dependent variable; in contrast, [18], using fleet-average FE, found a 6% annual adjustment. The dynamic model allows us to distinguish between short-run and long-run effects. The short-run effects of standards and fuel prices are significant and range from 0.14 to 0.24 and from 0.04 to 0.09 respectively. Per capita income turns out to be insignificant in this equation, for the whole sample as well as for the American and European subsets. Long-term impacts of FE standards (i.e. the short-run coefficients divided by 1-λ) vary between 0.46 (for the whole sample) and 0.99 (for North America), whereas long-term price effects range from 0.20 (for Europe) to 0.28 (for the whole sample). For US data alone (not shown in Table 2), the long-term price elasticity is estimated at 0.29, compared to the value of 0.22 that Austin and Dinan [5] found on the basis of partial equilibrium analysis 7. Finally, in all cases the deterministic time trend was found to be statistically insignificant and very close to zero. 7 The elasticity that [5] found is positive because it refers to the effect on fuel economy, whereas we use fuel consumption as a variable; see also footnote 1. 12

13 5. Policy implications The results from our econometric model can be used to provide answers to some policy questions which are at the center of related discussions worldwide. Do fuel economy standards make a difference? Table 2 shows that FE standards enter significantly in equation (1), with coefficients that are higher (in absolute terms) than those of fuel prices, in the whole sample as well as in the North American and European sub-samples. This is already an indication that standards have indeed made a difference in the evolution of automobile fuel consumption. In order to further examine whether the adoption of standards has been crucial for FE developments, we split the sample in pre-standard and with standards sub-samples for those cross-sections with available data. This is not possible with US data as the whole post-1975 period is under the with standards regime (see Appendix for more explanations). Such a separation is possible, however, in Japan and 7 European countries (Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Sweden and the UK), where available data cover the pre-standard period and the with standards period from 1995 onwards (170 observations in total). Figure 1b shows the evolution of new-car fuel consumption in some of these countries; European countries not illustrated in this Figure experienced a very similar evolution. Since data in these 8 countries can be split into periods with and without standards, it makes sense to test whether the adoption of standards should be viewed as a structural change in the data series. For the pre-standard and with standards periods as well as for the entire period, we re-estimated equation (1) minus the STD variable (since this is constant throughout the pre-standard period). We conducted these two regressions jointly for the 7 EU countries and Japan. We performed a Wald test and a Chow [10] test in order to examine the stability of the estimated coefficients. The null hypothesis of these tests is that of coefficient stability, meaning that there is no structural break in the series. Following the notation of equation (1), the null hypothesis of the Wald test is: H 0 : λ pre = λ ; α 1pre = α 1 ; α 2,0pre = α 2,0 ; α 4pre = α 4 where the pre index denotes the estimated coefficient for the pre-standard sample. Τhe Wald test for H 0 gave a χ 2 (4)-statistic of 95.99, which corresponds to a p-value of for the 8-country sample. Furthermore, the Chow test gave an F-statistic of 3.071, which, for 170 observations and 4 parameters, yields a p-value of The rejection of the null hypothesis by both tests indicates a structural break in 1995: pre coefficients are different from those estimated for the whole sample period. We had reached a similar conclusion in an earlier paper [50], where we had also tested for a structural break in simple equations including an intercept, a time trend and post dummies for both the intercept and trend. 13

14 The above results seem to provide a clear indication that the adoption of FE regulations or similar voluntary targets has indeed made a difference in the evolution of automobile fuel economy over the years, and also to the evolution of total automobile fuel consumption. If it had not been for FE standards, average new-car fuel consumption would not have improved at the rates that have been observed in Europe and Japan in recent years, and this would most probably have happened in the US as well. Furthermore, bearing in mind the overall increase in vehicle kilometers traveled during the last decades, total fuel consumption would also have been considerably higher in the absence of standards. 8 This finding does not imply that there are no better alternatives to FE standards but just that, ceteris paribus, fuel economy and total fuel use would have been worse without them. What would be the equivalent fuel price increase of tighter fuel economy standards? As already mentioned, the results in Table 2 indicate that the STD coefficient is higher in absolute terms than the price coefficients. In America, the absolute ratio of the STD coefficient to the price coefficient is 2.5; in Europe the corresponding ratio is 5.1. This means e.g. that a 20% lower (i.e. tighter) fuel consumption standard (expressed in liters per 100 km) might yield the same improvements in new-car fuel consumption as an increase in retail fuel prices of 50% in America and 102% in Europe. This implies that in Europe, where a target of new-car 120 g CO 2 /km is currently discussed for the year 2012 (a 25% decrease compared to about 160 g CO 2 /km realized in the year 2004), if standards are not to be tightened then retail fuel prices might have to double in order to have an equivalent effect. Similarly, an increase of the current CAFE car standard of 27.5 mpg by 3 mpg, which is a 10% reduction in liters per 100 km, would be equivalent to increasing the gasoline price relative to the average US price in 2004 by 45 US cents per gallon (in 2004 prices). This price rise is higher than that of [38], who estimated an increase by 11 cents per gallon to yield the same FE benefits as a 3 mpg higher CAFE standard, and closer to that of [5], who estimated that cents per gallon would be equally effective with an increase of the CAFE standard by 3.8 mpg. It should be noted, however, that these two studies also take into account the long-run impacts on gasoline demand: a tighter standard might induce more driving (the so called rebound effect) and hence would save less fuel than expected, whereas higher fuel prices would discourage driving of all cars and would thus yield additional fuel savings. Hence our estimates are consistent with those from the aforementioned studies. What would be the long-run effect of the two policies (tighter standards vs. higher fuel taxes) on total fuel consumption? To provide a rough assessment, it is reasonable to assume a rebound effect of 20%, i.e. that the total distance traveled annually by a car increases by 2% for every 10% improvement in fuel economy [27, 28], so that the overall effect of a 10% tighter standard on fuel consumption would come down to 8 Greene [14] argues that the CAFE program has saved hundreds of billions of gallons of fuel in the US since

