Ultrabroadband Competition in Two-Sided Markets

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Ultrabroadband Competition in Two-Sided Markets"

Transcription

1 Ultrabroadband Competition in Two-Sided Markets Armando CALABRESE, Irene IACOVELLI & Nathan LEVIALDI GHIRON University of Rome "Tor Vergata", Italy Massimo GASTALDI University of L'Aquila, Italy Abstract: In this paper we study the competition among triple play operators, each one characterised by different attributes. We propose a mathematical model which analyses the impact of convergence between communication and telecommunication platforms on their pricing strategies. Key words: ultrabroadband innovation, two-sided platforms, triple play, telecommunication and communication industries. The paper is based on the multi-sided platform analysis (ARMSTRONG, 2004; CALABRESE et al., 2006; DOGANOGLU & WRIGHT, 2005; ROCHET & TIROLE, 2004a-b; and SCHIFF, 2003), that is on platforms that allow the interconnection of two different categories of players as, in the case of telecommunication and media industries, content providers and/or advertisers on one side of the platform and users (readers/viewers) on the other side (ARMSTRONG, 1999, 2005; GABSZEWICZ et al., 2005). The iteration between different clusters of users may be influenced by indirect network-effects, by strategic choices of the platforms (WRIGHT, 2002, 2003; EVANS, 2003; GABSZEWICZ et al., 2005), and by technological benefits available to the market players. Ultrabroadband innovation involves the convergence between communication and telecommunication industries (Triple Play). Thus, the aim of the paper is to analyse, through a simulation approach, the impact of convergence on the pricing strategies of triple play operators. More specifically we have extended the CHAKRAVORTI & ROSON model (2006) in order to study the competition among triple play operators, each one characterised by different peculiarities. In fact, the ultrabroadband development allows the entry of new players into the market and changes the competition for traditional incumbents. Thus we consider the competition COMMUNICATIONS & STRATEGIES, Special issue, Nov. 2008, p. 131.

2 132 Special issue, Nov among four players the incumbent (the traditional telecommunication or communication operator) and new entrants (both telecommunications and communication companies who, thanks to ultrabroadband, may now offer voice, data and video/tv through telecommunication networks) in order to represent and analyse the development of the telecommunication industry. The paper is organised as follows: first of all we define a two-sided market, highlighting the main contributions of the literature; then, we describe the ultrabroadband convergence (Triple Play), we introduce a mathematical model and we analyse the results of some numerical simulations. Finally, we conclude the paper with some observations and comments. Literature review The paper is based on the two-sided industry research. The ultrabroadband innovation allows the telecommunications firms to enter the two-sided markets (ARMSTRONG, 2004; CALABRESE et al., 2006; DOGANOGLU & WRIGHT, 2005; ROCHET & TIROLE, 2004a-b; ROSON, 2005; SCHIFF, 2003).The multi-sided platform markets can be defined as industries characterised by the interconnection between different groups of customers through a platform and by pricing strategies for each side (EVANS, 2003; ROCHET & TIROLE, 2004a-b).These industries range from computer games, to information technologies, to media, to telecommunication industries, to payment systems. According to the above definition a platform allows to increase the social surplus only if three necessary and sufficient conditions are observed: distinct groups of users, having their demand coordinated with each other, by means of a platform that coordinate their trade more efficiently than bilateral relationships (EVANS, 2003; ROCHET & TIROLE, 2004a-b). In an industrial economics framework the multi-sided platform industries are related to the concepts of network externalities and of multi-product pricing (ROCHET & TIROLE, 2004a-b). The ultrabroadband telecommunications can be characterized even by the interaction of two different customers' categories: the contents providers and/or advertisers and the users (readers and/or viewers) (ARMSTRONG, 2005; GABSZEWICZ et al., 2005).The interaction between these categories of users is influenced by the presence of indirect network-effects:

