Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search"

Transcription

1 Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia March 30, 2014 Abstract We analyze how the market power of firms in consumer search markets depends on how consumers form beliefs about the offers they encounter on their next search. Using the Wolinsky model, we show that under symmetric beliefs, firms have much more market power and set higher prices. Pricing behavior is a non-monotonic function of search cost. We show that symmetric beliefs naturally arise in an environment where retailers common costs are unknown to consumers and either follow a random process or are determined by an upstream firm. The first environment allows us to provide an alternative explanation for sales (compared to Varian s model of sales). In the second environment, we show that the manufacturer has the incentives and the ability to prevent the market from breaking down, providing an alternative channel through which the Diamond paradox can be solved. JEL Classification: D40; D83; L13 Keywords: Vertical Relations, Consumer Search, Double Marginalization, Product Differentiation 1 Introduction When consumers search, they have to form beliefs about what offers they can expect to get at a next search. If they are pessimistic that the next search yields a good offer, they are more likely to accept the current offer, giving firms an incentive to set higher prices. Thus, market power in an industry where search is important crucially depends on consumer beliefs. This insight is important in any search market, but particularly so in markets where there is additional uncertainty concerning factors that influence market prices. For example, if consumers know that prices depend on firms marginal cost, but are uninformed about them, then beliefs about offers consumers can expect on the next search may depend on what consumers currently observe at the firm they are visiting. The consumer search literature, by and large, has side-stepped issues regarding consumer beliefs and implicitly or explicitly assumes that consumers hold passive beliefs, i.e., no matter what they observe at a particular search round, consumers believe that at a next search round they encounter firms that stick to their equilibrium strategies. There is, however, no reason not to consider alternative beliefs. For example, consumers could hold symmetric beliefs (see, Department of Economics, University of Vienna and State University Higher School of Economics. maarten.janssen@univie.ac.at Department of Economics, University of Vienna. sandro.shelegia@univie.ac.at 1

2 for instance, Hart and Tirole (1990), McAfee and Schwarz (1994) and more recently Pagnozzi and Piccolo (2012)), i.e., after observing in a search round that a firm has deviated from its equilibrium strategy, consumers could believe that other firms (that they would encounter on a next search) have also deviated in the same way. In this paper we show that symmetric beliefs emerge naturally in two important search settings and they lead to equilibrium predictions that are qualitatively and quantitatively different from predictions obtained under traditional passive beliefs. The first setting is one where firms have a common cost that fluctuates randomly and is not observed by consumers. The second considers a vertical industry where retailers cost is determined by an upstream monopoly. We take the now standard Wolinsky (1986) model of sequential search where cost is known and consumers have passive beliefs as our starting point. 1 To fully understand the impact of beliefs on market prices, and the price increasing effect of symmetric beliefs, we analyze the Wolinsky model for small and large search cost. Most papers that build on the Wolinsky model (see, e.g., Anderson and Renault (2006), Armstrong, Vickers and Zhou (2009) and Bar-Isaac, Caruana and Cuñat (2011)) take search costs to be relatively small so that the consumers reservation utility is not binding for the firms optimization problem. The behavior of the model for larger search cost is relatively under-explored. While it is known that, when the search cost is such that prices exceed consumers reservation utility, firms set the monopoly price (that is independent of the search cost), the literature has not looked int the equilibrium market demand that drops discretely at the critical level of the search cost. The reason is that once search cost is so high that prices are above the reservation utility, consumers are not willing to pay the cost to obtain a new utility draw in case the first one was unsatisfactory and drop out of the market. This leads to a drop in demand from those consumers who would have purchased at the second firm, but never arrive there. This unexplored market size effect is the second important ingredient our our results in the setting with vertical market structure. With symmetric beliefs in the Wolinsky model, it is not difficult to see that firms will set higher equilibrium prices as consumers are less willing to continue to search after observing a deviation to a higher price than the equilibrium price under passive beliefs. This price increasing effect drives our first main result, namely that under symmetric beliefs, prices are non-monotonic in search cost. The reason can be understood as follows. For large search cost, as consumer behavior is not driven by their beliefs about prices at the other firms, price equals the monopoly price. For very small search cost, the equilibrium price remains smaller than consumers reservation utility and here prices are increasing in search cost and larger than under passive beliefs. As the reservation utility is independent of whether consumers have passive or symmetric beliefs, this utility becomes binding at lower levels of the search cost. At these intermediate levels of search cost where the reservation utility is binding, equilibrium prices are equal to the reservation utility and as this utility is decreasing in search cost. Thus, for intermediate levels of the search cost, equilibrium prices are decreasing in search cost. 1 In the context of the alternative, homogeneous goods search model by Stahl (1989), Dana (1994), and more recently, Tappata (2009), Chandra and Tappata (2011) and Janssen, Pichler and Weidenholzer (2011) have analyzed the consequences of asymmetric information on firms common marginal cost. Janssen and Shelegia (2014) study retailers common cost being determined by an upstream firm and the consequences of this wholesale price not being observed by consumers. These models use passive beliefs, because in a homogeneous goods model reservation price equilibrium does not exist under symmetric beliefs. 2

3 These observations are of importance for understanding the implications consumers not having information about a common cost component of firms. This situation is relevant in retail gasoline markets, for example, where retail gasoline stations know today s world oil market price (as this is reflected in the common cost they have), but consumers probably do not know current world oil market prices (due to the fact that they are highly volatile). Symmetric beliefs are natural in such a setting where retailers have a common cost as after observing a retail price by one firm, consumers form beliefs about the cost that is common to all retailers. Along the equilibrium path, upon observing a high price, consumers will infer that common cost is high and that the other retailer will also have a high price. Given the observation on the Wolinsky model with symmetric beliefs, it is not surprising that in this setting with small search cost there exists a symmetric equilibrium where for each cost realization, prices (and firms profits) are strictly larger than in the corresponding model where cost is known to consumers and they have passive beliefs. Symmetric beliefs make continuing searching less attractive, providing firms with more market power and an incentive to raise prices. Interestingly, for some level of search cost, the equilibrium price can be as high as the joint profit maximizing price! When this happens, the joint profit maximizing price equals consumers reservation utility. It also follows that for a given cost realization, retail price may be decreasing in search cost when search cost is at intermediate values. An interesting feature that plays an important role in the vertical relations model discussed below is that for most values of the search cost, the equilibrium pricing strategy has a flat part where price does not vary with cost, apart from parts where price is increasing in cost. Thus, for many parameter values the equilibrium is neither pooling, nor separating, but semi-separating. The reason is that there is a region of cost levels where the equilibrium price equals consumers reservation utility and this reservation utility is independent of cost. An interesting aspect of this equilibrium characterization is that it provides an alternative explanation for the common observation that retailers often follow a pricing strategy for their products that is characterized by a regular price and a sales price at irregular moments in time (as in Varian (1980) s model of sales). Unlike the existing literature, our model can explain sales in terms of a pure strategy equilibrium where a firm s price is a function of its cost (with horizontal parts where price is independent of cost). We then turn to the results of our paper dealing with vertical relations, where the retailers common cost is set by an upstream firm. We show that in this vertical relations model with search, a combination of interesting features that have been discussed above in isolation can arise. To do so, we add to the Wolinsky model an upstream firm setting the wholesale price. In the benchmark vertical model consumers observe this wholesale price. We then compare the equilibrium of that model with the case where the wholesale price remains unknown to consumers. When wholesale price is observed, but search cost is small, we have a model where the upstream firm chooses its profit maximizing price given the margins that downstream firms will charge. For small search costs downstream prices are smaller than the consumers reservation utility and increasing in search cost, even though upstream prices are falling. Once the search cost crosses a critical level, the retail price becomes larger than the consumers reservation price (with the corresponding drop in market demand as a consequence) in case the manufacturer does 3