15 8% 9. Over a period of years (when most cars would have been replaced by the new fuel efficient ones) such a standard would yield total fuel savings of approximately 8%. Based on the results of Table 2 and the above mentioned ratio of STD coefficient to price coefficients, the same fuel savings could be equivalently attained through a fuel price increase of 20% or 36 US cents per gallon (at 2004 prices); obviously this is a lower increase than in the case where we ignored the rebound effect. Alternatively, ignoring the coefficients of Table 2 and assuming instead a long-run price elasticity of total gasoline consumption of 0.39 like Austin and Dinan [5] did, the 8% reduction in fuel use would require a 20.5% increase in fuel prices, or 37 cents per gallon almost the same amount as that of our calculations based on equation (1). How might new-car fuel economy evolve without stricter standards and at today s fuel prices? As mentioned above, there are intense ongoing discussions in the EU regarding future CO 2 emission targets. Environmentalists and numerous analysts point to the need for adopting a 120 g CO 2 /km new-car mandatory target for the year 2012 or later, instead of the current voluntary industry commitment (which is unlikely to be fulfilled) to achieve 140 g CO 2 /km by 2008/2009. On the other hand, several European long-term energy and transport models assume that automobile fuel economy will continue to improve at fast rates (similar to those observed in Europe between 1995 and 2003) even without post-2010 FE regulations (see e.g. the review in [49]). Observing the results for coefficient α 1 in Table 2, it is evident that the deterministic time trend of equation (2) is insignificant and almost zero, in the whole sample and in the American and European sub-samples alike. Note that this time trend is intended to capture the composite effect of autonomous technical progress, i.e. progress that is not induced by high energy prices nor by FE standards, and other factors that are not explicitly addressed by the explanatory variables. Examples of such factors are changing consumer preferences in favor of diesel cars, which would reduce average fuel consumption 10, or expanded availability of safety equipment and other amenities (e.g. air conditioning systems, electrically controlled items) even in small cars, which would make a car heavier and more fuel consuming. Increasing consumer awareness for climate change, if any, would eventually be included in this time trend too. Bearing this in mind, the observation that the time trend in equation (1) is almost zero does not necessarily mean that there has been no autonomous technical progress in 9 However, [44] estimate that the rebound effect diminishes as private income rises and find a long-run rebound effect of 10% for California. 10 As already mentioned, the sharp increase of diesel sales in Europe after 1995 should not be entirely attributed to the industry s commitment for more fuel efficient cars. For example, environmental regulations that require significant cuts in particulate emissions from diesel vehicles have induced technological breakthroughs in the design of diesel engines that a) have made diesel cars more attractive to consumers (e.g. achieving low noise levels and fast acceleration rates that are similar or even better than their gasoline counterparts) and b) have partly improved fuel economy as well. 15

16 vehicle fuel economy over the last 30 years. A more plausible interpretation is that automotive technology advances in other fields and changing consumer preferences towards safer and more comfortable cars have canceled out any autonomous technical progress achieved during this period. The major policy implication of such a result is that, without stricter FE standards and at fuel prices around or below $40 50 (in 2004 prices) per barrel, one should not expect any marked FE improvements in the future in the absence of major technological breakthroughs or an economic recession. Although this finding is not reflected in many European studies (which tend to be optimistic), it is in line with the assumptions made in an international study of the World Business Council on Sustainable Development jointly with the International Energy Agency [21, 47]. In America this assumption of almost zero autonomous improvement is already reflected in official US studies [17]. Are taxes always the most efficient measure? From an economic point of view, an externality is tackled most effectively by imposing an appropriate tax and letting the market work. As mentioned in the introductory section, according to some analysts consumer myopia is a reason that may render fuel taxation inefficient. Analyses like [5], [38] and others refute this finding and estimate that raising fuel taxes causes much lower welfare costs than regulatory options such as imposing FE standards. However, even if these studies are better representations of reality, they employ a partial equilibrium framework and do not account for the effects on those economic sectors that use fuel as an intermediate good, which may be significantly affected by e.g. a 20% increase in retail gasoline prices. Available general equilibrium analyses address the impact of one policy only: either that of tighter standards [46] or that of higher fuel taxes (a possible application of [25]). In the absence of comparisons of the cost of policies on the whole economy, the conclusion that raising fuel taxes is a clearly superior option may have to be treated with caution. 11 Furthermore, an analyst should not overlook political aspects. The analysis of costs and benefits from tighter FE standards has mainly been performed in the US up to now, but the European scene is quite different. The European Union has decided to fulfill its commitment under the Kyoto protocol, which means that ever increasing transport CO 2 emissions must be curtailed. This is a political decision that has been taken irrespective of estimates on the external costs of transport energy consumption. In this context, if the EU is to restrain greenhouse gas emissions from transport, it is highly unlikely that any country would be willing to double automotive fuel prices in 11 Parry and Small [41] note that a higher gasoline tax in the US would hardly have any effect on production costs because only a very small fraction of gasoline is used for medium and heavy trucks. This argument obviously does not hold for Europe, where a higher fuel tax should be applied to gasoline and diesel alike as both fuels are used by private cars. This means that all enterprises using transportation fuel as an intermediate production input would be affected. 16

