Entrepreneurs, Jobs, and Trade

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Entrepreneurs, Jobs, and Trade"

Transcription

1 Entrepreneurs, Jobs, and Trade Elias Dinopoulos University of Florida Bulent Unel Louisiana State University March 6, 2013 Abstract We propose a simple theory of personal income distribution, equilibrium unemployment, and interindustry trade, in which product markets are perfectly competitive and labor markets exhibit search related frictions. Individuals, based on their managerial talent, choose to become self-employed entrepreneurs and acquire more managerial capital, or they become workers and face the prospect of unemployment. We analyze the effects of trade on a small-open jobless economy and a two-country global economy. In the case of a small-open economy, improvements in international competitiveness raise the possibility of immiserizing recessions with higher unemployment, lower GDP, and lower aggregate welfare. Reductions in the costs of acquiring managerial capital or appropriate job-vacancy subsidies generally lead to lower unemployment rate, higher aggregate welfare, and higher income inequality. In a two-country global economy, a country exports the good with lower labor-market frictions or lower costs of managerial capital acquisition. Unilateral job-creating policies have asymmetric effects on income inequality and unemployment across countries, and ambiguous effects on welfare in each country. JEL Classification: F1, J2, J3, J6, L1 Keywords: Inequality, Managerial Capital, Search and Matching, Trade, Unemployment Elias Dinopoulos: Department of Economics, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL elias.dinopoulos@cba.ufl.edu; Tel: (352) Bulent Unel: Department of Economics, Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, LA bunel@lsu.edu; Tel: (225)

2 1 Introduction The last decade has witnessed substantial changes in the U.S. distribution of earnings. According to Haskel et al. (2012), since 2000 real earnings of most U.S. workers have declined independently of educational status, and corporate profits increased substantially reaching 12.4 percent of GDP in 2010 (the highest percentage in the pase 60 years). In addition, the share of U.S. income accounted by the top 1 percent earners rose steadily from 13.5 percent in 1995 to 16.5 in 2000, reaching 18.3 percent in During the same period the process of globalization steadily intensified caused by further improvements in communication and transportation technology leading to reductions in trade barriers and a surge in trade. The 2007 financial crises added two features to this process: persistent high unemployment in advanced countries, and significant changes in volume and terms of trade among many countries. U.S. aggregate unemployment rate has stayed above 8 percent in the past five years, and Europe has experienced double digit unemployment rates with unemployment reaching over 25 percent in countries such as Greece and Spain. In addition, Gopinath et al. (2012) documented that the global trade collapse of lead to significant changes in trade prices and volume across countries. These developments have generated renewed interest among economists in the nexus among unemployment, personal income distribution, and globalization. This interest is guided by some of the following questions. Is more trade job-creating or job-destroying? What are the effects of international competitiveness captured by better terms of trade on personal income distribution, unemployment, and welfare? What is the relationship between comparative advantage and labor market frictions in a global economy with persistent unemployment? Can one identify the nature and effects of economic recovery policies? Do unilateral job-creating policies have any adverse effects on other countries? In this paper, we propose a simple theory of personal income distribution, equilibrium unemployment, and trade addressing these important questions. Labor is the only factor of production and consists of a fixed measure of individuals differing in managerial talent 1

3 (ability). The economy produces two goods, a traditional and a modern one, under perfect competition. The traditional sector consists of a measure of single-worker firms as in Pissarides (2004, Chapter 1), whereas the modern sector consists of multiple worker firms managed by self-employed entrepreneurs with high managerial talent as in Lucas (1978). Individuals with low managerial talent choose to become workers. An entrepreneur may enhance the productivity of her firm by acquiring managerial capital which depends positively on managerial talent. In contrast, worker productivity is independent of ability. The choice between becoming an entrepreneur or a worker depends on expected earning considerations. We assume, for tractability purposes, that entrepreneurs do not face the prospect of unemployment and their earnings equal firm profits, whereas workers have to search for jobs. Labor markets for workers exhibit search frictions leading to equilibrium unemployment, which equals the weighted sum of sector-specific unemployment rates and changes with shifts of labor between the traditional and modern sectors. 1 Having developed a tractable model, we first study a small open jobless economy trading with the rest of the world at fixed terms of trade. An increase in the relative price of modern good leads to a movement of resources from the traditional to the modern good. The effects on aggregate unemployment depend on sector specific differences in labor market distortions. Where the derived parameter measuring the job-finding rate (the probability that a worker finds a job) is higher in the modern sector than in the traditional sector, then an increase in the price of the modern good reduces aggregate unemployment. The opposite occurs if the job-finding rate in the traditional sector is higher. An increase in the the relative price of the modern sector raises the economy s aggregate expenditure, increases income inequality between employed workers and entrepreneurs, and has an ambiguous effect on aggregate welfare. Under the assumption that the distribution of entrepreneurial talent is Pareto, aggregate welfare is a U shape function of the relative price of modern good. 1 Botero et al. (2004) among others assert that labor market rigidities stemming primarily from national labor regulation policies different across countries, affect adversely labor force participation, and lead to higher unemployment especially among young workers. 2

4 Next we illustrate the usefulness of the small open economy framework by highlighting a few novel comparative statics properties. We employ the assumptions that the job-finding rate in the modern sector is higher than the corresponding one in the traditional sector, and that the distribution of managerial talent is Pareto. We analyze the effects of international competitiveness measured by the absolute difference between the economy s terms of trade (relative price of its exportable) and the autarky price. Within the context of our static model, greater international competitiveness can occur in two ways: through an exogenous improvement in the terms of trade caused by lower trade costs or the global financial crises; or product market policies that change the domestic price such as tariffs and/or export subsidies. Under parameter assumptions implying lower labor-market distortions in the modern sector, the effects of international competitiveness depend on the initial trade pattern. Where the economy starts with exporting the traditional good and exhibiting low trade volume, improved international competitiveness may lead to an immiserizing recession with lower GDP, higher unemployment, and lower welfare. Where the economy exports the modern good, improved international competitiveness caused by better terms of trade reduces unemployment, increases welfare, and leads to higher GDP. We then discuss the effects of two job-creating labor-market policies within the context of a small open jobless economy. A policy leading to lower costs of managerial capital or one generating lower costs of posting job-vacancies in the modern sector have identical effects. They lead to lower unemployment, higher GDP, and higher welfare. As such, they are preferable to product market policies that might lead to a recession. These results are consistent with the generalized theory of distortions and welfare. Finally, we analyze the relationship between labor-market rigidities and comparative advantage by employing a two-country framework. Comparative advantage depends on a derived parameter based on the following factors: the cost of acquiring managerial capital and market tightness of modern sector relative to that in the traditional sector. A country is more likely to export the modern good if it has lower costs of managerial capital and 3

5 a relatively lower labor-market frictions in modern sector. A move from autarky to free trade has asymmetric effects on income inequality (between entrepreneurs and workers) and the rate of unemployment across two countries. Global free trade, however, has ambiguous national welfare effects. Furthermore, our analysis show that a unilateral job-creating policy also has asymmetric effects on income inequality and the rate of unemployment across countries, while having ambiguous effect on welfare in each country. This paper is related to a growing literature that investigates the nexus between trade and unemployment. Researchers in this literature have identified different sources of labor market frictions that lead to equilibrium unemployment. In Brecher s (1974) model, for example, unemployment stems from minimum wages, whereas in Copeland s (1989) and Davis and Harrigan s (2011) models efficiency wages play key role in generating equilibrium unemployment. Kreickemeier and Nelson (2006), Amiti and Davis (2011), and Egger and Kreickemeier (2009) use models of fair wages to generate unemployment. Our model is more closely related to the trade literature that uses the standard Diamond Mortensen Pissarides search and matching frictions in the labor markets as a source of unemployment. 2 In an important contribution, Davidson et al. (1999) develop a general equilibrium search model of trade between two countries to investigate the extent to which results obtained in traditional, full-employment trade models must be modified. 3 In their model, both sectors share the same production technology which is also common across countries. However, job turnover (break-up) rates vary across sectors and countries, and these differences determine the pattern of trade. Although there are workers and entrepreneurs in their model, their supplies are exogenously given. In addition, their model assumes away managerial capital acquisition, and thus trade does not affect firm 2 Helpman et al. (2011) provides a comprehensive review of this literature by emphasizing the role of firm heterogeneity. 3 Davidson et al. (1999) build on Davidson et al. (1998) that study two-sector, closed-economy, general equilibrium models with frictional unemployment. Davidson and Matusz (2009) provides several extensions of the Davidson et al. (1999) model to study how international trade affects labor markets and how differences in labor markets affect international trade. 4