3 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 133 "advertisers value the service more if there are more members of an audience who will react positively to their messages; audiences value the service more if there are more useful messages" (EVANS, 2003).Thus the opposite network size represents a quality parameter in the platform selection (ROSON, 2005). Furthermore, according to WRIGHT (2002, 2003), such an interaction between the two market sides of a platform depends on their strategic choices. Viewers and readers can be both adverse to ads and interested in them, and some papers show the subsidiarization of readers by advertiser (GABSZEWICZ et al., 2005). Many authors have studied the platform competition (CAILLAUD & JULLIEN, 2003; ROCHET & TIROLE, 2002, 2003) but the relationship between innovation and platform competition has received less attention from the literature (ARMSTRONG, 1999; DISTASO et al., 2006; MILNE, 2005; WICKELGREN, 2004; ZOU, 2006). Moreover, two-sided platforms can develop product/service innovations or price differentiations in order to deal with market competition effectively (CALABRESE et al., 2008). The paper is based on CHAKRAVORTI & ROSON (2006). They construct a model to study competing payment networks offering differentiated products in terms of benefits to consumers and merchants. They analyse market equilibrium in several market structures: duopolistic competition and cartels, symmetric and asymmetric networks, taking into consideration alternative assumptions about consumer preferences in both cases. Their results show how competition increases consumer and merchant welfare. Ultrabroadband and convergence in telecommunication industries Over the last few years there has been a growing interest in the ICT market for multimedia and interactive services, such as fast Internet access, Video on Demand, Pay per View, e-commerce, video-conferences, home banking, on-line work from home, interactive games, etc. At present networks are generally categorised as being either broadband or narrowband, according to the capacity to transfer data which is available for the user.

4 134 Special issue, Nov The term broadband is utilised to describe a connection which can transport a great quantity of digital information. In this sense any transmission technology which allows a faster connection than the potential speed of an analogical modem in conjunction with a copper telephone line may be considered broadband. The future of telecommunication systems will require considerable investments in order to develop the ultrabroadband infrastructure that will allow integrated communication using voice, data, television and more. The technologies, whose continuous innovations will allow the development of an ultrabroadband infrastructure, are for example xdsl, fibre optics, wireless, power line communications and so on. Ultrabroadband allows telecommunications companies to enter into the communications markets (Triple Play). Traditional broadcasting is characterised by a price structure in which the audiences do not pay any fee while the advertisers pay a fee depending on the number of audiences. The convergence involves that telecommunication/communication platforms will be characterised by interactivity, security, speed, interoperability, audience targetization and so on. These attributes represents the benefits that new telecommunications/communications platforms involve for both markets sides (readers/viewers and advertisers). The aim of this paper is to analyse how the convergence, expressed in terms of some attributes (i.e. interactivity, security, speed, interoperability, audience targetization and so on), between communication and telecommunication platforms impacts on their pricing structure. In order to employ such an analysis we will develop some numerical simulation starting from the CHAKRAVORTI & ROSON (2006) model. The model The model describes the competition among four market players: the incumbent, i.e., the traditional communication or telecommunication operator and three competitors, i.e., both telecommunication and communication companies which, thanks to ultrabroadband, may offer voice, date and IPTV. We assume no utility is obtained by either readers/viewers and advertisers in using traditional communication or telecommunication operators. We consider the advertisers have no utility in using the incumbent as a media for

5 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 135 their ads hence its lack of targetization (the case of traditional broadcasting advertisement); on the audience side we consider that the contents impoverishment causes a null utility. Thus, according to the above assumptions we assume that all readers/viewers and advertisers do not pay any fees and do not obtain any benefits. In the following the triple play operators will be simply named as platforms; the competitors of our model will be the incumbent platform that will be simply named as incumbent and three new entrants that will be represented as platform 1, platform 2 and platform 3. We adopt the main assumptions made by the CHAKRAVORTI & ROSON (2006) model and will adapt them to the case of convergence in the telecommunication industry: All readers/viewers adopt only a platform i=1,2,3 (singlehoming). Considering that advertisers allow producing contents, we can assume that advertisements have a positive effect on audiences. Thus, the total benefit that each reader/viewer obtains by utilising the platform i=1,2,3 is given by multiplying the benefit for each connection to the platform, h c i, by the number of advertisers which use the platform i, D m i. The benefits, h c i, are distributed according to a uniform distribution in [0, i ], where i represents the maximum benefit that a reader/viewer may obtain from platform i and is calculated by adding the different attributes together, i.e interactivity, security, speed, interoperability and so on. Each reader/viewer pays the platform i a flat fee, f c i. The reader/viewer utility U c (in using one of the three platforms) is calculated from the difference between total benefits and fees. Moreover, let us assume that once a reader/viewer becomes a member of a platform, he/she will use this platform exclusively (such an assumption is always true in each time unit); thus the utility for a generic reader/viewer U c can be expressed as: U c =max {0,(h c 1 D m 1 f c 1 ),(h c 2 D m 2 f c 2 ), (h c 3 D m 3 f c 3 )}. [1] Each advertiser can broadcast advertisements on several platforms simultaneously (multihoming). Moreover it pays a fee for each advertisement, f m i. The benefit, h i m, which each advertiser obtains from platform i, when it provides an advertisement, is distributed according a uniform distribution in [0 i ], where i represents the maximum advertiser's benefit. i is calculated