17 order to achieve its environmental goals. Apart from the questionable economic rationale behind already existing fuel taxes 12, the political acceptance of a considerably higher fuel tax is not given 13. This means that, no matter how accurate the welfare calculations are, the political economy of higher taxes cannot be ignored as it may prove to be decisive for the success of policy measures. Therefore, while in the US a combination of higher gasoline taxes with an improved CAFE program may be a prudent solution, in Europe mandatory or voluntary standards may be the only way to proceed. 6. Conclusions To our knowledge, this study is the first one that attempts to explore econometrically the impact of automobile fuel economy regulations around the world and to compare it with the effect of fuel prices, including all countries that have implemented some type of FE standards for a substantial period of time. Using data from official sources, we built an unbalanced panel comprising 384 observations from the US, Canada, Australia, Japan, Switzerland and 13 EU countries spanning a period between 1975 and We specified a reduced form dynamic panel model of FE and used the Arellano Bond GMM estimator to obtain consistent and unbiased estimates of the parameters of interest. Average annual fuel consumption of new cars was the dependent variable, and explanatory variables were lagged gasoline prices, the FE standard or target and real GDP per capita. Estimating the model for the whole sample and also for North American and European data separately, we found that the impact of a FE standard on new-car fuel consumption is more pronounced than that of a rise in fuel prices, which in principle should have been expected as standards (mandatory or voluntary) represent binding commitments for the automotive industry. Based on these estimates, we addressed three important and topical policy issues. Firstly, there seems to be sufficient evidence that if there were no FE standards or targets in force, new-car fuel consumption would not have improved at the rates that have been observed in Europe and Japan in recent years (or it may have even deteriorated), and this would most probably have happened in the US as well; as a result, transportation energy use would have increased more rapidly. Secondly, in order to avoid tightening FE standards by 10% in the US, one would have to raise fuel prices by 20% (or 36 US cents per gallon at 2004 prices) in order to attain the same fuel savings, taking into account the rebound effect. In Europe, if standards are not to be tightened then retail fuel prices might have to double in order to attain the currently discussed target of 120 g CO 2 /km in the future. Thirdly, without higher fuel prices and/or tighter FE standards, one should not expect any marked improvements in fuel 12 Parry et al. [42] note that...the externality rationale for higher fuel taxes, or more stringent fuel economy standards, may well have come and gone. (p. 30) and favor user charges per mile driven. 13 [41] provides examples of public opposition to higher fuel taxes in the US and the UK, and West and Williams [48] note that...the practical relevance of any result on optimal gasoline taxes is limited by political constraints; the existing tax in the U.S. is far below what almost any economic analysis would indicate as the optimum (p. 18). 17

18 economy under business as usual conditions. Potential fuel savings due to autonomous technical progress in the past have been counterbalanced by changes in consumer preferences towards safer and more comfortable cars, and there is no reason to believe why this trend should not continue in the future in the absence of impressive technological breakthroughs or an economic recession. European policy makers might need to consider this issue carefully because some recent European studies tend to be optimistic in this respect. Finally, we attempted to provide some explanations as regards the question why raising fuel taxes may not lead to the economically most efficient solution. In the US tighter FE standards and higher gasoline taxes need to be carefully examined against their welfare impact, and a combination of both policy options should not be excluded. Conversely, it is hardly possible to increase fuel taxes in Europe because of their already high levels. Moreover, as a tax increase would have to apply to both gasoline and diesel fuel in Europe, the effect of such a measure in the whole European economy has to be considered with great care. Acknowledgments The second author has conducted his part of the research in the framework of a Marie Curie Fellowship that he has received from the European Community within its Sixth Framework Programme. An earlier version of the manuscript was presented at the 29th International Conference of the International Association for Energy Economics and the 2006 International Energy Workshop, and we appreciate all comments we received. We also thank Karl Storchmann for his very useful comments on an earlier draft. Views expressed in this article and remaining errors or omissions are the sole responsibility of the authors. References 1. F. An, A. Sauer, Comparison of passenger vehicle fuel economy and greenhouse gas emission standards around the world, Report prepared for the Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Arlington, VA, T.W. Anderson, C. Hsiao, Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data, J. Econometrics 18 (1982) M. Arellano, Α note on the Αnderson-Ηsiao estimator for panel data. Econ. Letters 31 (1989) M. Arellano, S. Bond, Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev. Econ. Stud. 58 (1991) D. Austin, T. Dinan, Clearing the air: The costs and consequences of higher CAFE standards and increased gasoline taxes, J. Environ. Econom. Management 50 (2005)

Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles

Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles Date Issue Brief # I S S U E B R I E F Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles A Summary of Priority Research Questions

More information

Beyond Business-as-Usual: Achieving a Paradigm Shift towards Low-Carbon Transport

Beyond Business-as-Usual: Achieving a Paradigm Shift towards Low-Carbon Transport Cyprus University of Technology From the SelectedWorks of Theodoros Zachariadis 2012 Beyond Business-as-Usual: Achieving a Paradigm Shift towards Low-Carbon Transport Theodoros Zachariadis, Cyprus University

More information

The impact of fiscal policies and standards on passenger car CO 2 emissions in EU countries

The impact of fiscal policies and standards on passenger car CO 2 emissions in EU countries Energy Production and Management in the 21st Century, Vol. 1 609 The impact of fiscal policies and standards on passenger car CO 2 emissions in EU countries A. Ajanovic & R. Haas Vienna University of Technology,

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 24.8.2006 COM(2006) 463 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT Implementing the Community Strategy to Reduce

More information

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum Preliminary version Abstract This paper

More information

Vehicle Controls and Petrol Demand in Hong Kong

Vehicle Controls and Petrol Demand in Hong Kong Vehicle Controls and Petrol Demand in Hong Kong W. David Walls School of Economics and Finance University of Hong Kong Pokfulam Road Hong Kong Tel: 852 2859 1049 Fax: 852 2548 1152 Email: wdwalls@hkusub.hku.hk

More information

EXPLORING THE POTENTIAL FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN TURKEY SIMONE TAGLIAPIETRA SENIOR RESEARCHER, FONDAZIONE ENI ENRICO MATTEI

EXPLORING THE POTENTIAL FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN TURKEY SIMONE TAGLIAPIETRA SENIOR RESEARCHER, FONDAZIONE ENI ENRICO MATTEI EXPLORING THE POTENTIAL FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN TURKEY SIMONE TAGLIAPIETRA SENIOR RESEARCHER, FONDAZIONE ENI ENRICO MATTEI Energy efficiency is one of the key crossroads between energy, climate and economic

More information

Evaluating the Economic Impact of Decarbonisation Policies in Road Transport

Evaluating the Economic Impact of Decarbonisation Policies in Road Transport Evaluating the Economic Impact of Decarbonisation Policies in Road Transport Theodoros Zachariadis Associate Professor and Dean Faculty of Geotechnical Sciences and Environmental Management Cyprus University

More information

AN ESTIMATION OF THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE IN MONTANA, AND PROJECTIONS OF FUTURE GASOLINE CONSUMPTION. Aaron David McNay

AN ESTIMATION OF THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE IN MONTANA, AND PROJECTIONS OF FUTURE GASOLINE CONSUMPTION. Aaron David McNay AN ESTIMATION OF THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE IN MONTANA, AND PROJECTIONS OF FUTURE GASOLINE CONSUMPTION by Aaron David McNay A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of

More information

What Do We Know about Gasoline Demand Elasticities?