6 productivity. 4 Helpman and Itskhoki (2010) introduce search and matching frictions leading to equilibrium unemployment in a trade model with product differentiation, monopolistic competition, and scale economies. 5 Helpman et al. (2010) extends Helpman and Itskhoki (2010) by introducing match-specific heterogeneity in ability across workers to study the impact of trade on wage distribution. Imperfectly competitive product markets complicate their analysis, and necessitate the use of a two-country framework because firms in these models are not price takers. In addition, they do not consider the effects of self-employed entrepreneurs by assuming that the supply of workers is exogenous. Our theory makes possible the study labor-market frictions and trade without additional complications and distortions stemming from product market imperfections, and also allows us to analyze the effects of international trade and policies in the context of a small open jobless economy. Moreover, our theory complements Helpman et al. (2010) by highlighting the nature of income inequality fueled by firm profits stemming from heterogeneous entrepreneurial talent (as opposed to income inequality based on differences in wages generated by heterogeneous worker ability). The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 introduces international trade considerations by analyzing the properties of a small open jobless economy and a two-country global economy. Section 4 concludes. 2 The Model Consider an economy producing two homogeneous goods indexed by i = 1, 2. The economy is populated by a continuum of identical families with measure equal to one. Each family has a supply of labor consisting of all family members. Without loss of generality, we assume that the size (mass) of each family is equal to one as well. Family members possess 4 Dutt et al. (2009) develop a model of trade with unemployment to study the impact of trade on unemployment. Although search and matching frictions lead to unemployment in their model, trade results from either Heckscher-Ohlin or Ricardian comparative advantage. 5 See also Felbermayr et al. (2011) who use a similar set-up to study the relationship between trade and unemployment in a context of symmetric countries. 5

7 different ability levels indexed by a. In the present context, ability is a broad generic term measuring managerial talent, propensity to learn, level of training or education and any other feature helping an individual to acquire managerial (entrepreneurial) capital. The distribution of abilities within each family is given by an exogenous cumulative distribution G(a) with density g(a) and support [1, ). Decisions are made sequentially. An individual first decides whether to become an entrepreneur or a worker. An entrepreneur with a given entrepreneurial talent chooses the optimal level of managerial capital, followed by how many workers to employ. The latter choice is conditioned by the existence of hiring costs stemming from search and frictions in the labor market. The entrepreneur engages in bargaining with the firm s workers to determine the negotiated wage while treating the level of managerial capital and hiring costs as sunk. Entrepreneurial income equals firm profits. Each worker decides first in which sector to search for a job based on wage and unemployment considerations. Once committed to a sector, a worker cannot switch sectors. Finally, we assume that each family engages in appropriate income transfers among its members equalizing their income and utility levels independently of their employment statues and ability. Accordingly, aggregate welfare equals the sum of individual utilities across all family members. 2.1 Preferences Family members have identical preferences over the two homogeneous goods as described by the following utility function u = ( ) 1 β ( ) β q1 q2, (1) 1 β β where q i is the consumption of good i = 1, 2, and 0 < β < 1 is an exogenous, constant parameter. Denoting with e income of an individual, one can write the demand for good i as q i = β i e/p i, (2) 6

8 where β 1 = 1 β, β 2 = β, and p i is the price of good i. We choose good 1 as the numeraire by setting its price equal to one (i.e., p 1 = 1). To further simplify notation, we rewrite the relative price of good 2 as p. Substituting q i from (2) into (1) yields the following indirect utility function v(e, p) = ep β, (3) which increases with income e and decreases with the relative price of good 2, p. The linear dependence of indirect utility on income indicates that individuals are risk neutral Production and Job Creation We refer to good 1 as the traditional good and to good 2 as the modern good. Production of traditional good 1 is carried out by small, identical, and single-worker firms. The concept of single-worker firms has been used extensively in the Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides (DMP) literature of equilibrium search unemployment (see, e.g., Chapter 1 in Pissarides, 2004). Each firm is free to post a job vacancy and hire one worker. Vacancies are not instantaneously filled because of matching and search frictions. When a firm hires a worker, the worker produces one unit of good 1 independently of ability. Upon matching, the firm and worker bargain over revenue earned by selling one unit of output at p 1 = 1. Assuming equal bargaining power and zero value of outside options (e.g., no unemployment insurance), each worker receives w 1 = 1/2. Good 2 in the modern sector is produced by a continuum of heterogeneous firms, each owned and managed by an entrepreneur. The production technology of sector 2 incorporates two features: heterogeneous managerial skill (or organization capital) denoted by z; and diminishing returns to scale with respect to labor capturing span of control stemming from a concave production function, as in Lucas (1978). The production function of a firm 6 Risk aversion considerations can be readily introduced into the analysis by assuming that utility takes the form u = (q 1 /β 1 ) β 1 (q 2 /β 2 ) β 2, with β 1 + β 2 < 1 such that the indirect utility is concave in income. However, we confine ourselves to the risk-neutral case to simplify the subsequent exposition. 7

9 managed by an entrepreneur with organization capital z is given by y 2 (z) = ( ) z 1 η ( ) l η, (4) 1 η η where l is the number of workers employed and η (0, 1) is an exogenous parameter. According to (4), organizational capital z also represents firm productivity and exhibits diminishing returns for any given level of labor l. Thus, we hereafter use the terms organization capital and firm productivity interchangeably. The above formulation delivers a market structure with heterogeneous firms producing a homogeneous product under perfect competition. Heterogeneous firm productivity stems from endogenous formation of organizational capital which, in turn, is based on exogenous distribution of managerial talent. As a result, this paper complements seminal studies of firm heterogeneity, such as Hopenhayn (1992) and Melitz (2003), which postulate an exogenous distribution of firm productivity and internal scale economies. Following the insights of human capital theory, we assume that individuals choose to become entrepreneurs or workers depending on earning considerations and costs of acquiring managerial capital. In particular, we postulate that an individual with ability (managerial talent) a faces λz 2 /2a costs of acquiring z units of organizational capital, where λ > 0 is an exogenous parameter. The costs of acquiring managerial capital are measured in units of good 1, decline with the level of ability, and increase with the level of managerial capital. The proposed cost function captures, albeit in a reduced form, the idea that human capital formation is costly involving various inputs, experience, schooling, on-the-job training, etc. These dynamic elements are not explicitly modeled but captured by shift parameter λ. This quadratic cost function delivers linear marginal costs and leads to an interior, closedfrom solution. Higher values of λ are associated with higher total and marginal costs of managerial-capital acquisition. In what follows, we will refer to an increase in λ as a rise in costs of acquiring managerial capital. 7 7 The production-function based approach to human capital formation has long tradition going back to seminal studies by Becker (1994) and Ben-Porath (1967) among many others. 8

10 An entrepreneur with managerial talent a maximizes his earnings e 2 (a), equal to firm profits, by choosing the level of managerial capital z and the number of employees l. As in the traditional sector 1, hiring in the modern sector is costly due to search and matching frictions. A firm with productivity z may hire l workers instantaneously by incurring hiring cost c 2 l, measured in terms of good 1. In addition, the firm incurs a wage bill denoted by w 2 l, where w 2 is the negotiated wage between the entrepreneur and employees as will be shown below. As a result, an entrepreneur incurs managerial capital costs and two types of labor costs: hiring costs and the wage bill. As will be discussed in the next section, hiring-cost parameter c 2 depends on sector-specific labor market conditions, and therefore is common across all firms producing good 2. This discussion leads to the following expression for entrepreneurial income where y 2 (z) is given by (4). e 2 (a) max } {py 2 (z) w 2 l c 2 l λz2, (5) 2a To obtain a solution for e 2 (a), we first determine the negotiated wage rate w 2 and labor input l recognizing that bargaining occurs after an entrepreneur completes the process of hiring and acquiring managerial capital. Upon a match an employee cannot be replaced without cost, and thus a hired worker is not interchangeable with an outside worker. Consequently, hired workers have bargaining power. The wage bargaining process is modeled as in Stole and Zwiebel (1996a): the firm engages in bilateral bargaining with each worker and internalizes the effect of a worker s departure on wages of remaining workers. In our model all workers are identical in regards to output productivity, since the latter is independent of ability by assumption. 8 As a result, a firm treats each worker as marginal and firm surplus from a worker departure equals the marginal change in firm value (profits) with respect to labor. We assume that the value of outside options for each worker is zero (i.e., workers 8 Helpman et al. (2010) develop a model of unemployment and inequality where worker productivity depends on ability and firms engage in ex-ante screening for worker ability. Screening leads to more productive firms offering higher wages. Our model complements their analysis by focusing on endogenous firm productivity (based on managerial capital acquisition) and equally productive workers. 9