4 not drastically adjust its behavior. As the manufacturer has a clear incentive that consumers who are not satisfied at the first retailer continue to search to see whether the product of the second retailer better fits their taste, it will prevent the market demand to drop by lowering its price significantly. This leads to retail prices also falling in search cost. It is interesting to observe that this creates a second channel through which the Diamond paradox can be solved. Wolinsky (1986) solves the Diamond paradox by introducing product differentiation. However, when search cost becomes large and the first search is costly, the market will still break down in his model as retail firms individually cannot prevent this from happening. By being able to influence both retail prices, the manufacturer has different incentives and has the ability to keep the market active for (much) higher levels of search cost. Of course, (depending on whether or not the first search is for free) when search cost rises further there is a point where also the manufacturer has to set such a low price to prevent the market demand to fall that it is not in its interest to do so. When the first search cost is not for free, this will happen at the point where the manufacturer charges a price equal to its marginal cost. When the search cost is for free, at this level of search cost, wholesale and retail prices drastically increase to the classic double marginalisation level. Consumers stop searching at this point and for all larger search cost the equilibrium prices are constant. When retail costs are not observed by consumers, there are multiple equilibria depending on to whom consumers attribute a deviation from the conjectured (equilibrium) retail price. As retail prices are now the outcome of the combination of a retail pricing strategy and the actual upstream price chosen, a consumer cannot know whether the upstream firm or the retailer has deviated after observing a deviation and both passive and symmetric beliefs can be rationalized. Under passive beliefs, the equilibrium structure is very similar to the case where wholesale price is observed. The only difference is that the manufacturer may have an incentive to charge a different price due to the fact that its deviations are not observed. As this effect on the unobservability of the wholesale price to consumers is explored in Janssen and Shelegia (2014), we focus here on the impact of consumer beliefs. With symmetric beliefs, for a given wholesale price downstream behavior is identical to that behavior in the random cost model. This fact creates interesting incentives for the manufacturer. In particular, at a certain level of search cost, as the retail price is independent of retailers cost, the manufacturer has an incentive to increase price and the equilibrium wholesale price increases discontinuously in search cost. With wholesale price being unobserved by consumers, to the market size effect also provides the manufacturer with incentives to reduce its price for larger search cost. The range of parameters for which the manufacturer can prevent the market from breaking down is reduced, however. Thus, in the case where the wholesale arrangement is unobserved by consumers, wholesale prices can be increasing in search cost, decreasing in search cost, and may perform discontinuous jumps. Retail prices fall with search costs in a surprisingly large interval and the quantitive effects we show in numerical examples can be quite substantial. Thus, the forces created by symmetric beliefs and the market size effect can be empirically important. This paper is related to several strands of literature. In the context of the homogeneous goods search model by Stahl (1989), Dana (1994), and more recently, Tappata (2009), Chandra and Tappata (2011) and Janssen, Pichler and Weidenholzer (2011) have analyzed an asymmetric 4

5 information model where firms know their common cost and consumers do not. 2 These papers show that for the same average cost realization equilibrium prices in the asymmetric information model are higher than in the setting where the cost is known to be equal to the average cost of the cost uncertainty model. Our results in this paper for the asymmetric information model are stronger in that we show that for all cost realizations prices are higher. Moreover, in our asymmetric information model prices are non-monotonic in search cost, whereas they are monotonically increasing in the homogeneous goods search models. The difference in results is related to the difference in underlying mechanism: in our paper the main mechanism builds on symmetric beliefs and the market size effect, while symmetric beliefs would destroy the equilibrium analysis in the homogeneous goods search literature. The importance of beliefs in a vertical structure has recently also been stressed by Pagnozzi and Piccolo (2012). In that paper, the authors study the reason for manufacturers to sell to consumers via an independent retailer rather than directly. In their framework, it is retailers that have to form beliefs about the wholesale prices that manufacturers charge to their competitors. They show that the nature of the vertical channel depends on whether retailers hold passive or symmetric beliefs. Janssen and Shelegia (2014) perform the vertical analysis of the Stahl (1989) model where retailers cost is determined by a manufacturer maximizing profits. They consider two different scenarios, one where consumers do not observe retailers cost and one where they do. show that the unobservability of retailers cost has severe implications for the prices charged in the market due to the fact that market demand is much more inelastic when the wholesale price is unobserved. The analysis of the vertical structure in the current paper mainly relies on mechanisms (symmetric beliefs and the market size effect) that are absent in Janssen and Shelegia (2014). Other explanations for prices being declining in search cost differ sharply from the ones that are given in earlier contributions. In Janssen et al. (2005) a participation effect is responsible for prices being declining in search cost. In that model the equilibrium fraction of consumers participating in the market is determined by a participating constraint and if search cost are large that constraint is binding. Zhou (2014) studies a multi-product search environment where with one search, consumers can buy multiple products. In this environment products become complements and if search cost become higher, firms may compete more intensely to keep the consumers from searching further. We provide two alternative reasons why retail prices may be declining in search cost. First, in the absence of vertical considerations, there is an intermediate region of search cost where retail prices are higher than the monopoly price and the consumer reservation utility is binding and this reservation utility is decreasing in search cost. Second, this effect is significantly strengthened under vertical relations when the manufacturer has an additional incentive to prevent retail prices to be larger than the reservation utility. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. they The next section sets out the model we use to analyze the pricing implications of the different environments we study. Section 3 then analyzes the implications of symmetric beliefs in the Wolinsky model and it shows the underexplored market size effect. Section 4 discusses the implications of asymmetric information 2 In the context of different models, Benabou and Gertner (1993) and Fishman (1996) have also studied the effects of asymmetric information about retailers cost in consumer search models. 5