What Do We Know about Gasoline Demand Elasticities? What Do We Know about Gasoline Demand Elasticities? Carol A. Dahl Colorado School of Mines Working Paper http://dahl.mines.edu/courses/courses/dedd/dahl_g06.pdf November 2006 Numerous studies have been

More information

5. Empirical Results. 5.1 Event study analysis

5. Empirical Results. 5.1 Event study analysis 5. Empirical Results 5.1 Event study analysis Our main empirical results of event study are presented in the following sections. Rather than report full details of the event study results, we only provide

More information

Highlights. Figure 1. World Marketed Energy Consumption by Region,

Highlights. Figure 1. World Marketed Energy Consumption by Region, Highlights World energy consumption is projected to increase by 71 percent from 3 to 23. Fossil fuels continue to supply much of the energy used worldwide, and oil remains the dominant energy source. In

More information

A decade of oil demand

A decade of oil demand A decade of oil demand World oil demand Eni has recently published the thirteenth edition of the 2014 World Oil and Gas Review, the annual statistical review on the world oil and gas market and the refining

More information

Methodology to estimate the effect of energy efficiency on growth

Methodology to estimate the effect of energy efficiency on growth Methodology to estimate the effect of energy efficiency on growth Report prepared for The Climate Institute March 2013 2 Contents 1 Introduction... 5 2 Energy efficiency and economic growth... 7 3 Data...

More information

New emission test procedure What does it mean for fleet managers?

New emission test procedure What does it mean for fleet managers? New emission test procedure What does it mean for fleet managers? What s next? Q4 2017 Tailpipe CO 2 emissions have been a hot topic ever since global warming became a major concern, and the automotive

More information

A rm s-length transfer prices for the remuneration of

A rm s-length transfer prices for the remuneration of 1164 (Vol. 25, No. 20) BNA INSIGHTS Cost Plus Markups for Manufacturing Entities: The Effect of Size on Fully Loaded Versus Variable Costs The authors analyze the statistical and economic significance

More information

The Impact of Building Energy Codes on the Energy Efficiency of Residential Space Heating in European countries A Stochastic Frontier Approach

The Impact of Building Energy Codes on the Energy Efficiency of Residential Space Heating in European countries A Stochastic Frontier Approach The Impact of Building Energy Codes on the Energy Efficiency of Residential Space Heating in European countries A Stochastic Frontier Approach Aurélien Saussay, International Energy Agency, Paris, France

More information

Is There an Environmental Kuznets Curve: Empirical Evidence in a Cross-section Country Data

Is There an Environmental Kuznets Curve: Empirical Evidence in a Cross-section Country Data Is There an Environmental Kuznets Curve: Empirical Evidence in a Cross-section Country Data Aleksandar Vasilev * Abstract: This paper tests the effect of gross domestic product (GDP) per capita on pollution,

More information

WIND POWER TARGETS FOR EUROPE: 75,000 MW by 2010

WIND POWER TARGETS FOR EUROPE: 75,000 MW by 2010 About EWEA EWEA is the voice of the wind industry actively promoting the utilisation of wind power in Europe and worldwide. EWEA members from over 4 countries include 2 companies, organisations, and research

More information

Background and objectives

Background and objectives Workshop on greenhouse gas emission projections 12-13 December 2006, European Environment Agency, Copenhagen Background and objectives André Jol Head of Group climate change and energy European Environment

More information

The Implications of Global Ecological Elasticities for Carbon Control: A STIRPAT Formulation

The Implications of Global Ecological Elasticities for Carbon Control: A STIRPAT Formulation The Implications of Global Ecological Elasticities for Carbon Control: A STIRPAT Formulation Carol D. Tallarico Dominican University Arvid C. Johnson Dominican University In this paper, we analyze the

More information

STUDY ON ECONOMIC AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACTS OF ENERGY TAXATION: SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS DG TAXUD C5

STUDY ON ECONOMIC AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACTS OF ENERGY TAXATION: SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS DG TAXUD C5 STUDY ON ECONOMIC AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACTS OF ENERGY TAXATION: SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS DG TAXUD C5 Background The scope of the study was to update the impact assessment of the Commission 1997 energy tax

More information

Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs

Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs Sustainable Development and Planning V 947 Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs M. Asali Petroleum Studies Department, Research Division, OPEC,

More information

Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits

Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits by Kenneth B Medlock III El Paso Corporation Department of Economics, Rice University Ron Soligo Department

More information

INTERNATIONAL ENERGY AGENCY EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Emissions Trading for Climate Policy

INTERNATIONAL ENERGY AGENCY EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Emissions Trading for Climate Policy INTERNATIONAL ENERGY AGENCY EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Act Locally, Trade Globally Emissions Trading for Climate Policy INTERNATIONAL ENERGY AGENCY The International Energy Agency (IEA) is an autonomous body which

More information

The impact of more efficient new passenger cars on energy consumption in EU-15 countries

The impact of more efficient new passenger cars on energy consumption in EU-15 countries The impact of more efficient new passenger cars on energy consumption in EU-15 countries Amela Ajanovic, Vienna University of Technology Energy Economics Group, Austria ajanovic@eeg.tuwien.ac.at Lee Schipper

More information

Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02)

Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02) Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02) Appendix 1. Data Description Table A. Countries in the sample. Abbreviation Country AUS* Australia BEL

More information

Long-term Market Analysis Nordics and Europe Executive summary

Long-term Market Analysis Nordics and Europe Executive summary Long-term Market Analysis Nordics and Europe 2018 2040 Executive summary 1 December 2018 Europe is set to develop a low carbon power system with significant contribution from renewable energy sources.