11 do not receive unemployment benefits); and therefore worker surplus equals the negotiated wage. Assuming equal bargaining power, the Stole and Zwiebel (1996a) solution requires that total surplus be equally split between the entrepreneur and a worker according to l [py 2(z) w 2 l] = w 2, where w 2 is the negotiated wage rate and p is the relative price of good 2. 9 Because hiring costs c 2 l and managerial-capital acquisition costs λz 2 /2a are sunk (i.e., they are paid before the bargaining process), these terms do not appear in the right hand side. The solution to this ordinary differential equation provides the following expression for the negotiated wage w 2 = p [ ] ηz 1 η. (6) 1 + η (1 η)l According to (6), the negotiated wage increases with price p and firm productivity z, and decreases with firm size measured by the number of employees l. 10 Faced with this wage rate, an entrepreneur chooses the number of employees l by taking into account hiring costs to maximize (5). This maximization yields w 2 = p [ ] ηz 1 η = c 2. (7) 1 + η (1 η)l Thus, all entrepreneurs (irrespective of managerial capital and firm size) pay the same wage to workers by setting it equal to hiring cost per worker, that is w 2 = c 2. The above equation can be solved for the number of workers hired by a firm with productivity z l = η [ ] 1 p 1 η z. (8) 1 η (1 + η)c 2 Equation (8) is the firm demand for labor in the presence of labor market frictions. This demand for hired labor (l) declines with the level of hiring costs per worker (c 2 ), and increases with the relative price of good 2 (p) and firm productivity (z). Thus, firms with higher productivity and lower hiring costs per employee employ more workers. 9 Incorporating asymmetric bargaining power between an entrepreneur and workers as in Stole and Zwiebel (1996b) does not alter the main results. 10 It can easily be verified that (6) is the solution to the differential equation by substituting (6) in the former and performing the calculations. 10

12 2.3 Talent Allocation An entrepreneur with managerial talent a maximizes earnings (economic profits) by choosing the level of managerial capital z after taking into account labor costs. Substituting w 2 = c 2 from (7) and (8) into equation (5), and maximizing the resulting function with respect to z yields z = a λ [ p (1 + η)c η 2 ] 1 1 η. (9) Equation (9) indicates that the optimal level of acquired organizational capital increases with managerial talent a and price p; and decreases with hiring cost per worker c 2, and the cost of acquiring managerial capital λ. We are now in the position to determine how the distribution of managerial talent determines the choice between becoming an entrepreneur or a worker. This choice is affected by expected income considerations. Substituting w 2 = c 2 from (7), l from (8), and z from (9) into equation (5) provides a closed-form expression for maximum income e 2 (a) earned by an active entrepreneur e 2 (a) = a [ 2λ p (1 + η)c η 2 ] 2 1 η. (10) According to (10), the return on entrepreneurship e 2 (a) is an increasing linear function of managerial talent a and behaves similarly to the optimal level of organizational capital z: it increases with relative price p, and declines with the costs of managerial capital acquisition λ and hiring c 2. Active entrepreneurs do not face the prospect of unemployment and receive e 2 (a) with certainty. Observe also that indirect utility (3) is linear in income implying that individuals are risk neutral. The next section will formally establish that the ex-ante income of each worker is equalized across the two sectors, that is all workers receive the same expected wage. Worker income is independent of managerial talent a by assumption, and entrepreneurial income increases linearly with the level of managerial talent, as indicated by (10). As a result, there exists a unique cutoff level of managerial talent a > 0 such that all individuals 11

13 with talent a < a choose to become workers, whereas all individuals with talent a a choose to become self-employed entrepreneurs. Deriving an explicit expression for the cutoff level of managerial talent requires determination of expected worker income in one of the two sectors. It is simpler and more convenient to focus on the traditional sector, where worker income is e 1 = w 1 = 1/2 and, of course, does not depend on the level of managerial talent. Let ζ 1 denote the probability of a worker to find a job in sector 1 (to be determined in the next section). Then expected income of a worker then is simply E[e 1 ] = ζ 1 w 1 = ζ 1 /2. An individual chooses to become an entrepreneur if and only if e 2 (a) E[e 1 ]. The cutoff level of managerial talent a, at which an individual is indifferent between being an entrepreneur and a worker, is given by e 2 (a ) = ζ 1 /2, and using (10) yields [ (1 + η)c η ] 2 a 1 η 2 = λζ 1. (11) p As in Lucas (1978), only the most talented individuals become entrepreneurs. However, unlike Lucas (1978), here entrepreneurs acquire managerial capital and workers face the threat of unemployment. The cutoff level of managerial talent a is endogenous and increases with per-worker hiring cost c 2, the probability of finding a job as a worker ζ 1 (capturing part of the opportunity costs of entrepreneurship), and the cost of managerial capital acquisition λ. The cutoff level of managerial talent decreases with relative price p as expected. Finally, combining equations (9) and (11) yields z = ( ) 1 ζ1 2 a, (12) λa which states that the equilibrium level of managerial capital increases with the probability of finding a job in the traditional sector ζ 1, and decreases with the talent cutoff level a and the cost of acquiring managerial capital λ. 12

14 2.4 Taking Stock For a given level of managerial capital and hiring costs, the firm equilibrium is identical to the textbook short-run equilibrium of a perfectly competitive firm producing a homogeneous good under a U shaped average cost curve and increasing marginal costs of production. Equation (5) can be employed to express total costs as a function of output. Solving for the number of employees from production function (4) and substituting the resulting expression into C(l, z) = (w 2 + c 2 )l + λz 2 /2a yields C(y 2, z) = Φ(z)y 1/η 2 + λz 2 /2a, where Φ(z) = (w 2 + c 2 )η[(1 η)/z] (1 η)/η. The first component of C(y 2, z) is an increasing and convex function of output and corresponds to variable production costs; the second component corresponds to fixed costs. Accordingly, for a given level of managerial capital z and per-unit labor costs w 2 + c 2, each firm faces a U shaped average cost curve and increasing marginal costs. As a result, each entrepreneur chooses the output level that maximizes e 2 (y 2, z) = py 2 C(y 2, z) by setting price equal to marginal costs p = [Φ(z)y 2 /η] (1 η)η = (w 2 + c 2 )[(1 η)y 2 /z] (1 η)/η as in Lucas (1978). The present model differs from the standard textbook model of output choice by a competitive firm in several important aspects. First, each entrepreneur differs in managerial talent leading to different levels of managerial capital, firm productivity, and firm size. Second, each firm engages in bargaining with its employees and uses its monopsony power to drive the negotiated wage down to the level of hiring costs per worker, that is w 2 = c 2. Third, economic profits are not driven down to zero: a fraction of economic profits covers short-run fixed costs stemming from acquisition of managerial capital; and the remaining fraction of profits covers the return to entrepreneurial talent which serves as a fixed primary factor of production. In the long-run, the return to entrepreneurial talent determines the allocation of resources among individuals who decide to become self-employed entrepreneurs and individuals who decide to become workers according to (11). Thus entry costs into the modern sector equal expected worker income. Fourth, hiring costs and the negotiated wage are endogenously determined through interactions between labor market frictions and 13