6 concerning retailers common cost. Interestingly, the increased price effect does not disappear if cost uncertainty vanishes. Section 5 then analyzes the effects of asymmetric information concerning retailers common cost in an environment where this cost is not a random variable, but strategically chosen by an upstream firm. The last section concludes. 2 The models The retail side of the three models is exactly the same as in Wolinsky (1986). There are two retail firms, 1 and 2, who can acquire some input at a common cost c. The retailers transform the input costlessly into a final differentiated good, using a one for one technology. There is a unit mass of consumers per firm. Utility to a consumer from buying the good at firm i is v i. This utility is drawn according to some distribution function G(v i ), which is defined over the interval [v, v]. The valuation of a consumer for the product of firm 1 is independent of his valuation for the product of firm 2. Each consumer costlessly visits one of the downstream firms at random and finds out v i and p i. After visiting the first firm, consumers have to decide whether to buy there, search the second retail firm, or stop searching altogether. The additional search comes at a cost s. The consumer can always go back to the first firm at no additional cost (free recall). In the search literature based on the Wolinsky model, it is common to denote by w the expected utility of searching another firm including the search cost. Consumers visit the first firm for free, 3 and after observing the match value v i and the price p i they decide whether or not to visit the second firm. If they do so, they make their purchase at the best available surplus v i p i. If they decide not to continue searching, they buy at the first firm if v i p i 0. In general, an individual retailer i s demand depends on the price p i it chooses, the price p j of firm j and on consumers beliefs p e j about the price of firm j. The latter may depend on the marginal cost c and price charged by firm i. For now we will keep the formulation general, and specify model-specific beliefs later. Consider a consumer who visits firm i. To determine the reservation utility w we have to determine the benefit from searching firm j. Under free recall, the reservation utility w if prices are equal at both firms, is the solution to: v w (v w )f(v) dv = s. If such a solution does not exist, then w = v. This means that a consumer who draws v i and p i will search the other firm if v i < w p e j + p i. For consumers to ever continue to search we need that w > p e j. If this inequality is not satisfied, a consumer will not continue to search. Given the optimal search behavior from above, firm 1 s demand is given by Q 1 (p 1 ) = (1 G(w p e 2 + p 1 )) + G(w p e 1 + p 2 )(1 G(w p e 1 + p 1 )) (1) + w p e 2 +p 1 p 1 G(p 2 p 1 + v)g(v)dv + w p e 1 +p 1 p 1 G(p 2 p 1 + v)g(v)dv. 3 Here, we follow most of the consumer search literature. When desired we show, however, how our results depend on this assumption. 6

7 The first term is the demand from consumers who visit firm 1 and buy outright because their v 1 falls below the threshold w p e 2 + p 1. The second term is the demand from consumers who visit firm 2, draw v 2 lower than the threshold w p e 1 + p 2 move on to firm 1, encounter there v 1 more than w p e 1 + p 1 and buy at firm 1. The first integral is the demand from those who move on from firm 1 to firm 2, but come back to firm 1. Finally, the second integral is the demand from those consumers who first visit firm 2, move on to firm 1 and buy there. To understand the role of beliefs in the Wolinsky model, we formally define the equilibrium notion below. As, depending on the out-of-equilibrium beliefs, consumers beliefs about the price to be observed at the next search may depend on the price p 1 observed at the first search, consumers expected utility (or reservation utility) of searching another firm may depend on the price observed at the first firm, and we write w (p 1 ). Definition 1. A symmetric perfect Bayesian equilibrium of the Wolinsky model is a price p (the same for both firms) and a reservation utility w (p) such that 1. Each firm i chooses p i = p to maximize its expected profit given the price of the other firm and consumers reservation utility; i.e., firm i will set a price that solve the first order condition where Q 1 is given in (1); p 1 = c Q 1 Q 1 (p 1), 2. Consumers follow an optimal search rule given their beliefs and the match value v i and the price p i they observe at firm i; 3. Consumers beliefs are updated using Bayes Rule when possible, i.e., whenever they observe p 1 = p at their first search, they believe that the other firm has also set a price p. Outof-equilibrium beliefs p e 2 of the price set by the firm that is not yet visited are either i. (passive beliefs) such that p e 2 = p if p 1 p, or ii. (symmetric beliefs) such that p e 2 = p 1 if p 1 p. In principle, one could study the implications of many different formulations of out-ofequilibrium beliefs. For example, one could specify a convex combination of passive and symmetric beliefs or one could have a different belief for different out-of-equilibrium prices. Passive beliefs is the common assumption in the search literature and we want to study the impact of that assumption by studying the implications of another belief formation process that is considered in another literature (see, e.g., Hart et al. (1990) and Mcafee and Schwartz (1994) in the context of vertical relations between a manufacturer and two retailers, something we also consider later). As explained in the Introduction, we also (and mainly) want to supplement the Wolinsky model with settings where the common cost is determined. First, we consider a market where the common cost c follows a random distribution with support [c, c]. Firms know the realization of c, but consumers do not, so that we have asymmetric information between firms and consumers. One can think of this as the common cost being determined in a competitive (upstream) market 7

8 environment where price is determined by supply and demand. Consumers think it is highly unlikely (a probability 0 event) that cost is below c or above c. A second environment we consider is where the common cost is determined by an upstream monopolist. The upstream firm U produces the essential input at a marginal cost of zero and charges c for one unit to the downstream competitors. In this second environment we study a benchmark model where retailers cost is observed by consumers and a model where it is not observed. The timing of these two games is that the common cost is determined either by Nature or by an upstream firm. The choice of c is observed by the downstream firms (and, in the benchmark vertical relations model, but only there, also by consumers). After c is determined, we have the same interaction between retailers and consumers as described above. In the asymmetric information model where retailers cost is randomly determined, retailers (symmetric) strategy is given by a function p(c), whereas the search strategy is characterized by w (p 1 ). A symmetric equilibrium for this model is then given as follows. Definition 2. A symmetric perfect Bayesian equilibrium in continuous strategies of the search model with asymmetric information about cost is a continuous pricing strategy p (c) with reach P and a reservation utility w (p) such that 1. for every cost realization c, each firm i chooses p i (c) = p (c) to maximize its expected profit given the pricing strategy p (c) of the other firm and consumers reservation utility w (p); 2. Consumers follow an optimal search rule given their beliefs and the match value v i and the price p i they observe at firm i; 3. Consumers beliefs are updated using Bayes Rule when possible, i.e., whenever they observe p 1 P at their first search, they believe that the other firm has also set a price p e 2 = p 1. Out-of-equilibrium beliefs p e 2 of the price set by the firm that is not yet visited are symmetric, i.e., p e 2 = p 1 if p 1 / P. Note that in the asymmetric information model, for any equilibrium price p i P, consumers have to have beliefs that satisfy p e j = p i. The reason is simple: if equilibrium is symmetric, and consumers observe one (or possible many) equilibrium prices, they have no other choice but to believe that the firm they visited first has chosen a price according to the equilibrium strategy, update their beliefs about cost and thus believe the other firm has the same cost and charges the same price. Again, there are in principle no restrictions on beliefs after observing out-of-equilibrium prices. The problem with passive beliefs is, however, that it is typically not clear what passive beliefs mean in this context. In equilibrium, all prices in P may be observed and if another price is observed upon the first search, then passive beliefs are only meaningful in a pooling equilibrium where P is a singleton. We therefore assume that out-of-equilibrium beliefs are similar to equilibrium beliefs and are symmetric: p e j = p i. In the model where retailers cost are set by an upstream firm and the decision of this upstream firm is not observed by the consumer, a symmetric equilibrium is defined in a similar way. Of course, the equilibrium for this setting has to introduce the manufacturer as a separate player. In addition, we can have both passive and symmetric out-of-equilibrium beliefs as 8