More information

Potentials and Costs for GHG Mitigation in the Transport Sector

Potentials and Costs for GHG Mitigation in the Transport Sector Revised version of manuscript published in Proceedings of the 18 th International Symposium on Transport & Air Pollution, 18-19 May 2010 in Duebendorf/Switzerland. Potentials and Costs for GHG Mitigation

More information

Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China

Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China Auburn University Department of Economics Working Paper Series Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China Liping Gao and Hyeongwoo Kim Georgia Southern University; Auburn University

More information

British Columbia s carbon tax: Greenhouse gas emission and economic trends since introduction

British Columbia s carbon tax: Greenhouse gas emission and economic trends since introduction British Columbia s carbon tax: Greenhouse gas emission and economic trends since introduction Sierra Rayne a,, Kaya Forest b a Chemologica Research, 318 Rose Street, PO Box 74, Mortlach, Saskatchewan,

More information

BUSINESSEUROPE views on the review of the Energy Efficiency Directive

BUSINESSEUROPE views on the review of the Energy Efficiency Directive May 2016 BUSINESSEUROPE views on the review of the Energy Efficiency Directive Key messages Being energy efficient is in the DNA of European entrepreneurs. Industry has been at the forefront of efforts

More information

The Cost of the Kyoto Protocol: Moving Forward on Climate Change Policy While Preserving Economic Growth

The Cost of the Kyoto Protocol: Moving Forward on Climate Change Policy While Preserving Economic Growth The Cost of the Kyoto Protocol: Moving Forward on Climate Change Policy While Preserving Economic Growth Dr. Margo Thorning Managing Director, International Council for Capital Formation Brussels Office:

More information

Energy Subsidies, Economic Growth, and CO 2 emissions

Energy Subsidies, Economic Growth, and CO 2 emissions Energy Subsidies, Economic Growth, and CO 2 emissions Gabriela Mundaca The World Bank October 18, 2018 Presentation based on 2 papers 1. Energy Subsidies, Public Investment and Endogenous Growth. (2017).

More information

Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design.

Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design. Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design. Miguel Rodríguez http://webs.uvigo.es/miguel.r Yolanda Pena Universidade de Vigo & rede (Research in Energy, Innnovation

More information

Is Low-Carbon Road Freight Possible?

Is Low-Carbon Road Freight Possible? POLICY BRIEF Decarbonising Transport Initiative Is Low-Carbon Road Freight Possible? Road freight is a backbone of the economy, irreplaceable for moving goods. But it burns 17 million barrels of oil per

More information

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods Mark R. Jacobsen, 1,5 Christopher R. Knittel, 2,5 James M. Sallee, 3,5 Arthur A. van Benthem 4,5 December 8, 2014

More information

Cars, Carbon Taxes and CO 2 Emissions

Cars, Carbon Taxes and CO 2 Emissions Cars, Carbon Taxes and CO 2 Emissions Julius J. Andersson envecon 2017 London School of Economics and Political Science 3 March 2017 Julius J. Andersson (LSE) Cars, Carbon Taxes and CO 2 Emissions 3 March

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the document. Proposal for a Council Regulation

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the document. Proposal for a Council Regulation EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 11.1.2018 SWD(2018) 6 final PART 3/4 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Council Regulation on establishing the European

More information

Questions and Answers on the Decision on effort sharing

Questions and Answers on the Decision on effort sharing MEMO/08/797 Brussels, 17 December 2008 Questions and Answers on the Decision on effort sharing 1. How is the 20% greenhouse gas target shared between sectors and Member States? The total effort for greenhouse

More information

Automobility in Brazil, Russia, India, and China A collaborative study by the RAND Corporation and the Institute for Mobility Research

Automobility in Brazil, Russia, India, and China A collaborative study by the RAND Corporation and the Institute for Mobility Research Automobility in Brazil, Russia, India, and China A collaborative study by the RAND Corporation and the Institute for Mobility Research Charlene Rohr Presentation to the Konrad Adenauer Foundation 18 February

More information

Rebound Effect: Overview and Recent Research. Joshua Linn NYU Transportation Workshop October 2011

Rebound Effect: Overview and Recent Research. Joshua Linn NYU Transportation Workshop October 2011 Rebound Effect: Overview and Recent Research Joshua Linn NYU Transportation Workshop October 2011 What Is the Rebound Effect? Passenger vehicle fuel economy regulation Corporate average fuel economy (CAFE)

More information

B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia

B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia IMPACTS OF ENERGY TAXES AND SUBSIDIES B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia Keywords: energy taxes, energy subsidies, price gap approach

More information

Global energy trends in road freight transport

Global energy trends in road freight transport Global energy trends in road freight transport Maja Piecyk Alan McKinnon LRN 2009 Cardiff 10th September 2009 Research background This research was carried out as part of the project undertaken with the

More information

Economic Concepts. Economic Concepts and Applications to Climate Change

Economic Concepts. Economic Concepts and Applications to Climate Change Economic Concepts and Applications to Climate Change Economic Concepts When markets work and when they don t t work Policy Interventions to correct market failures Recent research in climate change 1 Part

More information

Implementation of EU Postal Legislation. A guide to the transposition of EC Directive 97/67/EC as amended by Directive 2008/6/EC

Implementation of EU Postal Legislation. A guide to the transposition of EC Directive 97/67/EC as amended by Directive 2008/6/EC Implementation of EU Postal Legislation A guide to the transposition of EC Directive 97/67/EC as amended by Directive 2008/6/EC 2009 The purpose of this Guide This document is intended to serve as an explanatory