15 general equilibrium forces, as the next subsection demonstrates. The present model also differs from models of monopolistic competition with heterogeneous firms such as those descending from the seminal work of Melitz (2003). In Melitz-type models each firm produces a horizontally differentiated product under internal increasing returns to scale, and draws its fixed productivity from a random distribution after incurring fixed entry costs. In the present model, each good is homogeneous and produced under diminishing returns and increasing marginal production costs. Firm productivity is endogenous and reflects the underlying distribution of managerial talent. Entry into the modern sector does not depend on fixed costs, as in Melitz, and reflects the opportunity cost of entrepreneurship; and aggregate profits are distributed among active self-employed entrepreneurs. In summary, the present model complements existing models of firm heterogeneity that emphasize the role of R&D and productivity uncertainty and abstract from the determinants of personal income distribution. In contrast, our model follows the tradition of human-capital formation and talent allocation as sources of firm heterogeneity and personal income distribution. One notable advantage of our approach, as we will later discuss, is the analysis of trade and personal income distribution within the context of a traditional small open economy facing fixed terms of trade and perfectly competitive product markets (as opposed to symmetric countries with monopolistically competitive product markets). Another notable feature is incorporating the option of becoming a self-employed entrepreneur which has profound implications for the behavior of aggregate equilibrium unemployment. 2.5 Equilibrium Unemployment Workers are risk neutral and decide whether to search for a job in the traditional or modern sectors. The labor market exhibit search frictions as in the standard DMP theory of unemployment. As we indicated above, we assume that once committed to a sector a worker cannot move to another sector, i.e. there is no ex-post inter-sectoral worker mobility. 14

16 Let N i and V i denote the number of unemployed workers searching for jobs and total number of posted job vacancies in sector i = 1, 2. We assume that the number of successful matches (e.g., hired workers) in sector i is given by Cobb-Douglas matching function M i = m i V ξ i N 1 ξ i, where parameter m i measures matching efficiency, and ξ (0, 1) is a constant parameter. Assuming that M i < N i, the job finding rate ζ i M i /N i, interpreted as the probability that an unemployed worker matches with a firm is given by ζ i = m i (V i /N i ) ξ < 1, where V i /N i is the number or vacancies per unemployed worker. The term ζ i is an index of labor market tightness and captures the notion that a higher job-finding rate implies a greater number of vacant jobs per unemployed worker, that is more firms are posting vacancies and therefore the demand for labor increases leading to a tighter labor market. In what follows we use the terms job-finding rate and labor market tightness interchangeably. Following Blanchard and Gali (2010), we assume that a firm can hire workers instantaneously by incurring a cost of hiring a worker expressed in units of the traditional good. Hiring cost per worker in sector i is given by c i (ζ i ) = τ i ζ γ i, (13) where the exogenous parameter τ i is an index of labor market frictions; ζ i is the job-finding rate or the labor market tightness index; and γ > 0 is a constant parameter. According to equation (13), higher market tightness ζ i implies greater instantaneous hiring costs per worker c i, for any given degree of labor market frictions τ i. As shown by Blanchard and Gali (2010, footnote 6), the above hiring cost function can be derived from a standard constant returns to scale Cobb-Douglas matching function. Accordingly, if the matching function is given by M i = m i V ξ i N 1 ξ i, then the two parameters in (13) are given by γ = (1 ξ)/ξ > 0 and τ i = m 1/ξ i. As a result, τ i declines with matching efficiency m i, and therefore corresponds to an index of labor market frictions (rigidities) in sector i. Consider now sector 1 where each firm employs one worker. Entry to the market is unrestricted, but each firm faces entry costs equal to the cost of posting a vacancy (denoted by ν 1 and measured in terms of good 1). It then follows that χ 1 = ν 1 /c 1 represents the 15

17 probability that a firm fills a vacancy, that is χ 1 is the hiring rate in the traditional sector. Because each firm receives half of generated revenue, expected profit is χ 1 /2. As a result, free-entry condition χ 1 /2 = ν 1 implies c 1 = 1/2. Substituting c 1 = 1/2 into (13) yields the equilibrium values of the job-finding rate and hiring costs ζ 1 = (2τ 1 ) 1 γ, c 1 = 1 2. (14) We assume that τ 1 < 1/2 to ensure that the job-finding rate ζ 1 is smaller than one. Note that the equilibrium probability of finding a job in this sector decreases with the degree of labor market frictions τ 1 as expected. Accordingly, greater labor-market frictions lead to lower labor market tightness in sector 1. In the absence of heterogeneous organizational capital, hiring cost per employee c 1 and labor market tightness ζ 1 are exogenously determined by labor-market (as opposed to product-market) parameters. To determine the equilibrium values of job-finding rate ζ 2 and hiring-cost per employee c 2, note that ex-ante labor mobility implies that a worker must be indifferent between assigned to the traditional or modern sectors. Because workers are risk-neutral, equilibrium in the labor market requires equalization of expected worker earnings between sectors. Expected earnings of a worker searching for a job in sector 1 is simply ζ 1 /2, and expected earnings of a worker searching for a job in sector 2 is ζ 2 w 2 = ζ 2 c 2. Using equations (13) and (14), ζ 1 /2 = ζ 2 c 2 implies ζ 2 = 2 1 γ τ 1 γ(1+γ) 1 τ 1 1+γ 2, c 2 = 1 2 ( τ2 τ 1 ) 1 1+γ. (15) To determine the unemployment rate among workers, first note that the measure of individuals who decide to enter the labor force as workers is G(a ) since the size of population is normalized to one. Observe also that ζ 2 N 2 = a lg(a)da, where l is given by (8). Using (9) together with (11) in the integration yields N 2 = 2η E[a a ] (1 η) a, (16) 16

18 where E[a a ] = a ag(a)da is the expected level of entrepreneurial talent in sector 2. The aggregate unemployment rate among workers is defined as the total number of unemployed workers in both sectors divided by the total number of workers searching for jobs. The number of unemployed workers in sector i is U i = (1 ζ i )N i, and the aggregate number of workers searching for a job is equal to the supply of workers G(a ) = N 1 + N 2 because entrepreneurs are fully employed. As a result, the economy-wide unemployment rate is given by U = (U 1 + U 2 )/G(a ) and can be written as U = (1 ζ 1 ) + (ζ 1 ζ 2 ) N 2 G(a ) = (1 ζ 2η 1) + (ζ 1 ζ 2 ) (1 η) E[a a ] a G(a ), (17) where parameters ζ 1 and ζ 2 are given by (14) and (15), and N 2 /G(a ) < 1 is the fraction of workers assigned to the modern sector. In Helpman and Itskhoki (2010), the supply of workers is exogenous, and as a result, aggregate unemployment is affected only through changes in N 2. In contrast, in the present model self-employed entrepreneurs influence worker supply G(a ), which is endogenous and affects the level and behavior of aggregate unemployment rate. 2.6 Aggregation Armed with these variables, we can determine total revenue in each sector [ Y 1 = ζ 1 N 1 = ζ 1 G(a ) 2η E[a a ] ] (1 η) a, (18a) py 2 = where ζ 1 is given by (14). 11 py 2 (a)g(a)da = (1 + η)ζ 1 a (1 η) Aggregate hiring cost in each sector is given by C 1h = c 1 ζ 1 N 1 = ζ [ 1 G(a ) 2η E[a a ] ] 2 (1 η) a, C 2h = a c 2 l(a)g(a)da = ηζ 1 1 η E[a a ] a, (18b) E[a a ] a. 11 Equation (7) implies that py 2 (z) = (1 + η)c 2 l/η and equations (8), (9), and (11) imply that c 2 l = ηζ 1 a/[(1 η)a ]. Thus, py 2 (a) = (1 + η)ζ 1 a/[(1 η)a ], and integrating this last expression across all entrepreneurs yields (18b). 17

19 Traditional good 1 is also used in formation of managerial capital. Because each entrepreneur uses λz 2 /2a units of good 1, equation (12) implies that z 2 /2a = ζ 1 a/(2a ). Integrating this expression across all entrepreneurs yields the total amount of good 1 used in the formation of organizational capital, C z, C z = ζ 1 E[a a ] 2 a. (19) Thus total amount of resources used in hiring and the formation of organizational capital (measured in units of good 1) is given by C = C 1h + C 2h + C z = ζ 1 2 [ G(a ) + E[a ] a ] a. (20) Equations (18a), (18b), and (20) imply that the value of total output, measured in units of good 1, used in hiring and in the formation of organizational capital equals half of the economy s GDP, that is C = (Y 1 + py 2 )/ Income Distribution and Welfare Equations (10) and (11) imply that the income of an entrepreneur with ability a is given by e 2 (a) = ζ 1 a/(2a ). Worker income in sector 1 is w 1 = 1/2 and worker income in sector 2 is w 2 = c 2. As a result, ex-post personal income distribution is given by e(a) = 0 if a < a and worker is unemployed 1/2 if a < a and worker is employed in sector 1 c 2 if a < a and worker is employed in sector 2 ζ 1 a/(2a ) if a a and individual is self-employed entrepreneur (21) where ζ 1 and c 2 are given by (14) and (15), respectively. Because ζ i is the probability of finding a job in sector i, it follows from the law of large numbers that ζ i N i is the number of workers and w i ζ i N i is the total wage paid the workers in sector i. Using the above income distribution, aggregate income is E = ζ 1 2 [ G(a ) + E[a ] a ] a. (22) 18