6 136 Special issue, Nov by adding different attributes together i.e. interactivity, speed, interoperability, audience targetization and so on. The advertiser's utility U m in using platform i is calculated from the difference between benefits and fees. An advertiser will use a platform if he/she obtains a positive benefit from it; thus the utility for each advertiser U m can be expressed as: U m =max{0,(h 1 m -f 1 m )D 1 c }+max{0,(h 2 m -f 2 m )D 2 c }+max{0,(h 3 m -f 3 m )D 3 c }. [2] where D i c represents the number of readers/viewers using theplatform i. Readers/viewers utilise an alternative platform to the incumbent if such a platform meets two requirements: it produces a positive utility and the readers/viewers' utility (U c ) is greater than the utility provided by other platforms. We use the same assumptions as the CHAKRAVORTI & ROSON (2006) model, but expand on them in order to encompass competition between the three platforms. The market share can be seen in figure 1, where each reader/viewer is represented by a point whose coordinates (h 1 c D 1 m, h 2 c D 2 m, h 3 c D 3 m ) express the total benefits of using platforms 1, 2 or 3 (each point is obtained by multiplying the three benefits h i c by the number of advertisers who choose the platform i, D i m ). In figure 1, the parallelepiped is divided into 8 sections. Each one is derived from the intersection of the parallelepiped with the three planes that are obtained according to the values assumed by f c i. Readers/viewers within section 1 use the incumbent platform, since the net benefits offered by the other three platforms are negative. In sections 5, 2 and 4 readers/viewers choose the operator which offers them positive utility. In sections 6, 8, and 3 the competition is only between the two platforms that offer a positive net benefit. In figure 2, we show section 6 of parallelepiped (of figure 1) where, in this particular case, the competition is between platform 1 and platform 2. In fact in section 6 since h c 1 D m 1 >f c 1 and h c 2 D m 2 >f c 2, the platform 1 and platform 2 offer positive net benefits; while given that h c 3 D m 3 <f c 3, platform 3 offers a negative net benefit to readers/viewers. Figure 2 shows a volume divided into two parts. The grey section represents the percentage of demand equally divided between two platforms (platform 1, platform 2, platform 3). In fact, if platforms offer readers/viewers the same value of net benefits (grey volume of figure 2), readers/viewers choose on the basis of relative utility and the border between the two market shares is given by a 45 degree plane that splits the grey volume into two sections (CHAKRAVORTI

7 P1 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 137 & ROSON, 2006). The white volume represents the additional percentage of demand to be added to the platform which offers the greatest net benefit to the readers/viewers. Only the platform offering the highest readers/viewers surplus ( D m -f c ) attracts readers/viewers in the white volume (Chakravorti and Roson, 2006); for example if ( 2 D 2 m -f 2 c )>( 1 D 1 m -f 1 c ) the readers/viewers utility is the greatest using platform 2. Figure 1 Readers/viewers market shares on platform i P. P

8 138 Special issue, Nov Figure 2 - Enlargement of section 6 of the parallelepiped in figure 1 P P1 Section 7 represents the only volume in which readers/viewers obtain a positive utility in using all three platforms (1,2,3). The market share of each platform is represented in figure 3. The white cube at the bottom left of figure 3 is obtained by the third power of the minimum among 1 D 1 m -f 1 c, 2 D 2 m -f 2 c and D 3 m -f 3 c, that is, the utility of the platform which provides the minimum net benefit among all platforms. Since each platform provides a positive utility, each platform gains 1/3 of the white cube. In order to obtain the grey volume in figure 3, we found the intermediate value among 1 D 1 m - f 1 c, 2 D 2 m -f 2 c and D 3 m -f 3 c. The two platforms that offer the greatest net benefits gain half of the grey volume to sum to their respective market shares. In order to obtain the white parallelepiped at the right of figure 3, we calculated the maximum among 1 D 1 m -f 1 c, 2 D 2 m -f 2 c and D 3 m -f 3 c ; then we calculated the volume of this parallelepiped. Only the platform that provides the maximum value of net benefit gains the additional market share represented by this parallelepiped. Figure 3 - Enlargement of section 7 of the parallelepiped in figure 1 P 1