More information

Revisiting Energy Consumption and GDP: Evidence from Dynamic Panel Data Analysis

Revisiting Energy Consumption and GDP: Evidence from Dynamic Panel Data Analysis MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Revisiting Energy Consumption and GDP: Evidence from Dynamic Panel Data Analysis Sabri Nayan and Norsiah Kadir and Mahyudin Ahmad and Mat Saad Abdullah Universiti Teknologi

More information

The Effect of Information and Communication Technology on Energy Consumption in the European Union Countries

The Effect of Information and Communication Technology on Energy Consumption in the European Union Countries The Effect of Information and Communication Technology on Energy Consumption in the European Union Countries Çiğdem Börke TUNALI Department of Economics, Faculty of Economics, Istanbul University, Merkez

More information

Figure 1. Energy dependency of EU member states in 2004 (%)

Figure 1. Energy dependency of EU member states in 2004 (%) The ESTONIAN ENERGY SECTOR IN COMPARISON TO OTHER COUNTRIES Einari Kisel The n energy sector has undergone several significant changes in the past few years. The following article represents an effort

More information

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series Social Rate of Return to R&D on Various Energy Technologies: Where Should We Invest More? A Study of G7 Countries Roula Inglesi-Lotz

More information

Best Practices for Promoting the Renovation of Buildings and the Interlinkage with the EPBD

Best Practices for Promoting the Renovation of Buildings and the Interlinkage with the EPBD Workshop on Energy Efficiency, Savings obligations, public building targets and the promotion of CHP Policy Department A European Parliament Best Practices for Promoting the Renovation of Buildings and

More information

Keidanren Action Plan on the Environment (Section on Global Warming Measures) Reassessment Report

Keidanren Action Plan on the Environment (Section on Global Warming Measures) Reassessment Report Keidanren Action Plan on the Environment (Section on Global Warming Measures) Reassessment Report 19 November 2013 Keidanren 1. Overview of the Keidanren Action Plan on the Environment (1) Background Prior

More information

The Kyoto Protocol and EU competitiveness

The Kyoto Protocol and EU competitiveness The Kyoto Protocol and EU competitiveness Paper prepared for the 6h GTAP Conference, June 12-14, The Hague, The Netherlands Johannes Bollen 1, Henri de Groot 2, Ton Manders 2 and Paul Tang 2 1 RIVM National

More information

Technical Report IMACLIM. Emissions estimation method. Model description

Technical Report IMACLIM. Emissions estimation method. Model description Technical Report IMACLIM Emissions estimation method Emissions are computed ex post, on the basis of modelling results and assumptions from three distinct sources: the IMACLIM-R and POLES models produce

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER. The Rebound Effect for Passenger Vehicles. J o s h u a L i n n P St. NW Washington, DC

DISCUSSION PAPER. The Rebound Effect for Passenger Vehicles. J o s h u a L i n n P St. NW Washington, DC DISCUSSION PAPER Jul y 2013; revised November 2013 RFF DP 13-19-REV The Rebound Effect for Passenger Vehicles J o s h u a L i n n 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036 202-328-5000 www.rff.org The Rebound

More information

What STIRPAT tells about effects of population and affluence on environmental impact?

What STIRPAT tells about effects of population and affluence on environmental impact? What STIRPAT tells about effects of population and affluence on environmental impact? Taoyuan Wei 1 July 21, 2010 Abstract In the literature of STIRPAT application to environmental impacts of population

More information

Tough caps on CO 2 (UPDATED VERSION JUNE 06)

Tough caps on CO 2 (UPDATED VERSION JUNE 06) WWF International Groe Präsidentenstr. 10 10178 Berlin Germany Tel.: +49-30-308742-0 Direkt: -21 Fax: +49-30-308742-50 teriete@wwf.de www.panda.org Tough caps on CO 2 (UPDATED VERSION JUNE 06) WWF recommendations

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 19.12.2007 COM(2007) 856 final 2007/0297 (COD) C6-0022/08 Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL Setting emission performance

More information

APPRAISAL OF POLICY APPROACHES FOR EFFECTIVELY INFLUENCING PRIVATE PASSENGER VEHICLE FUEL CONSUMPTION AND ASSOCIATED EMISSIONS.

APPRAISAL OF POLICY APPROACHES FOR EFFECTIVELY INFLUENCING PRIVATE PASSENGER VEHICLE FUEL CONSUMPTION AND ASSOCIATED EMISSIONS. Proceedings 28-29th August, ITRN2017 Dublin Dennehy: Evidence based analysis to guide private passenger vehicle policy decisions APPRAISAL OF POLICY APPROACHES FOR EFFECTIVELY INFLUENCING PRIVATE PASSENGER

More information

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model 30/10/2013 The Belgian TIMES model 1.1 General overview: history» INTERNATIONAL DIMENSION» Developed by ETSAP implementing agreement of IEA as successor of MARKAL» History of 30 years development» Software

More information

FORECASTING LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER STATES: IS LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY CHANGING AS EXPECTED?

FORECASTING LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER STATES: IS LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY CHANGING AS EXPECTED? Interdisciplinary Description of Complex Systems 16(3-B), 504-523, 2018 FORECASTING LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER STATES: IS LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY CHANGING AS EXPECTED? Berislav Žmuk*,

More information

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many THE HOUSEHOLD SECTOR IN THE SMETS-WOUTERS DSGE MODEL: COMPARISONS WITH THE STANDARD OPTIMAL GROWTH MODEL L. Tesfatsion, Econ 502, Fall 2014 Last Revised: 19 November 2014 Basic References: [1] ** L. Tesfatsion,

More information

Trends in Transport Intensity across Europe

Trends in Transport Intensity across Europe Trends in Transport Intensity across Europe Dominic Stead Research Fellow Bartlett School of Planning University College London United Kingdom EJTIR, 0, no. 0 (2000), pp. 27-39 Received:1999/2000 Accepted:

More information

Energy, Electricity and Nuclear Power Estimates for the Period up to 2050

Energy, Electricity and Nuclear Power Estimates for the Period up to 2050 REFERENCE DATA SERIES No. 1 2018 Edition Energy, Electricity and Nuclear Power Estimates for the Period up to 2050 @ ENERGY, ELECTRICITY AND NUCLEAR POWER ESTIMATES FOR THE PERIOD UP TO 2050 REFERENCE

More information

Training programme GHG emission trends and projections

Training programme GHG emission trends and projections Training programme GHG emission trends and projections 11 th lead reviewer meeting. Bonn, 7 March 2014 Barbara Muik, Programme Officer UNFCCC secretariat, MDA Outline of presentation Overview of the module

More information

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services By Ian Small of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. This article (1) reviews how price-cost mark-ups

More information

Analysis and comparison of national and EU-wide projections of greenhouse gas emissions

Analysis and comparison of national and EU-wide projections of greenhouse gas emissions 1 Topic report 1/2002 Analysis and comparison of national and EU-wide projections of greenhouse gas emissions Prepared by: Martin Cames, Wolf Garber, Ann Gardiner, Jelle van Minnen, Bernd Strobel, Peter

More information

PART I. COUNTRY-BASED DATA AND INDICATORS

PART I. COUNTRY-BASED DATA AND INDICATORS PART I. COUNTRY-BASED DATA AND INDICATORS Ch. 2 GHG Emissions and Trends 11 Ch. 3 Emissions Projections 17 Ch. 4 Per Capita Emissions 21 Ch. 5 Emissions Intensity 25 Ch. 6 Cumulative Emissions 31 Ch. 7

More information

Abstract. 1. Introduction

Abstract. 1. Introduction A review of the history of emission legislation, urban and national transport trends and their impact on transport emissions A.Smith,H.Davies University of Central England, Birmingham, UK Abstract With

More information

WWF recommendations for cap levels for Phase 2 of the EU ETS

WWF recommendations for cap levels for Phase 2 of the EU ETS WWF International Groe Präsidentenstr. 10 10178 Berlin Germany Tel.: +49-30-308742-0 Direkt: -21 Fax: +49-30-308742-50 teriete@wwf.de www.panda.org Tough caps on CO 2 WWF recommendations for cap levels

More information

Energy Use and CO 2 Emissions of Passenger Vehicles in Bahrain - A Case Study

Energy Use and CO 2 Emissions of Passenger Vehicles in Bahrain - A Case Study 2015 International Conference on Advances in Environment Research Volume 87 of IPCBEE (2015) DOI: 10.7763/IPCBEE. 2015. V87. 18 Energy Use and CO 2 Emissions of Passenger Vehicles in Bahrain - A Case Study

More information

Econ 1101 International Application Case Studies

Econ 1101 International Application Case Studies Econ 1101 International Application Case Studies InterApp 2: Fuel Consumption in Europe and the United States And Long-Run Elasticity of Demand By Thomas J. Holmes, Dept. of Economics, University of Minnesota

More information

Setting Emissions Reduction Targets in a Long-term Strategy: The Chilean Experience

Setting Emissions Reduction Targets in a Long-term Strategy: The Chilean Experience Setting Emissions Reduction Targets in a Long-term Strategy: The Chilean Experience Marcia Montedonico, Head of Socioenvironmental Development Area, Energy Center, University of Chile Rodrigo Palma-Behnke,

More information

Background to the consultation. Case Id: 10607d bbba-0c0dc66ac545 Date: 30/08/ :39:56

Background to the consultation. Case Id: 10607d bbba-0c0dc66ac545 Date: 30/08/ :39:56 Case Id: 10607d57-163-489-bbba-0c0dc66ac545 Date: 30/08/016 13:39:56 Consultation on the revision of Regulation (EU) No 443/009 and Regulation (EU) No 510/011 setting CO emission performance standards

More information

The Challenges of Clean Air - Local, Regional & Global A Possible Solution

The Challenges of Clean Air - Local, Regional & Global A Possible Solution The Challenges of Clean Air - Local, Regional & Global A Possible Solution ISATA Congress Dublin, Ireland - September Outline Summarize Progress To Date Highlight Remaining Problems Forecast Future Trends

More information

Draft ETUC position on the proposal for a regulation aimed at reducing CO2 emissions from new passenger cars (COM(2007)856)

Draft ETUC position on the proposal for a regulation aimed at reducing CO2 emissions from new passenger cars (COM(2007)856) Executive Committee Brussels, 04/05.03.2008 179. EX Item 11 on the agenda: Draft ETUC position on the proposal for a regulation aimed at reducing CO2 emissions from new passenger cars (COM(2007)856) The

More information

Environmentally Harmful Subsidies in the Transport Sector

Environmentally Harmful Subsidies in the Transport Sector Environmentally Harmful Subsidies in the Transport Sector Presentation at the Green Budget Europe conference 28 February 2011, Brussels By Nils Axel Braathen OECD, Environment Directorate 1 Background

More information

FHWA Forecasts of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT): May 2014

FHWA Forecasts of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT): May 2014 FHWA Forecasts of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT): May 2014 Office of Highway Policy Information Federal Highway Administration May 22, 2014 Highlights Long-Term Economic Outlook Under the IHS Baseline economic

More information

Review of the EU strategy to reduce CO 2 emissions and improve fuel efficiency from cars

Review of the EU strategy to reduce CO 2 emissions and improve fuel efficiency from cars EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL ENVIRONMENT Review of the EU strategy to reduce CO 2 emissions and improve fuel efficiency from cars Report on the Public Consultation June - August 2006 In line

More information

IMPLEMENTATION OF ARTICLE 33 and ARTICLE 41 OF DIRECTIVE 2009/73/EC regarding Gas Storage