9 consumers may either blame the retailer that was visited for having deviated (assuming the wholesale price is at its equilibrium level) resulting in passive beliefs, or they may blame the manufacturer (assuming the retailers choose their equilibrium strategies and simply react to a change in the wholesale price) resulting in symmetric beliefs. Definition 3. A symmetric perfect Bayesian equilibrium of the search model with vertical relations is a wholesale price c, a retail pricing strategy p (c) and a reservation utility w (p 1 ) such that 1. the manufacturer chooses c so as to maximize its profit given the pricing strategy p (c) of the retailers and consumers reservation utility w (p 1 ); 2. each retailer i chooses p i (c) = p (c) to maximize its expected profit given the pricing strategy p (c) of the other retailer and consumers reservation utility w (p 1 ); 3. Consumers follow an optimal search rule given their beliefs and the match value v i and the price p i they observe at firm i; 4. Consumers beliefs are updated using Bayes Rule when possible, i.e., whenever they observe p 1 = p (c ) at their first search, they believe that the other firm has also set a price p e 2 = p (c ). Out-of-equilibrium beliefs p e 2 of the price set by the firm that is not yet visited are either i. (passive beliefs) such that p e 2 = p (c ) if p 1 p (c ), or ii. (symmetric beliefs) such that p e 2 = p 1 if p 1 p (c ). When, as in the benchmark vertical relations model, the consumer observes the common retailer s cost, the consumer search strategy can depend on this cost and the expected utility of searching another firm and is denoted by w (p, c). Other aspects of the equilibrium definition remain the same. 3 The Wolinsky Model The reference point for the environments we consider in this paper is the Wolinsky model where two retailers have the same cost c. In this section, we reconsider the Wolinsky model, show how under passive beliefs the market size effect comes about and then analyze the implications of symmetric beliefs. In order to find the symmetric equilibrium price p for the Wolinsky model under passive beliefs, we use (1) and adopt it to the Wolinsky model. In particular, we then have that firm 2 charges the equilibrium price, and consumers who visit firm 1 or firm 2 first also expect the other firm to charge the equilibrium price no matter what the price is that the consumer observes, so p 2 = p e 2 = pe 1 = p. When the equilibrium price satisfies w p, expected demand for firm 1 then simplifies to: Q 1 = (1 G(w p + p 1 ))(1 + G(w )) w p +p 1 p 1 G(p p 1 + v)g(v) dv.

10 The first order condition for firm 1 s profit maximization, along with the equilibrium condition p 1 = p gives then the following price setting rule for both retailers: p 1 G(p ) 2 (c) = c + 2 w p g(v) 2 dv + 2G(p )g(p ) + (1 G(w ))g(w ). (2) where we note that p is an increasing function of c. Anderson and Renault (1999) show that the equilibrium price is increasing in search cost s. For large enough s, however, p > w and no consumer will choose to search beyond the first firm. Each firm is then a single-good monopolist that faces demand 1 G(p). It is easy to see that the resulting profit (p c)(1 G(p)) is maximized at the price p m that solves p m (c) = c + 1 G(pm ) g(p m. (3) ) The threshold search cost level s is such that w = p m at which point (3) and (2) coincide. Formally, s solves v p m (v p m )g(v) dv = s. (4) So for s s, the equilibrium price solves (2), for s > s the equilibrium price equals the monopoly price p m (c). Figure 1 shows that the equilibrium price is continuous in search cost s and strictly increasing for small s and constant for s > s. Note that after s crosses the threshold value s equilibrium demand decreases discretely. For s > s, consumers only buy when their match value at the first firm is large enough so that the market size equals 1 G(p m ). For smaller s, consumers will search on and total demand equals (1 G(p)) (1 + G(p)). As equilibrium price is continuous in search cost, the market size (and thus firms profits) in equilibrium is discontinuous at s = s. Figure 1 also displays this discontinuous jump in market size. s **** *** INSERT FIGURE 1 HERE: Wolinsky passive beliefs prices and demand as function of On may wonder why retailers cannot prevent the market size from decreasing discretely by abstaining from increasing their prices above w ( s) (the reservation utility corresponding to s)? The answer is the following. Once s > s, even though both firms would prefer to collectively charge p 1 = p 2 = w (s), individually they have an incentive to increase their price to a level above w (s). This happens because once consumers believe prices do not exceed w they search, and thus firms have the incentive to increase prices to the levels given by 2, but at such prices consumers should not search, and thus in equilibrium both firms charge p m (c) and no consumer searches for s > s. Note that this explanation for the discrete fall in equilibrium market demand is related to the Diamond paradox (Diamond, 1971), but as the first search is costless the market does not break down here. As is known in the search literature (see, e.g., Wolinsky (1986)), note also that when the first search is costly, instead of having a discrete fall in market size, the market would break down completely for high search cost. The reason is that when consumers expect prices to be larger than their reservation utilities, they will not search in the first place if the first search is costly. 10