20 Comparing (22) to (20) reveals that E = Y 1 +py 2 C and E = C = (Y 1 +py 2 )/2. In words, aggregate earnings equal aggregate revenue minus the value of good 1 covering organization capital and hiring costs; it also reveals that half of the economy s GDP covers hiring and organization costs and half of GDP covers earnings of workers and entrepreneurs. Using (3) and (21), one can readily determine the welfare of each individual. However, to address the impact of trade on welfare, we need to aggregate the individuals welfare. The assumption of identical families allows us to treat aggregate welfare as each family s welfare which equals the sum of the individual utilities. Integrating the resulting indirect utility functions across all individuals within a family yields V = Ep β, (23) where E is the aggregate expenditure given by (22). 2.8 Closed-Economy Equilibrium In the closed-economy equilibrium, Q 1 = Y 1 C and Q 2 = Y 2, where Q i is aggregate quantity consumed of good i. Substituting these into Q 1 /pq 2 = (1 β)/β from equation (2) implies E[a a ] a = BG(a ), B β(1 η) 2(1 β)(1 + η) + β(3η + 1). (24) The left hand side (LHS) is a decreasing function of managerial ability cutoff a, 12 whereas the right hand side (RHS) is an increasing function of a. As a result, equation (24) determines the unique closed-economy equilibrium cutoff level of managerial talent a. Because 0 < B < 1, the equilibrium cutoff level ensures that both goods are produced, i.e. N i > 0 for i = 1, Observe that the equilibrium cutoff level of managerial talent a does not 12 Using Leibniz rule, de[a a ]/da = d [ a ag(a)da ] /da = a g(a ) < Equation (24) can be written as N 2 /G(a ) = 2ηE[a a ]/[(1 η)a G(a )] = 2ηB/(1 η) < 1 implying that the equilibrium share of workers assigned in sector 2 is strictly positive and strictly less than one. This result combined with the supply of workers G(a ) = N 1 + N 2 implies N i > 0, i.e. the closed-economy equilibrium is characterized by incomplete specialization of production. 19

21 depend on parameters capturing labor market rigidities such as hiring costs per employee, costs of posting and maintaining job vacancies, and costs of acquiring organizational capital. This property facilitates the analysis of comparative advantage as will become obvious in the next section. Lemma 1. The closed-economy equilibrium cutoff level of managerial talent a satisfying equilibrium condition (24) exists and is unique. Once the closed-economy cutoff level of managerial talent is determined one can easily determine other endogenous variables in the model. First, substituting the cutoff talent level a into (21) and (22) determines the distribution of personal income and aggregate income, respectively. Second, substituting a into (12) yields the equilibrium cutoff level of managerial capital ζ = (a ζ 1 /λ) 1/2, where ζ 1 is exogenous and given by (14). Third, equations in (15) determine the job-finding rate ζ 2 and hiring cost per worker c 2, respectively. Fourth, substituting c 2 into (11) yields the relative price of good 2, p; and substituting p into (23) determines aggregate welfare. Using equilibrium condition (24) in (17) provides the following expression for aggregate unemployment rate U = (1 ζ 1 ) + (ζ 1 ζ 2 ) 2ηB 1 η, where parameter B is defined in (24) and expression 2ηB/(1 η) is the equilibrium share of workers assigned to sector 2. Finally, note that the autarkic relative price of modern good p A can be written as a function of a from (11) p A = (1 + η)c η 2 [ ] 1 η λζ1 2 a, (25) where ζ 1 and c 2 are given by (14) and (15). The autarkic price depends on virtually all parameters: it increases with labor-market tightness in the traditional sector and with the cost of managerial capital acquisition; and declines with parameters increasing the 20

22 cutoff level of managerial talent a (which is determined by (24)). This completes the characterization of closed-economy equilibrium. 3 Open Economy In this section, we extend our framework to analyze the nexus of trade, unemployment, inequality, and welfare. We discuss two cases: first, we employ the traditional framework of a small, open, jobless economy taking its terms of trade (relative price of good 2) as given; second, we employ a two-country framework to analyze the role of labor market rigidities and costs of managerial capital acquisition as sources of comparative advantage. 3.1 A Small Open Jobless Economy Consider now a small open economy trading with the rest of the word at a fixed international relative price of good 2 denoted by p T. Following the standard practice of trade theory, we assume balanced trade: Y 1 Q 1 C + p T (Y 2 Q 2 ) = 0, where Y i is quantity supplied and Q i is quantity demanded for good i. The balanced trade condition can be written in an equivalent form as E = Y 1 + p T Y 2 C = Q 1 + p T Q 2, where aggregate income E is given by (22). In other words, the value of aggregate income (expenditure) equals the value of production net of hiring and organization capital costs (treated as intermediate inputs). Substituting the international price p T into equation (11) provides the equilibrium level of managerial talent [ (1 + η)c η ] 2 a 1 η 2 T = λζ 1. (26) p T where ζ 1 and c 2 are given by (14) and (15). Once a T is determined, we can readily solve for all endogenous variables as in the closed-economy equilibrium. 21

23 If the economy produces both goods, then there must be an upper bound, denoted by p max T, on the relative price of good The trade pattern depends on several factors that determine the ranking between the closed-economy equilibrium price p A, which is given by (25), and the (exogenous) international price p T : where p A = p T, there is no trade; where 0 < p T < p A, the economy exports the traditional good; and where p A < p T < p max T, the economy exports the modern good. Proposition 1. Consider a small open economy producing both goods and trading with the rest of world at a fixed international price of good 2 denoted by p T. Let p A denote the autarky price determined by (24) and (25). The economy does not engage in trade if p A = p T ; exports the traditional good 1 iff 0 < p T < p A ; and exports the modern good 2 iff p A < p T < p max T. As the international price p T increases, the economy switches from importing the modern good to exporting it. This pattern of trade reflects general-equilibrium forces and the law of comparative advantage. Where the economy exports the modern good, firm heterogeneity is irrelevant to whether small or large firms export. This feature stems from the assumptions of perfect competition and the absence of fixed foreign-market access costs. 15 We continue the analysis of a small-open economy by investigating the effects of trade on unemployment, income distribution, and welfare. Without loss of generality we consider the case where the economy is incompletely specialized and under free trade exports the 14 Note that equation (26) states that a T is monotonically decreasing in p T from infinity to zero. As the relative price of good 2 increases and the cutoff level of managerial talent declines, the modern sector expands because more individuals want to become self-employed entrepreneurs and more workers would like to find employment in the modern sector. This process is reflected in the corresponding increase in the fraction of workers assigned in the modern sector N 2 /G(a T ) 1. Note also that N 2 /G(a T ) = 2ηE[a a T ]/[(1 η)a T G(a T )] declines monotonically in a T, and approaches unity for a sufficiently small value a T = a min. For example, if the distribution of managerial talent is Pareto G(a) = 1 a k, where k > 1 is the shape parameter, then the share of workers in sector 2 is given by N 2/G(a ) = 2ηk/[(1 η)(k 1)(a k 1)]. As a result, a min = [1 + 2ηk/(1 η)(k 1)] 1/k > 1. Replacing a T in (26) with a min yields p max T. 15 The introduction of fixed costs would presumably resolve this indeterminacy in the usual fashion with larger firms exporting and smaller firms serving the domestic market. Incorporating fixed costs will derail the focus of the present paper, increase the algebraic complexity and cloud the intuition of the main results. We differ the analysis of firm heterogeneity and export status to future research. 22