9 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 139 The market shares of readers/viewers' demand, for each platform, are obtained by adding the volumes (2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8) in figure 1, divided by the total market demand (m 1 * m 2 * m 3 ). The total readers/viewers' demand for each platform is represented respectively by the following Equations [3]: D 1 c ={{[b 1 * f 2 c * f 3 c ]+[((min(b 1,b 2 ) *f 3 c )+(b 1 -(min(b 1,b 2 )))*((min(b 1,b 2 ))* f 3 c )]+ +[((min(b 1,b 3 ) *f 2 c )+(b 1 -(min(b 1,b 3 )))*(min(b 1,b 3 ))*f 2 c ]+Z i }/m 1 *m 2 *m 3 }*C D 2 c ={{[b 2 * f 1 c * f 3 c ]+[((min(b 1,b 2 ) *f 3 c )+(b 2 -(min(b 1,b 2 )))*((min(b 1,b 2 ))*f 3 c )]+ +[((min(b 2,b 3 ) *f 1 c )+(b 2 -(min(b 2,b 3 )))*(min(b 2,b 3 ))*f 1 c +Z i }/m 1 *m 2 *m 3 }*C D 3 c ={{[b 3 * f 1 c * f 2 c ]+[((min(b 1,b 3 ) *f 2 c )+(b 3 -(min(b 1,b 3 )))*((min(b 1,b 3 ))*f 2 c )]+ +[((min(b 2,b 3 ) *f 1 c )+(b 3 -(min(b 2,b 3 )))*(min(b 2,b 3 ))*f 1 c +Z i }/m 1 *m 2 *m 3 }*C where: m m i = i* D i i =1,2,3; c b i = m i f i i =1,2,3; C= total number of readers/viewers; B= min{b 1,b 2, b 3 };A= max{b 1,b 2,b 3 };M=max{min{b 1,b 2 };min{b 1,b 3 };min{b 2,b 3 }}; if the platform i produces net benefits lower than the other platforms; Z i = if the platform i produces net benefits between the ones produced by other platforms; if the platform i produces net benefits greater than other platforms. B 3 represents the white cube in the left of parallelepiped of figure 3: according to Equation [3] for each platform (platform 1, platform 2, platform 3), 1/3*B 3 has to be added to market shares. M 2 *B-B 3 represents the grey area in figure 3: according to Equation [3] for two platforms (platform 1, platform 2, platform 3) that offer the greatest net benefits, 1/2*(M 2 *B-B 3 ) has to be added to 1/3*B 3. (A-M)*M*B represents the white volume on the right part of the parallelepiped of figure 3: according to

10 140 Special issue, Nov Equation [3] for the platform (platform 1, platform 2, platform 3) that provide maximum net benefits (A-M)*M*B has to be added to 1/3*B 3 + 1/2*(M 2 *B-B 3 ). Under the assumption that the advertisers use the platform i if and only if the benefits are greater than the costs (h i m f i m ), the demand of the advertisers is equal to: D i m =Pr(h i m f i m )*M = (1 - K i m (f i m )) *M. [4] where M represents the number of advertisers on the market. For simplicity, let us assume that the advertisers benefits are distributed with a uniform distribution, K i m, in [0, i ]. Each platform faces two types of costs: the cost, g i, on the readers/ viewers' side and a cost, c i, on the advertisers' side. The profit of each platform is given by: i = (f i c - g i ) D i c +( f i m - c i ) D i m D i c. [5] The numerical simulations: the impact of convergence between communication and telecommunication platforms on price structures In this section we will analyse the impact of convergence between communication and telecommunication platforms on their pricing strategies. In order to do this we will employ some numerical simulations whose data has been tested by interviews with experts on such industries. The simulations will be developed through the use of Matlab (MATrix LABoratory) software; they are based on the following assumptions: 1. The cost g i, on the readers/viewers' side and the cost c i, on the advertisers' side are equal to zero. 2. We consider eight scenarios, each one based on the following assumptions: For three scenarios (see tables 1, 2 and 3) we consider that the benefits offered by platform 1 are lower than the others competitors, the benefits offered by the platform 3 are the greatest and finally the benefits