11 Symmetric Beliefs In the previous sections we have argued that consumers could also have symmetric out-ofequilibrium beliefs, i.e., if consumers that have visited firm 1 observe it has deviated to p 1 p they expect firm 2 has deviated to the same price. We now proceed to constructing a symmetric equilibrium p(c) under symmetric beliefs, where to make the transition to the next section easier we already take into account that the equilibrium price may depend on cost (which is here known to consumers). For low enough s, so that p(c) < w, expected demand for firm 1 which charges p 1, while firm 2 charges the equilibrium price p(c) and all consumers expect the firm they have not visited first to charge the price they observed at the firm they just visited is given by: + w Q 1 (p 1 )G(w p(c) + p 1 ) + w p(c)+p 1 p 1 G( p(c) p 1 + v)g(v)dv p 1 G( p(c) p 1 + v)g(v)dv. (5) The first-order condition for profit maximization given the demand in (5), is then given by 1 G( p(c)) 2 p(c) = c + 2 w p g(v) 2 dv + 2G( p(c))g( p(c)). (6) Recall that (6) is derived under the assumption that p(c) < w. As w is decreasing in s, for large enough s we will have p(c) = w and p(c) = w = c + 1 G( p(c))2 2g( p(c))g( p(c)). (7) It is not difficult to see that this price actually is the profit-maximizing price for a monopolist selling both products. Such a monopolist would set p 1 = p 2 = p (NEEDS TO BE PROVEN) and maximize (1 G(p) 2 )(p c), which is maximized at p jm that solves p jm (c) = c + 1 G(pjm ) 2 2g(p jm )G(p jm ). (8) This price is always higher than the single-product monopoly price p m because the joint profit maximization takes into account that some consumers who do not buy product 1 will buy product 2. Thus for some value of the search cost, the two firms set prices that are higher than the single-good monopoly price and as high as the price of a multi-good monopolist! So the largest search cost at which our solution in (6) still holds is where w (s) = p jm. Denote by s the search cost that solves v p jm (v p jm )g(v) dv = s. (9) Then for s s, the equilibrium price is given by (6). As p jm > p m, it is clear that s < s. What about equilibrium prices for s > s? First, note that in this case w < p(c). This means that whatever the symmetric equilibrium price, it cannot be smaller than w because in 11

12 that case each firm wants to deviate to a larger price (as the symmetric equilibrium price is still given by p(c)), so they will at least charge w if consumers still search. Can it be the case that firms charge equilibrium prices above w? In this case consumers do not search and firm 1 s demand is the monopoly demand 1 G(p). For this demand profit is maximized at p m. Now depending on whether w is above or below p m we will have two cases. First, consider w p m, which happens when s < s < s. In this case firms will never want to charge any price above w, because they have an incentive to charge at most w. So the only possible candidate for equilibrium is p 1 = p 2 = w. We know that deviations to higher prices, where the profit function equals the monopoly profit function, are not profitable. Deviations to lower prices require to look at the quantity sold by the deviating firm. This quantity is given by (5) since both prices are at most w. In this case we know that profit is increasing in p 1 because the symmetric solution to the FOC is p that is larger than w. Thus, in this case p(c) = w and as w is decreasing in s, we have that the equilibrium price is decreasing in search cost. Now consider the case where w < p m, which happens when s > s. Here, for the same reasons as explained in the Wolinsky model, even though firms suffer from a discrete drop in demand, they cannot stop themselves from deviating upwards to prices larger than w when consumers do search, and thus consumers stop searching and the equilibrium price becomes p m. Thus we have the following proposition. Proposition 1. Under symmetric beliefs, the Wolinsky model has a unique equilibrium where the retailers price p(c) is implicitly given by (6) for s < s, is equal to w for s s s, and is equal to p m (c) for s < s. Figure 2 illustrates for a given c how the equilibrium price varies with search cost in the Wolinsky model under symmetric beliefs. For small search cost prices first rise, until the joint monopoly price, and then fall in s until price equals the monopoly price, and price is then constant for even larger values of s. Note that the non-monotonicity of the equilibrium price in search cost, does not depend on whether or not the first search is costly. With costly first visits, the monopoly pricing part of the Figure would disappear as the market breaks down (as before), but the part of the equilibrium construction where s < s < s would not be affected as expecting these prices, consumers would still consider making a first search, and given that consumers search, firms do not have an incentive to charge higher prices. 4 Asymmetric Information about common cost In this Section we study an environment where firms have a common cost that is known to the firms, but unknown (and uncertain) to consumers. The effect of common cost uncertainty has been studied in the context of the Stahl (1989) model (see, e.g., Dana (1994), Tappata (2009) and Janssen et al. (2011)), but has not been incorporated in the Wolinsky model. The timing of the model and the equilibrium concept we use has been described in Section 2. As explained in that section, a symmetric equilibrium p (c) is such that if consumers observe a price p on the equilibrium path, then they have to update their beliefs about cost in such a way that they 12

13 p w p jm (c) p(c) p m (c) p (c) p d (c) s s s Figure 1: Equilibrium prices in Wolinsky (red) and random cost (blue) models for equal c. Dashed line depicts w while p d is the oligopoly price when consumers know both prices and their valuations for both products. believe that the other firm charges the same price p. Thus, along the equilibrium path, the equilibrium notion requires that consumers have symmetric beliefs. As explained in Section 2, we will restrict ourselves to out-of-equilibrium beliefs that are also symmetric. To characterize the possible equilibria in this game, we first show how the equilibrium price p(c) in the Wolinsky model with symmetric beliefs (but without asymmetric information about cost) varies with c. Subsequently, we characterize the equilibrium of the asymmetric information model. Let p(c) and p m (c) be given as in (6), respectively (3). It is clear that p(c) and p m (c) are increasing without bound. Thus, for any given s, there exist c and c such that p( c) = w (s) and p m ( c) = w (s). Moreover, as for any given c it is the case that p(c) = w (s) when p(c) = p jm (c) > p m (c), it follows that c < c. Figure 3 then summarizes the dependence of the equilibrium price of the Wolinsky model with symmetric beliefs on c. For c < c, the equilibrium price is given by p(c) which is increasing in c. For c < c < c, the equilibrium price is equal to w (s), which does not depend on c. Finally, for c > c the equilibrium price is given by p m (c) which is again increasing in c. *** INSERT FIGURE EQUILIBRIUM PRICE DEPENDENCE ON C ******* As these prices are derived under the condition of symmetric beliefs and the equilibrium of the asymmetric information model is defined under symmetric beliefs, the next proposition characterizing the equilibrium of the asymmetric information model immediately follows: Proposition 2. For any given s, let c and c be defined as above. Then, depending on the range of cost uncertainty [c, c] the equilibrium of the asymmetric information model takes one of the following forms: a. If, c < c the equilibrium is fully separating and the equilibrium prices are given by (6). 13