24 modern good 2, that is p A < p T < p max T. The rate of aggregate unemployment is given by 2η U = (1 ζ 1 ) + (ζ 1 ζ 2 ) (1 η) E[a a T ] a T G(a T ), (27) where cutoff level a T is determined by (26). Because the share of workers allocated to the modern sector declines (increases) monotonically with a T (p T ), the effect of trade on unemployment depends on the ranking of sector-specific job-finding rates ζ 1 and ζ 2, which are determined by (14) and ( 15). It is obvious from (27) that the unemployment rate is independent of the international price if ζ 1 = ζ 2 = ζ. In this special case (which holds when τ 1 = τ 2, i.e. both sectors have identical matching efficiency), the rate of unemployment is U = (1 ζ). Where the job-finding rate in the modern sector exceeds the one in the traditional sector (i.e., ζ 1 ζ 2 < 0), then more exposure to trade reduces aggregate unemployment. Where the job-finding rate in the traditional sector exceeds the job-finding rate of the modern sector (i.e., ζ 1 ζ 2 > 0), more trade exposure increases aggregate unemployment. Proposition 2. Consider a small open economy producing both goods and exporting modern good 2 under free trade (p A < p T < p max T ). A move from autarky to free trade has no impact on the unemployment if sector-specific job-finding rates are equal (i.e., ζ 1 = ζ 2 = ζ). More trade reduces (increases) the unemployment rate if the job-finding rate in the modern sector is higher (lower) than the job-finding rate in the traditional sector, i.e. ζ 2 > ζ 1 (ζ 2 < ζ 1 ). Since an increase in the relative price of good 2 from p A to p T lowers the managerial talent cutoff from a to a T, equation (21) implies that such an increase only raises entrepreneurs income. This leads to rise in income inequality between entrepreneurs and employed workers. In addition, equation (22) indicates that aggregate expenditure decreases with a T. Accordingly more trade increases aggregate expenditure E. 23

Monitoring, Endogenous Comparative Advantage, and Immigration

Monitoring, Endogenous Comparative Advantage, and Immigration Monitoring, Endogenous Comparative Advantage, and Immigration Dhimitri Qirjo The University of British Columbia This Version: November 2011 Abstract This paper proposes a theory of free movement of goods

More information

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers Elhanan Helpman Harvard University and CIFAR Oleg Itskhoki Harvard University Stephen Redding London School of Economics May 30,

More information

Unequal Effects of Trade on Workers with Different Abilities

Unequal Effects of Trade on Workers with Different Abilities Unequal Effects of Trade on Workers with Different Abilities Elhanan Helpman Harvard University and CIFAR Oleg Itskhoki Princeton University Stephen Redding London School of Economics August 1, 2009 Abstract

More information

Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy

Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy Sybille Lehwald July, 22 2011 1 Motivation Krugman (1980) importance of intra-industry trade no firm goes out of business

More information

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Today s Plan 1 2 3 4 Revisiting New Trade Theory with firm heterogeneity Multiple

More information

movement of goods and labor. According to Hatton and Williamson (2005), average industrial

movement of goods and labor. According to Hatton and Williamson (2005), average industrial III. EDUCATION, INSTITUTIONS, MIGRATION, TRADE AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF TALENT III.I. Introduction In the modern world, a number of recent political developments have intensified the free movement of goods

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Trade, Development and Growth June 2013 For students electing APEC 8702 and APEC 8703 option Instructions * Identify yourself by your

More information

Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent

Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent Dhimitri Qirjo Florida International University This Version: March 2010 Abstract This paper proposes a theory of free movement

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. A Simple Model of Quantity Heterogeneity and International Trade. Elias Dinopoulos University of Florida

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. A Simple Model of Quantity Heterogeneity and International Trade. Elias Dinopoulos University of Florida DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES A Simple Model of Quantity Heterogeneity and International Trade Elias Dinopoulos University of Florida Bulent Unel Louisiana State University Working Paper

More information

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework ARNAUD CHÉRON (GAINS-TEPP, UNIVERSITY OF LE MANS) Attribution Non commercial - No Derivative Work : http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/2.0/fr/

More information

Chapter 15 Unemployment and Matching in the Labor Market

Chapter 15 Unemployment and Matching in the Labor Market George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 15 Unemployment and Matching in the Labor Market In a fully competitive labor market, without uncertainty and frictions, employers would

More information

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Economics Working Paper Series 2016/012 Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Kwok Tong Soo The Department of Economics Lancaster University Management School Lancaster LA1 4YX UK Authors All

More information

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki Department of Economics, University of Crete, Gallos University Campus, Rethymnon 74100, Greece

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Last week an overview of some labor market facts a brief reminder of dynamic programming

More information

Final Exam - Answers

Final Exam - Answers Page 1 of 8 December 20, 2000 Answer all questions. Write your answers in a blue book. Be sure to look ahead and budget your time. Don t waste time on parts of questions that you can t answer. Leave space

More information

International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003)

International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003) 14.581 Week 8 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 8) After Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 1 / 36 Announcement 1 Problem Set 4 has

More information

Globalization and the Jobs Ladder. March 2018

Globalization and the Jobs Ladder. March 2018 Preliminary and Incomplete: Please do not cite Globalization and the Jobs Ladder Carl Davidson a, Fredrik Heyman b, Steven Matusz a, Fredrik Sjoholm c,b and Susan Zhu a March 2018 Abstract: We develop

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L3: The labour market

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L3: The labour market Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201 L3: The labour market Anna Seim Department of Economics, Stockholm University Spring 2017 1 / 58 Contents and literature Labour market facts and developments. Labour

More information

Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory. September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science

Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory. September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science What is Organizational/Personnel Economics? 1. Key Component 1: Human Capital Theory + Heterogeneous skills/tasks

More information

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013 The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution Ofer Cornfeld Tel-Aviv University (TAU) June 2013 The empirical attributes of the earnings distribution, Neal and Rosen (2000): "Earnings distributions...

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly Outline Barriers to Entry Profit Maximization under Monopoly Welfare Loss of Monopoly Multiplant Monopolist Price Discrimination Advertising in Monopoly

More information

BACHELOR OF BUSINESS. Sample FINAL EXAMINATION

BACHELOR OF BUSINESS. Sample FINAL EXAMINATION BACHELOR OF BUSINESS Sample FINAL EXAMINATION Subject Code : ECO201 Subject Name : LABOUR ECONOMICS This examination carries 50% of the total assessment for this subject. Examiner(s) Moderator(s) Joyce

More information

Lesson22: Trade under Monopolistic Competition

Lesson22: Trade under Monopolistic Competition International trade in the global economy 60 hours II Semester Luca Salvatici luca.salvatici@uniroma3.it Lesson22: Trade under Monopolistic Competition 1 Trade under Monopolistic Competition Assumptions

More information

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3 More Tutorial at www.dumblittledoctor.com Microeconomics 1. To an economist, a good is scarce when: *a. the amount of the good available is less than the amount that people want when the good's price equals

More information

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam Ecn 100 - Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman Final Exam You have until 12:30pm to complete this exam. Be certain to put your name,

More information

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms A Glossary of Terms The Digital Economist -A- Abundance--A physical or economic condition where the quantity available of a resource exceeds the quantity desired in the absence of a rationing system. Arbitrage

More information

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY MULTIPLE-CHOICE QUESTIONS 1. The mercantilists would have objected to: a. Export promotion policies initiated by the government b. The use of tariffs or quotas

More information

Skill Erosion during Unemployment as a source of Inefficiency

Skill Erosion during Unemployment as a source of Inefficiency Skill Erosion during Unemployment as a source of Inefficiency March 15, 2012 Lien Laureys 1 Universitat Pompeu Fabra Abstract This paper analyzes whether the presence of skill erosion during unemployment

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By Break-even point : the point at which price equals the minimum of average total cost. Externalities : the spillover effects of production or consumption for which no

More information

Income Effects, Wealth Effects, and Multiple Equilibria. in Trade Models with Durable Goods

Income Effects, Wealth Effects, and Multiple Equilibria. in Trade Models with Durable Goods Income Effects, Wealth Effects, and Multiple Equilibria in Trade Models with Durable Goods By Eric W. Bond and Robert A. Driskill Department of Economics Vanderbilt University December 1, 2007 I. Introduction

More information

DIVERSE ORGANIZATIONS

DIVERSE ORGANIZATIONS DIVERSE ORGANIZATIONS AND THE COMPETITION FOR TALENT Jan Eeckhout 1,2 Roberto Pinheiro 1 1 University of Pennsylvania 2 UPF Barcelona Decentralization Conference Washington University Saint Louis April

More information

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp 1 Introduction Investments in energy efficiency are seen by many as a low-cost or even no-cost measure to curb greenhouse gas emissions, slow down growth in energy demand and increase energy security.