11 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 141 offered by platform 2 are between the benefits of the others two competitors (see tables 1, 2 and 3). The three scenarios are based on the following assumptions: - In the first scenario (A) the values of i are equal to i (see table 1), in the second scenario (B) the values i are greater than i, (see table 2), finally in the third scenario (C) the values of i are lower than i (see table 3). - For each scenario we fixed the starting values of i and (for i=1,2,3). In particular, in the scenario A the values of i and i are equal to 1 for the platform 1; 1.5 for the platform 2 and 2 for the platform 3. In the scenario B, the values of i are equal to 1 for the platform 1; 1.5 for the platform 2 and 2 for the platform 3, while the values of i are equal to 0.5; 1; 1.5 respectively. In the scenario C the values of i are equal to 0.5; 1 and 1.5 respectively, while the values of i are equal to 1; 1.5 and 2. - For each scenario (A, B, C) we compare the starting situation, (described above), with the four other cases. In particular, in the first case both the readers/viewers benefit level, i, and the advertisers benefit level, i, increase, with respect to the starting situation, of 0.5; in the second case of 1; in the third case of 1.5 and finally in the fourth case of 2 (see tables 1,2 and 3). In the scenarios D, E and F we suppose that the three platforms (1,2,3) offer the same benefits and that each platform fix i i (see tables 4, 5 and 6). In particular, in the scenario D i and i are equal to 0.1 (see table 4); in the scenario E i and i are equal to 2 (see table 5); and finally, in the scenario F i and i are equal to 4 (see table 6). In the scenarios G and H we suppose that the three platforms (1,2,3) offer the same benefits both to the readers/viewers and the advertisers (see tables 7 and 8). In particular, in the scenario G i = and i =0.1 (see table 7); while in the scenario H i =0.1 and i = 4 (see table 8). 3. Our inputs are both the benefit values ( i and ) and the costs (g i and c i ). 4. Our outputs: the platform profits and market shares (calculated using the model described in the previous section); the advertisers fees and the readers/viewers fees (determinated through the use of Matlab code). We provide some numerical examples in order to analyse the relationships between convergence and platforms pricing structures.

12 142 Special issue, Nov Input & pricing structures Table 1 Scenario A Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m Input & pricing structures Table 2 - Scenario B Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m

13 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 143 Input & pricing structures Table 3 Scenario C Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m The table 1 shows that when the platforms offer to both market sides the same benefit levels i ), the platforms fix the readers/viewers fees equal to the advertisers fees (f c /D m = f m ). Table 2 shows that when i > i the platforms fix f i c /D m > f i m while table 3 shows that when i < i the platforms fix f i c /D m < f i m. Tables 1, 2 and 3 show that the platform which offers the greatest benefit levels, compared to competitors, fixes the highest fees (platform 3); moreover the fees are always related to the broadband benefits. Table 4 Scenario D Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m Table 5 Scenario E Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m

14 144 Special issue, Nov Table 6 Scenario F Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m Tables 4, 5 and 6 show that when i the readers/viewers fees are almost equal to the advertisers fees. Tables 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6 show that an increase in the benefit levels ( and ), due to ultrabroadband innovation, increases both the readers/viewers and the advertisers fees. Table 7 Scenario G Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m Table 7 shows that when i the platforms fix the readers/viewers fee greater than the advertiser fees (f i c /D m > f i m ). Table 8 Scenario H Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m Table 8 shows that when then f i c /D m < f i m. Tables 2,3,7 and 8 show that for some values of i and i the platforms fix the readers/viewers fees or the advertisers fees equal to zero. In particular, when the values of 1 the readers/viewers fees are equal to zero (see tables 3 and 8), instead, when 0.5 the advertisers fees are equal to zero (see tables 2 and 7). The table 4 shows an anomaly if compared to tables 2,3,7 and 8. In fact, the values of i and of i are equal to 0.1 but the fees are different from zero. Thus, we developed other numerical simulations (see appendix), which showed both when the platforms provide equal and different benefits that the fees tend to zero only if the values of and/or i are low and if there is a substantial asymmetry between the readers/viewers benefit levels and the advertisers benefit

15 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON 145 levels. In particular, the market side characterized by minor benefit has fees equal to zero (see tables 9 and 10). Table 9 Different benefits between the platforms Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m Table 10 Equal benefits between the platforms Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m Conclusion The simulations show a relation between the benefits provided by ultrabroaband convergence (triple play) and the pricing structures. In the case of benefits homogeneity ( i = ) on both sides, the pricing structure is composed by identical prices on both sides (see tables 1, 4, 5 and 6). Instead, in the case of benefits heterogeneity ( ) between the two sides of the market, the pricing structure is composed of higher prices on the market side characterized by higher benefit levels (see tables 2, 3, 7 and 8). Furthermore, the results show that the higher the benefit levels are the greater is the price level and thus each price on each platform side (see tables 1, 2 and 3). Finally, in the case of low values of both i and/or i and of a substantial asymmetry between the readers/viewers benefit levels and the advertisers benefit levels, platforms fix the fees equal to zero on the market side characterized by the lowest benefit levels.