14 b. If, c < c < c, then the equilibrium is partially separating with equilibrium prices being given by (6) for c < c, while for c > c c the equilibrium price is independent of c and equal to w (s); If, in addition c > c, then for cost levels c > c, the equilibrium price is given by (3). c. If, c < c < c < c, then the equilibrium is pooling with equilibrium prices being given by w (s); d. If, c < c < c, then the equilibrium is partially separating with equilibrium prices being equal to w (s) for c < c < c, while for c < c the equilibrium price is given by (3); If, in addition c < c, then for cost levels c < c, the equilibrium price is given by (6). e. If, c > c the equilibrium is fully separating and the equilibrium prices are given by (3) The equilibrium nature can be fully understood by looking at Figure 3 As that figure has increasing and flat parts, the equilibrium can be partially or fully separating and also pooling depending on how cost uncertainty interacts with the search cost s. For instance, if the exogenous cost uncertainty is small, the equilibrium is likely to be fully separating or fully pooling, whereas if the range of cost uncertainty becomes larger, it will be partially separating. 4 It is interesting to relate some aspects of this equilibrium characterization to the two independent literatures: (i) the literature on sticky prices and (ii) the literature explaining sales. There is a large literature trying to explain why firms do not adjust their prices to variations in their cost. SHOULD WE SAY MORE ON THIS: IF SO; ALSO IN ABSTRACT; INTRO (AND I ALREADY DID CONCLUSION). Following the seminal article by Varian (1980), the literature on sales provides an explanation for the common observation that retailers often follow a pricing strategy for their products that is characterized by a regular price most of the time and a sales price at random moments in time, where the discount given on the regular price is also subject to large variations (see, also, e.g., Narasimhan (1988)). This literature explains this phenomenon by an asymmetric mixed strategy equilibrium with a mass point for the regular price and a continuous price distribution for the sales prices. From the viewpoint of the consumers (or the empirical economist who does not have data on cost, but only on retail prices) the equilibrium under b) in the Proposition can also be characterized as an equilibrium with sales. For many cost levels, firms (regular) price is independent of cost, but when cost becomes low enough, the retailers give a discount. When cost is unobserved by the empirical economist, the firm acts as if it is giving a random price promotion, but in fact (in our model) this sales arise as the realization of a pure strategy that is symmetric across firms. WE SHOULD BE CAREFUL HERE. IN OUR MODEL ALL FIRMS REDUCE PRICES, SO THAT AN ECONOMETRICIAN CAN OBSERVE (AND THEY RARELY TO I THINK). BUT, IT LOOKS LIKE A PERIODIC PRICE WAR, AND THERE S SOME DYNAMIC COL- LUSION LITERATURE ON THAT. Empirically, Pesendorfer (2002) finds evidence for the fact that a firm has a regular price and then provides discounts at irregular points in time. Note, however, that in line with d) in 4 If the first search would not be for free, then the equilibrium characterization would be similar. the only difference would be that at cost levels c > c, the market would break down. 14

15 our Proposition, a firm my also have a regular price with irregular price movements going up and down. This is a pricing pattern that is found in Hosken and Reiffen (2004). 5 Vertical Industry Structure We now turn to the environment where retailers cost is determined by an upstream firm and consider how consumer beliefs and the market size effect influence the pricing decisions of the upstream firm. We also consider the impact on upstream and downstream profits. we start with a relatively straightforward adaptation of the Wolinsky model as our benchmark analysis for the vertical industry structure. In the benchmark, we have an upstream firm choosing the wholesale price, retailers and consumers observing this wholesale price and consumers having passive beliefs when searching. the benchmark model thus simply adds an upstream layer to the standard Wolinsky model. The market size effect already plays an important role in the benchmark model. We then consider a model where consumers do not observe the wholesale arrangement between manufacturer and retailers and have symmetric beliefs, i.e., if they observe a retail price that is different from the one they had anticipated in equilibrium, they think that it is the manufacturer that has deviated so that the second retail firm they have not yet visited will charge the same price as the price they have observed at their first search. 5.1 The benchmark vertical model For any c that the upstream firm may charge, we know from Section 3 what happens downstream. This is because when consumers observed the choice of the upstream firm and have passive beliefs, any deviation from the retail price consumers expect to see in equilibrium is interpreted as a unilateral deviation by that retailer. Thus, for search cost and upstream price such that s < s(c) we have that prices are given by (2), while for larger search cost the downstream price is p m (c). Given this behavior downstream, we consider the manufacturer s optimal choice. One important consideration is that (downstream and upstream) demand is discontinuous at a critical level of search cost, which we have denoted in Section 3 by s. Note, however, that as s is determined by p m (c) this critical level of search cost depends on c. In Section 3, we have not made that dependance explicit as c was exogeneously given. As the manufacturer chooses the retail production cost c we now make that dependance explicit and write s(c). It is clear from definition (4) that s(c) is declining in c. Thus, for a given s if the manufacturer chooses c low enough, s < s(c), (upstream) demand is given by 1 G(p) 2, while for higher c demand falls. If the first search is for free demand falls to to 1 G(p) as consumers stop searching beyond the first retailer. If the first search is costly demand drops to 0 as consumers do not visit any firm. As the manufacturer chooses c, it has an incentive to accommodate larger search cost by reducing its price to prevent the fall in demand due to downstream prices becoming larger than w. To solve the model, let us start with the case where s is relatively small, so the above consideration does not apply. Then both retailers react to a choice of c by setting p (c) as in the Wolinsky model with passive beliefs. The manufacturer s demand consists of the demand at both 15

16 retailers, and consumers buy at one of the two retail firms if, and only if, max(v 1, v 2 ) > p (c), and thus buy with probability 1 G(p (c)) 2. The upstream firm maximizes (1 G(p (c)) 2 )c, and the optimal wholesale price (retail cost) c o when consumers observe this price is given by: c o = 1 G(p ) 2 1 2G(p )g(p ) p c. (10) The derivative p c (co ) can be derived from (2). This price remains the optimal price for any s where w is not binding and the resulting p (c o ) is smaller than w. Next, we consider such search cost s that for the upstream price that solves (10) we have p (c o ) > w. In this case consumer would not search, and thus the optimal price does not equal (10). In fact, downstream firms would revert to pricing at the monopoly price (corresponding to c) and upstream profits would suffer a discrete decline because consumers search less and buy less. This means that the optimal upstream price has to be such that p m (c) = w. In this case consumers (just barely) prefer to search, and downstream firms charge p = w. Since as s increases, w falls, this accommodation of downstream search by the upstream firm cannot continue forever. At some search cost, if the first search is for free it will become profitable to let consumers stop searching, and charge the optimal price given that downstream firms charge a monopoly price for that c. From that moment on the equilibrium characterization is independent of s and we are in the world on classical double marginalisation prices. Formally, let us define s o as the search cost such that at the wholesale price c o that solves (10) we have p (c o, s o ) = w (s o ). Note that as the Wolinsky price is increasing in search cost and the reservation utility is decreasing in search cost, s o is uniquely defined. Also, let c m denote the upstream price that maximizes (1 G(p m (c)))c. It follows that c m is given by c m = 1 G(pm (c m )). g(p m (c m )) pm c This is the wholesale price that would be set in the classic double marginalisation problem. Finally, let s o denote the search cost such that (1 G(w ( s o )) 2 )c = (1 G(p m (c m )))c m where c is such that downstream firms charge w. Charging such a c or charging c m is equally profitable at s o. Now we can formally describe the equilibrium characterization. Proposition 3. In case consumers observe the price set by the upstream firm, the equilibrium is given by: (i) upstream price is given by (10) and downstream prices are equal to p (c) if s < s o ; (ii) upstream price solves p m (c) = w and downstream prices are equal to w for s o s s o ; (iii) upstream price is c m and downstream prices are p m (c m ) for s > s o. SHOULD WE FORMALLY PROVE IN AN APPENDIX THAT s o s o AND THAT c m > 16