More information

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Economy with a Competitive Informal Sector

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Economy with a Competitive Informal Sector DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 6935 Efficiency in a Search and Matching Economy with a Competitive Informal Sector Olivier Charlot Franck Malherbet Mustafa Ulus October 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

Preface... iii Introduction... xxi Chapter 1: Managerial Economics: Meaning, Nature, Scope, and Importance... 1

Preface... iii Introduction... xxi Chapter 1: Managerial Economics: Meaning, Nature, Scope, and Importance... 1 Table of Contents Preface... iii Introduction... xxi Chapter 1: Managerial Economics: Meaning, Nature, Scope, and Importance... 1 1.1 Introduction... 2 1.2 Meaning of Economics... 2 1.2.1 Nature of Economics...

More information

Search Frictions, Efficiency Wages and Equilibrium Unemployment BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS

Search Frictions, Efficiency Wages and Equilibrium Unemployment BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Search Frictions, Efficiency Wages and Equilibrium Unemployment Chris Martin and Bingsong Wang No. 26 /14 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Department of Economics Search Frictions, Efficiency Wages and Equilibrium

More information

Chapter 2: LABOUR DEMAND

Chapter 2: LABOUR DEMAND Chapter 2: LABOUR DEMAND J. Ignacio García Pérez Universidad Pablo de Olavide - Department of Economics BASIC REFERENCE: Cahuc & Zylberberg (2004), Chapter 4 October 2014 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez

More information

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. October 13, 2011 Abstract In a durable good market where sellers have private

More information

Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Econ 2004

Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Econ 2004 Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Econ 2004 Practice Questions for Master Class 3 on Tuesday and Wednesday, March 2 and 3, 2010 and Master Class 4 on Tuesday and Wednesday, March 9 and 10, 2010 MULTIPLE CHOICE.

More information

Harvard University Department of Economics

Harvard University Department of Economics Harvard University Department of Economics General Examination in Microeconomic Theory Spring 00. You have FOUR hours. Part A: 55 minutes Part B: 55 minutes Part C: 60 minutes Part D: 70 minutes. Answer

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct. UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures 13-14 Oct. 1, 2011 Pricing While there is some involved analysis required,

More information

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup Theory Appendix In this appendix, we provide a stylized model based on our empirical setting to analyze the effect of competition on author behavior. The general idea is that in a market with imperfect

More information

Review Questions. Unions and Collective Bargaining. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

Review Questions. Unions and Collective Bargaining. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response. 192 Ehrenberg/Smith Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Tenth Edition Review Questions Choose the letter that represents the BEST response. Unions and Collective Bargaining 1. Which of the

More information

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed

More information

Trade Liberalization, Heterogeneous Firms and the Soft Budget Constraint. Michael Alexeev* and. Yong Joon Jang** June 2010

Trade Liberalization, Heterogeneous Firms and the Soft Budget Constraint. Michael Alexeev* and. Yong Joon Jang** June 2010 Trade Liberalization, Heterogeneous Firms and the Soft Budget Constraint by Michael Alexeev* and Yong Joon Jang** June 2010 * Department of Economics, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405; e-mail:

More information

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari These notes cover the basics of the first part of our classical model discussion. Review them in detail prior to the second class

More information

The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014

The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014 The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014 David Jaume June 2017 Preliminary and incomplete Abstract Most developing countries invest increasing shares of

More information

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK. University of California, Berkeley Department of Economics Field Exam January 2017 Labor Economics There are three parts of the exam. Please answer all three parts. You should plan to spend about one hour

More information

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as Economists typically assume that firms or a firm s owners try to maximize their profit. et R be revenues of the firm, and C be the cost of production, then a firm s profit can be represented as follows,

More information

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, 10 12 September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne Institutional quality and contract complexity: the effects on the intensive and extensive margins of trade

More information

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand WP-2009-001 Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand Rupayan Pal Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai January 2009 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2009-001.pdf

More information

Globalization and Organization of the Firm

Globalization and Organization of the Firm Globalization and Organization of the Firm Carl Davidson *, Fredrik Heyman +, Steven Matusz *, Fredrik Sjöholm +, and Susan Chun Zhu * This version 2014-03-24 Abstract: Engagement in foreign markets can

More information

The Beveridge Curve. IZA DP No Eran Yashiv. December 2006 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Beveridge Curve. IZA DP No Eran Yashiv. December 2006 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2479 The Beveridge Curve Eran Yashiv December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor The Beveridge Curve Eran Yashiv Tel Aviv

More information

The Effect of Benefits on Unemployment when the Wage Bargaining Regime is Endogenous

The Effect of Benefits on Unemployment when the Wage Bargaining Regime is Endogenous The Effect of Benefits on Unemployment when the Wage Bargaining Regime is Endogenous Rønnaug Melle Johansen Økonomisk Institutt UNIVERSITETET I OSLO Mai 29 Acknowledgments Writing my master thesis has

More information

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) Public Economics by Luca Spataro Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) 1 Introduction Connection between agents outside the price system The level of externality

More information

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer? Microeconomics, Module 7: Competition in the Short Run (Chapter 7) Additional Illustrative Test Questions (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: June 9, 2005 Question 7.1: Pricing in a

More information

Price setting problem: Rigidities

Price setting problem: Rigidities Advanced Monetary Theory and Policy EPOS 2012/13 Price setting problem: Rigidities Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it New Keynesian Economics Most economists believe that short-run

More information

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs. This year, if national product at factor cost is Rs. 500 billion, indirect taxes 150 billion and subsidies Rs. 50 billion, then national product at market prices will be: _ Rs. 700 billion. _ Rs. 650 billion.

More information

Emission Tax or Standard? TheRoleofProductivityDispersion

Emission Tax or Standard? TheRoleofProductivityDispersion Emission Tax or Standard? TheRoleofProductivityDispersion Zhe Li Shanghai University of Finance and Economics (li.zhe@mail.shufe.edu.cn) Shouyong Shi Department of Economics University of Toronto (shouyong@chass.utoronto.ca)

More information

Firm Distribution. Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis. April 2017

Firm Distribution. Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis. April 2017 Firm Distribution Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis April 2017 1 A. Introduction Conventional macroeconomic models employ aggregate production at national or industrial

More information

Quasi linear Utility and Two Market Monopoly

Quasi linear Utility and Two Market Monopoly Quasi linear Utility and Two Market Monopoly By Stephen K. Layson Department of Economics 457 Bryan Building, UNCG Greensboro, NC 27412 5001 USA (336) 334 4868 Fax (336) 334 5580 layson@uncg.edu ABSTRACT

More information

Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis

Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Articles and Chapters ILR Collection 1997 Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis Gary S. Fields Cornell University, gsf2@cornell.edu Follow

More information

Final Exam - Solutions

Final Exam - Solutions Ecn 100 - Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 009 Instructor: John Parman Final Exam - Solutions You have until 1:30pm to complete this exam. Be certain to put

More information

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note Giorgos Stamatopoulos University of Crete 12 April 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86143/ MPRA Paper No. 86143,

More information

The Decision to Import

The Decision to Import March 2010 The Decision to Import Mark J. Gibson Washington State University Tim A. Graciano Washington State University ABSTRACT Why do some producers choose to use imported intermediate inputs while

More information

Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge

Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge by Luis Garicano and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Since the seminal work of Katz and Murphy (1992), the study of wage inequality has taken as its starting point a

More information

Efficiency Wages and Unemployment in a Global Economy

Efficiency Wages and Unemployment in a Global Economy Efficiency Wages and Unemployment in a Global Economy Udo Kreickemeier Leverhulme Centre for Research on Globalisation and Economic Policy University of Nottingham June 2003 preliminary version Abstract

More information

Chapter 1- Introduction

Chapter 1- Introduction Chapter 1- Introduction A SIMPLE ECONOMY Central PROBLEMS OF AN ECONOMY: scarcity of resources problem of choice Every society has to decide on how to use its scarce resources. Production, exchange and

More information

Strategic environmental policy under free trade with. transboundary pollution

Strategic environmental policy under free trade with. transboundary pollution Strategic environmental policy under free trade with transboundary pollution Harvey E. Lapan Shiva Sikdar Iowa State University National University of Singapore October 2008 Abstract We analyze the effects

More information

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence Learning Objectives: Students should learn to: 1. Define and give examples of predatory conduct. 2. Explain stylized facts about the entry of firms into industries.