IMPLEMENTATION OF ARTICLE 33 and ARTICLE 41 OF DIRECTIVE 2009/73/EC regarding Gas Storage IMPLEMENTATION OF ARTICLE 33 and ARTICLE 41 OF DIRECTIVE 2009/73/EC regarding Gas Storage CEER Monitoring Report 09 July 2012 Council of European Energy Regulators ASBL 28 rue le Titien, 1000 Bruxelles

More information

An Empirical Assessment of the Effectiveness of Green Policies

An Empirical Assessment of the Effectiveness of Green Policies An Empirical Assessment of the Effectiveness of Green Policies Julian Dieler a, Darko Jus b and Markus Zimmer a a ifo Institute for Economic Research, Munich b Center for Economic Studies (CES), Ludwig-Maximilians-University,

More information

Evidence on R&D Impact Using Macroeconomic and General Equilibrium Models

Evidence on R&D Impact Using Macroeconomic and General Equilibrium Models Evidence on R&D Impact Using Macroeconomic and General Equilibrium Models Executive summary One of the key elements of the Lisbon strategy is the target of raising R&D spending to 3% of GDP by 2010 for

More information

The Cancun Agreements: Land use, land-use change and forestry

The Cancun Agreements: Land use, land-use change and forestry Decision 2/CMP.6 The Cancun Agreements: Land use, land-use change and forestry The Conference of the Parties serving as the meeting of the Parties to the Kyoto Protocol, Affirming that the implementation

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the documents

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the documents EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 11.7.2012 SWD(2012) 214 final COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the documents Proposal for a regulation of the European

More information

III.2. Inventory developments in the euro area since the onset of the crisis ( 49 )

III.2. Inventory developments in the euro area since the onset of the crisis ( 49 ) III.2 Inventory developments in the euro area since the onset of the crisis III.2. Inventory developments in the euro area since the onset of the crisis ( 49 ) This section analyses the changes in inventory

More information

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence ECB - BoC Workshop : Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Adjustment 15-16 June 2011 Christiane Baumeister Ehsan U. Choudhri Lawrence Schembri

More information

Trade in Pollutive Industries and the Stringency of Environmental Regulations. Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum

Trade in Pollutive Industries and the Stringency of Environmental Regulations. Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum Trade in Pollutive Industries and the Stringency of Environmental Regulations Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-Universy of Bochum April 2015 Abstract This paper analyses the impact of trade

More information

Group III. Suzana Kahn Ribeiro. Transport Engineering Program Federal University of Rio de Janeiro Brazil CLA Transport Chapter IPCC WG III

Group III. Suzana Kahn Ribeiro. Transport Engineering Program Federal University of Rio de Janeiro Brazil CLA Transport Chapter IPCC WG III IPCC Outreach Event on AR4 Working Group III Suzana Kahn Ribeiro Transport Engineering Program Federal University of Rio de Janeiro Brazil CLA Transport Chapter IPCC WG III AR4 WG3 Carbon dioxide is the

More information

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Zahoor Haq Post-Doctoral Fellow, Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Guelph, Canada and Lecturer, WFP

More information

Towards the Use of Emission Taxes in Canada

Towards the Use of Emission Taxes in Canada Towards the Use of Emission Taxes in Canada Testimony before the Finance Committee Roundtable on Green Taxes, May 31, 21, Ottawa. Presented by Dr. Ross McKitrick Assistant Professor Department of Economics

More information

No. 02/10 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS

No. 02/10 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Empirical Evidence on the Effectiveness of Environmental Taxes Bruce Morley No. 02/10 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Department of Economics Empirical evidence on the effectiveness of environmental taxes

More information

The Political and Selective Use of Data: Cherry-Picking Climate Information in the White House. Dr. Peter H. Gleick Pacific Institute

The Political and Selective Use of Data: Cherry-Picking Climate Information in the White House. Dr. Peter H. Gleick Pacific Institute The Political and Selective Use of Data: Cherry-Picking Climate Information in the White House Dr. Peter H. Gleick Pacific Institute Initial Version: March 8, 2007 Updated and Expanded: June 1, 2007 Summary

More information

The PRIMES Energy Model

The PRIMES Energy Model EC4MACS Uncertainty Treatment The PRIMES Energy Model European Consortium for Modelling of Air Pollution and Climate Strategies - EC4MACS Editors: E3MLab, National Technical University of Athens (NTUA)

More information

EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in)

EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in) Econ. 240B, Second Half Daniel McFadden, 2001 EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in) Several oil refinery accidents in California in the Spring of 1999 restricted production of gasoline

More information

Framing Sustainable Consumption and Production: The Past and the Present

Framing Sustainable Consumption and Production: The Past and the Present Presentation for the conference Sustainable Consumption and Production How to Make it Possible? Vilnius, Lithuania, 19-20 March 2008 Framing Sustainable Consumption and Production: The Past and the Present

More information

TERM EEA-31 Transport emissions of greenhouse gases by mode

TERM EEA-31 Transport emissions of greenhouse gases by mode Indicator factsheet TERM 2003 02 EEA-31 Transport emissions of greenhouse gases by mode In the area of EEA-31, emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) from transport (excluding international transport) increased

More information

Questions and Answers on the Commission's proposal for effort sharing

Questions and Answers on the Commission's proposal for effort sharing MEMO/08/34 Brussels, 23 January 2008 Questions and Answers on the Commission's proposal for effort sharing 1. What is the Commission proposing? On 10 January 2007 the Commission adopted an energy and climate

More information

Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions From Transportation

Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions From Transportation Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions From Transportation David L. Greene Corporate Fellow Oak Ridge National Laboratory A presentation to the Legislative Commission on Global Climate Change April 25, 2006

More information

Energy efficiency and Energy Security in Europe

Energy efficiency and Energy Security in Europe Energy efficiency and Energy Security in Europe SECURE WP 5.8: Energy Demand SECURE Stakeholder Workshop ERSE, Milan, 18-19 January 2010 Andrea Bigano and Roberta Pierfederici with Emauela Menichetti (OME)

More information

The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage

The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage Dusan Drabik Graduate student Charles H. Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, USA dd387@cornell.edu Harry

More information