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia February 15, 2014 Abstract We analyze two unexplored aspects of the Wolinsky model (Wolinsky (1986)

More information

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA WORKING PAPERS Beliefs and Consumer Search Maarten Janssen Sandro Shelegia January 2015 Working Paper No: 1501 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA All our working papers are available at: http://mailbox.univie.ac.at/papers.econ

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Consumer Search with Price Sorting

Consumer Search with Price Sorting Consumer Search with Price Sorting Jun Yu September 29, 2013 Abstract This paper introduces price sorting into a consumer search model. Either ascending or descending price sorting can be applied before

More information

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers Filip Matějka and Alisdair McKay January 16, 2012 Prepared for American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings Abstract We study a market

More information

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing TI 2004-068/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing Maarten C.W. Janssen José Luis Moraga-González* Matthijs R. Wildenbeest Faculty of Economics,

More information

Search and Categorization

Search and Categorization MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Search and Categorization Chaim Fershtman and Arthur Fishman and Jidong Zhou Tel Aviv University, Bar-Ilan University, NYU Stern December 03 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5366/

More information

Consumers search. Industrial Organization. Bernard Caillaud. October 20, Master APE - Paris School of Economics

Consumers search. Industrial Organization. Bernard Caillaud. October 20, Master APE - Paris School of Economics Industrial Organization Master APE - Paris School of Economics October 20, 2016 Consumers inertia as a source of market power We have seen how firms market power rests on differentiation, real or perceived,

More information

Multiproduct Pricing in Oligopoly

Multiproduct Pricing in Oligopoly Multiproduct Pricing in Oligopoly Sandro Shelegia Department of Economics and Business Universitat Pompeu Fabra November 29, 2008. JOB MARKET PAPER Abstract This paper proposes a two-good model of price

More information

Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly.

Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly. Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly. Maarten C.W. Janssen University of Vienna, Austria and Tinbergen Institute Rotterdam, The Netherlands. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas,

More information

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement Hideo Konishi Michael T. Sandfort June 21, 2001 Abstract Retail stores frequently advertise prices. When consumer search is costly, advertising low prices expands

More information

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming Market mechanisms and stochastic programming Kjetil K. Haugen and Stein W. Wallace Molde University College, Servicebox 8, N-6405 Molde, Norway E-mail: Kjetil.Haugen/Stein.W.Wallace@himolde.no 18.12.01

More information

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. October 13, 2011 Abstract In a durable good market where sellers have private

More information

Damaged Durable Goods: Mitigating the Time Inconsistency Problem

Damaged Durable Goods: Mitigating the Time Inconsistency Problem JEL Codes: D0, L0 1. Introduction World Review of Business Research Vol. 2. No. 6. November 2012. Pp. 84 99 Damaged Durable Goods: Mitigating the Time Inconsistency Problem Xiaojing (Joanne) MA * In this

More information

WP OCTOBER Pricing Interrelated Goods in Oligopoly. Sandro Shelegia

WP OCTOBER Pricing Interrelated Goods in Oligopoly. Sandro Shelegia ISET WORKING PAPER SERIES WP 014 08 OCTOBER 2008 Pricing Interrelated Goods in Oligopoly Sandro Shelegia The International School of Economics at Tbilisi State University (ISET) is supported by BP, the

More information

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Problem 1. Shorter problems. (35 points) Solve the following shorter problems. 1. Consider the following (simultaneous) game of chicken. This is a game in

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES ISSN 1471-0498 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Ordered Consumer Search Mark Armstrong Number 804 September, 2016 Manor Road Building, Oxford OX1 3UQ Ordered Consumer Search Mark Armstrong

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* Abstract Many software and video game firms offer a free demo with limited content to help buyers better assess the likely value

More information

Bundling and Quality Disclosure in a Bayesian Game

Bundling and Quality Disclosure in a Bayesian Game Journal of Game Theory 2015, 4(1): 13-17 DO: 10.5923/j.jgt.20150401.03 undling and Quality Disclosure in a ayesian Game Qing Hu Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University, Kobe, Japan Abstract We analyze

More information

1. INTRODUCTION IS IT POSSIBLE TO MOVE THE COPPER MARKET? MATTI LISKI AND JUAN-PABLO MONTERO *

1. INTRODUCTION IS IT POSSIBLE TO MOVE THE COPPER MARKET? MATTI LISKI AND JUAN-PABLO MONTERO * Cuadernos de Economía, Año 40, Nº 121, pp. 559-565 (diciembre 2003) IS IT POSSIBLE TO MOVE THE COPPER MARKET? MATTI LISKI AND JUAN-PABLO MONTERO * 1. INTRODUCTION In recent years, the question whether

More information

Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly. Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis

Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly. Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Competitor Based Price Clauses Competitor Based Price Clauses: any price guarantee

More information

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power May 19, 2012 Eric B. Rasmusen Dan R. and Catherine M. Dalton Professor, Department of Business Economics and Public Policy, Kelley

More information

Competition, Disclosure and Signaling.

Competition, Disclosure and Signaling. Competition, Disclosure and Signaling. Maarten C.W. Janssen University of Vienna, Austria. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. December 6, 2012 Abstract Competition creates strategic

More information

Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs

Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs Quyen Nguyen University of Arizona November 14, 2015 Abstract Access to product information changes a consumer s initial belief about the product s

More information

Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3

Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3 Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3 This is intended as a supplement to the lectures and section. It is what I would talk about in section if we had more time. After the first three chapters where we talked

More information

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1 The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1 Barna Bakó 2 Corvinus University of Budapest Hungary 1 I would like to thank the anonymous referee for the valuable comments and suggestions,

More information

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects Peter M. Kort, Pauli Murto, and Grzegorz Pawlina April 25, 2005 Preliminary and incomplete. Please do not quote. Abstract This paper is about

More information

Price setting in a differentiated-product duopoly with asymmetric information. about demand * Miguel Ángel Ropero García

Price setting in a differentiated-product duopoly with asymmetric information. about demand * Miguel Ángel Ropero García Price setting in a differentiated-product duopoly with asymmetric information about demand * Miguel Ángel Ropero García Department of Applied Economics University of Malaga El Ejido 6, 29071 Malaga Spain

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* University of Florida Department of Economics, P.O.Box 117140 Gainesville, FL 32611-7140 Email: lifan51@ufl.edu Tel:1-352-846-5475

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003 School of Economics, Mathematics and Statistics INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003 1. Strategic Interaction and Oligopoly

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO.