More information

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Simona Grassi Ching-to Albert Ma Max Weber Fellow Department of Economics European University Institute Boston University Villa La Fonte, Via Delle Fontanelle,

More information

SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS BSc. (APPLIED ACCOUNTING) GENERAL / SPECIAL DEGREE PROGRAMME END SEMESTER EXAMINATION JULY 2016

SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS BSc. (APPLIED ACCOUNTING) GENERAL / SPECIAL DEGREE PROGRAMME END SEMESTER EXAMINATION JULY 2016 All Rights Reserved No. of Pages - 08 No of Questions - 08 SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS BSc. (APPLIED ACCOUNTING) GENERAL / SPECIAL DEGREE PROGRAMME END SEMESTER EAMINATION JULY 2016 BEC 30325 Managerial

More information

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market Summary - Chapter 5 Labour Markets and Unemployment 5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market 5.2.1 Labour Supply and the Consumption Leisure Trade-off - The consumption leisure trade-off is the fundamental

More information

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Instructor: Thomas Chaney Econ 357 - International Trade (Ph.D.) Introduction In this class, we will see two papers that will be used as building blocks of most of this

More information

Water Resource Economics C H A P T E R A W A T E R D E M A N D, S U P P L Y, A N D A L L O C A T I O N

Water Resource Economics C H A P T E R A W A T E R D E M A N D, S U P P L Y, A N D A L L O C A T I O N Water Resource Economics C H A P T E R A W A T E R D E M A N D, S U P P L Y, A N D A L L O C A T I O N Reader, based on Griffin (2006), 2.1-2.6 Text Organization 1. Costs of water supply 2. Efficiency

More information

The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: The Role of Matching Costs Revisited

The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: The Role of Matching Costs Revisited MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: The Role of Matching Costs Revisited José Ignacio Silva and Manuel Toledo Universitat de Girona 25. May 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/17719/

More information

Final Exam - Solutions

Final Exam - Solutions Ecn 100 - Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis December 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman Final Exam - Solutions You have until 12:30 to complete this exam. Be certain to put your

More information

Macroeconomics II Unemployment

Macroeconomics II Unemployment Macroeconomics II Unemployment Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 6 from Mankiw (2003; 2010) Spring 2018 Where we are and where we are heading to Macroeconomics I covers the IS-LM Model which delivers Aggregate Demand

More information

1 Competitive Equilibrium

1 Competitive Equilibrium 1 Competitive Equilibrium Each household and each firm in the economy act independently from each other, seeking their own interest, and taking as given the fact that other agents will also seek their

More information

Reflections on Carbon Leakage

Reflections on Carbon Leakage Reflections on Carbon Leakage Larry Karp October 13, 2010 Abstract The general equilibrium effects of stricter environmental policy might reinforce or moderate the partial equilibrium effects. In some

More information

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings

More information

Unemployment, Environmental Policy, and International Migration* Kenji Kondoh. And. Shigemi Yabuuchi. Abstract

Unemployment, Environmental Policy, and International Migration* Kenji Kondoh. And. Shigemi Yabuuchi. Abstract Unemployment, Environmental Policy, and International igration* Kenji Kondoh And Shigemi Yabuuchi Abstract In this paper, we investigate the effects of an increase in emission tax, a decrease in fixed

More information

How Sticky Wages In Existing Jobs Can Affect Hiring

How Sticky Wages In Existing Jobs Can Affect Hiring How Sticky Wages In Existing Jobs Can Affect Hiring Mark Bils University of Rochester NBER Yongsung Chang University of Rochester Yonsei University February 5, Sun-Bin Kim Yonsei University Abstract We

More information

Growth and Unemployment (without market frictions)

Growth and Unemployment (without market frictions) Growth and Unemployment (without market frictions) Javier A. Birchenall University of California at Santa Barbara 22 Abstract This note introduces structural unemployment into an otherwise standard growth

More information

The Microfoundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies: Dicussion of Duranton and Puga (DP), 2004

The Microfoundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies: Dicussion of Duranton and Puga (DP), 2004 1 / 33 The Microfoundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies: Dicussion of Duranton and Puga (DP), 2004 Nathan Schiff Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Graduate Urban Economics, Lecture 3 March

More information

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit by Robin Boadway, Queen s University, Canada Zhen Song, Central University of Finance and Economics, China Jean-François Tremblay,

More information

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006 FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006 QUESTION NO: 1 (MARKS: 1) - PLEASE CHOOSE ONE Compared to the equilibrium price and quantity sold in a competitive market, a monopolist Will charge a price and sell a quantity.

More information

Efficiency Wages and Unemployment in a Global Economy

Efficiency Wages and Unemployment in a Global Economy Efficiency Wages and Unemployment in a Global Economy Udo Kreickemeier University of Nottingham, Leverhulme Centre for Research on Globalisation and Economic Policy July 2003 Abstract This paper considers

More information

Caballero and Hammour, Macroeconomics of factor specificity, JPE 1998

Caballero and Hammour, Macroeconomics of factor specificity, JPE 1998 Caballero and Hammour, Macroeconomics of factor specificity, JPE 1998 Notation: Factors 1 and 2 (e.g., labor and capital) that can produce a single consumption good either in autarky or jointly. total

More information

LABOUR ECONOMICS - ECOS3008

LABOUR ECONOMICS - ECOS3008 LABOUR ECONOMICS - ECOS3008 Definitions Casual employment: Full time or part time employment in which the employee receives a cash loading in lieu of entitlement to non-wage benefits such as paid annual

More information

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6 Econ 792 Labor Economics Lecture 6 1 "Although it is obvious that people acquire useful skills and knowledge, it is not obvious that these skills and knowledge are a form of capital, that this capital

More information

In Search of Labor Demand

In Search of Labor Demand In Search of Labor Demand Paul Beaudry David A. Green Ben Sand September, 2014 Abstract We propose and estimate a novel specification of the labor demand curve incorporating search frictions and the role

More information

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3 1 Chapter 1 1.1. Scarcity, Choice, Opportunity Cost Definition of Economics: Resources versus Wants Wants: more and better unlimited Versus Needs: essential limited Versus Demand: ability to pay + want

More information

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld Chapter 6 Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany International Economics: Theory and Policy, Sixth Edition by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice

More information

Different Models in International Trade

Different Models in International Trade Master s Degree programme in Economics - Models and methods in economics and management Final Thesis Different Models in International Trade From the Krugman-Melitz framework to the new Addilog Theory

More information

2) A production method that relies on large quantities of labor and smaller quantities of capital equipment is referred to as a: 2)

2) A production method that relies on large quantities of labor and smaller quantities of capital equipment is referred to as a: 2) Micro: TA Session 4, Problem set MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) The main difference between a short-run production function and

More information

A Simple Model of Globalization, Schooling and Skill Acquisition

A Simple Model of Globalization, Schooling and Skill Acquisition A Simple Model of Globalization, Schooling and Skill Acquisition Carl Davidson * and Nicholas Sly ** Abstract: We develop a model of schooling and skill acquisition, highlighting informational asymmetries

More information

IS WAGE COMPRESSION A NECESSARY CONDITION FOR FIRM-FINANCED GENERAL TRAINING?

IS WAGE COMPRESSION A NECESSARY CONDITION FOR FIRM-FINANCED GENERAL TRAINING? IS WAGE COMPRESSION A NECESSARY CONDITION FOR FIRM-FINANCED GENERAL TRAINING? Alison L Booth and Gylfi Zoega Institute for Social and Economic Research University of Essex Wivenhoe Park Essex CO4 3SQ Email:

More information

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS Dimitrios A. Giannias Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie-Mellon University Dissertation Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the

More information

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Hongru Tan and Julian Wright March, 2018 Abstract We show that in the context of pricing by a multi-sided platform, in addition to the classical market-power

More information