16 146 Special issue, Nov References ARMSTRONG, M.: - (1999): "Competition in the Pay-TV Market", Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, Vol.13, pp (2004): "Competition in Two-Sided Markets", Mimeo, University College London. - (2005): "Public Service Broadcasting", Mimeo, University College London. CAILLAUD, B. & JULLIEN, B. (2003): "Chicken & Egg: Competition among Intermediation Service Providers," RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 34, pp CALABRESE, A., GASTALDI, M., & LEVIALDI GHIRON, N. (2006): "Development Prospects for Mobile Networks: the Multi-sided Platform Approach in the Competition Analysis, in R. Cooper, A. Lloyd, G. Madden, M. Schipp (Eds),The Economics of ICT Networks, Contribution to Economics Series, Heidelberg, Germany: Physica-Verlag. CALABRESE, A., GASTALDI, M., IACOVELLI, I. & LEVIALDI GHIRON, N. (2008): "Innovation and Competition in the Two-Sided Markets: the Case of the Payment Systems", International Journal of Management and Network Economics, Vol. 1, pp CHAKRAVORTI, S. & ROSON, R. (2006): "Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks," Review of Network Economics, Vol. 5, pp DISTASO, W., LUPI, P. & MANENTI, F.M. (2006): "Platform Competition and Broadband Uptake:Theory and Empirical Evidence from the European Union," Information Economics and Policy, Elsevier, Vol. 18, pp DOGANOGLU, T. & WRIGHT, J. (2005): "Multihoming and Compatibility," International Journal of Industrial Organization, Elsevier, Vol. 24, pp EVANS, D.S. (2003): "Some Empirical Aspects of Multi-Sided Platform Industries," Review of Network Economics, Vol. 2, pp GABSZEWICZ, J., LAUSSEL, D., & SONNAC, N. (2005): "Does Advertising Lower the Price of Newspapers to Consumers? A Theoretical Appraisal", Economics Letters, Elsevier, Vol. 87, pp MILNE, A. (2005): "What is in it for us? Network Effects and Bank Payment Innovation," Journal of Banking & Finance, Elsevier, Vol. 30, pp ROCHET, J.C. & TIROLE, J.: - (2002): "Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations," Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 33, pp (2003): "Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets," Journal of European Economic Association, Vol.1, pp

17 A. CALABRESE, M. GASTALDI, I. IACOVELLI & N. LEVIALDI GHIRON (2004a) "Defining Two-Sided Markets," Mimeo, Rochet: IDEI and GREMAQ, University of Toulouse and Tirole: IDEI and GREMAQ, University of Toulouse, CERAS, University of Paris, and MIT. - (2004b) "Two-Sided Markets: An Overview," Mimeo, IDEI University of Toulouse, A preliminary version was presented at "The Economics of Two-Sided Markets" Conference, held at the University of Toulouse, January. ROSON, R. (2005): "Two-Sided Markets: a Tentative Survey", Review of Network Economics, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp SCHIFF, A. (2003): "Open and Closed Systems of Two-Sided Networks," Information Economics and Policy, pp WICKELGREN, A.L. (2004): "Innovation, Market Structure and Holdup Problem: Investment Incentives and Coordination," International Journal of Industrial Organization, Elsevier, Vol. 22, pp WRIGHT, J.: - (2002): "Optimal Card Payment Systems," European Economic Review, Elsevier, Vol. 47, pp (2003) "Pricing in Debit and Credit Card Schemes," Economics Letters, Elsevier, Vol. 80, pp ZOU, B. (2006): "Vintage Technology, Optimal Investment and Technology adoption," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, Vol. 23, pp

18 148 Special issue, Nov Appendix Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m Input & pricing structures Platform 1 Platform 2 Platform f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m f m f c /D m