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. 2008-14 ASYMMETRIC MARKET SHARES, ADVERTISING, AND PRICING: EQUILIBRIUM

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct. UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures 13-14 Oct. 1, 2011 Pricing While there is some involved analysis required,

More information

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

9 The optimum of Oligopoly Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, December 1, 2008 9 The optimum of Oligopoly During previous lectures we have investigated two important forms of market structure: pure competition, where there are typically

More information

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power Ross Baldick Copyright c 2009 Ross Baldick Title Page 1 of 54 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit 1 Background This review of background

More information

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Econ 11b: Intermediate Microeconomics Dirk Bergemann, Spring 01 Week of 3/6-4/3 1 Lecture 16: Imperfectly Competitive Market 1.1 Price Discrimination In the previous section we saw that the monopolist

More information

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 27, 2006 Answer four of the six

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

Web Appendix. Oligopolistic Markets with Sequential Search and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Retail Gasoline Markets

Web Appendix. Oligopolistic Markets with Sequential Search and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Retail Gasoline Markets Web Appendix Oligopolistic Markets with Sequential Search and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Retail Gasoline Markets Maarten Janssen Paul Pichler Simon Weidenholzer 28th July 2010 Department of

More information

Comparative Price Signaling by a Multiproduct Firm

Comparative Price Signaling by a Multiproduct Firm Comparative Price Signaling by a Multiproduct Firm Michael R. Baye and Rick Harbaugh May, 013 Abstract Existing work on price signaling finds that, in the absence of reputational or other effects, a firm

More information

Key words: Franchise Fees, Competition, Double Marginalization, Collusion

Key words: Franchise Fees, Competition, Double Marginalization, Collusion The Role of Franchise Fees and Manufacturers Collusion DongJoon Lee (Nagoya University of Commerce and Business, Japan) Sanghoen Han (Nagoya University of Commerce and Business, Japan) Abstract: This paper

More information

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki Department of Economics, University of Crete, Gallos University Campus, Rethymnon 74100, Greece

More information

Price ceilings and quality competition. Abstract

Price ceilings and quality competition. Abstract Price ceilings and quality competition Alexander Kemnitz University of Mannheim Cyrus Hemmasi University of Mannheim Abstract This paper investigates the quality implications of an upper limit on product

More information

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012.

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012. 1 A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET April 2012 Bralind Kiri bralind.kiri@gmail.com PhD Student, Department of Economic Theory and

More information

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments Chapter 8: Exchange 8.1: Introduction In many ways this chapter is the most important in the book. If you have time to study just one, this is the one that you should study (even though it might be a bit

More information

Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality

Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality Information Economics (Ec 515) George Georgiadis Consider a firm that sells an experience good. Experience good: product or service

More information

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition Strategic Competition: An overview The economics of industry studying activities within an industry. Basic concepts from game theory Competition in the short run Best-response functions, best-response

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities

Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities Daniel CERQUERA March 15, 2005 Abstract We present a model of R&D competition between an incumbent and a potential entrant with network externalities

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 01

More information

Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty

Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty Yu-Hung Chen and Baojun Jiang January 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model to examine how a firm with a new, non-durable

More information

Part II. Market power

Part II. Market power Part II. Market power Chapter 3. Static imperfect competition Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2009 Introduction to Part

More information

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract Information externalities in a model of sales John Morgan Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University Martin Sefton School of Economics, University of Nottingham Abstract We anlayze Varian's (1980) Model

More information

Christopher S. Ruebeck 1

Christopher S. Ruebeck 1 Exploring the space of demand curves and consumer rationing rules Christopher S. Ruebeck 1 Lafayette College Department of Economics Easton PA 18042 ruebeckc@lafayette.edu Prepared for participants in

More information

Retail Discrimination in Search Markets

Retail Discrimination in Search Markets Retail Discrimination in Search Markets Maarten Janssen and Edona Reshidi Friday 24 th August, 2018 Abstract This paper analyses the incentives of manufacturers to discriminate between ex ante symmetric

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman Working Paper 11407 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11407 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Comparative Advantage Under Monopoly: A Note On the Role of Market Power

Comparative Advantage Under Monopoly: A Note On the Role of Market Power Comparative Advantage Under Monopoly: A Note On the Role of Market Power Emanuele Bacchiega Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 74 Comparative Advantage Under Monopoly: A Note On the Role of Market Power Emanuele

More information

Regulation and Competition with Captive Customers. John Vickers

Regulation and Competition with Captive Customers. John Vickers Regulation and Competition with Captive Customers John Vickers Zeeman Lecture RPI Annual Conference Oxford, 24 September 2018 Vickers 24 September 2018 Zeeman Lecture UK Regulatory Policy Issues Privatization

More information

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account Index: 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account... 8. Introduction... 8. The deterministic case...3 8.3 Optimal consumption under uncertainty...4

More information

Horizontal Mergers With One Capacity Constrained Firm Increase Prices?

Horizontal Mergers With One Capacity Constrained Firm Increase Prices? From the SelectedWorks of David J. Balan November, 2017 Horizontal Mergers With One Capacity Constrained Firm Increase Prices? David J. Balan Patrick DeGraba Jason O'Connor Available at: https://works.bepress.com/david_balan/14/

More information

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island Market Structure ECON6021 Oligopoly Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island Oligopoly a few major players The top 4 cereal manufacturers sell 90% of all

More information

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009 Outline Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization Session 2 K. Graddy The Coase Conjecture and Price Skimming Sales Non linear pricing Two part tariffs and the Disneyland monopolist Geographical

More information

Consumer Search and Asymmetric Retail Channels

Consumer Search and Asymmetric Retail Channels Consumer Search and Asymmetric Retail Channels Daniel Garcia Maarten Janssen March 15, 2016 Abstract We study vertical relations in markets with a monopoly manufacturer and consumer search. The monopoly

More information

Harvard University Department of Economics

Harvard University Department of Economics Harvard University Department of Economics General Examination in Microeconomic Theory Spring 00. You have FOUR hours. Part A: 55 minutes Part B: 55 minutes Part C: 60 minutes Part D: 70 minutes. Answer

More information

ECON 4550 (Summer 2014) Exam 3

ECON 4550 (Summer 2014) Exam 3 ECON 4550 (Summer 014) Exam 3 Name Multiple Choice Questions: (4 points each) 1. Bob owns a food truck. He offers senior citizens a 10% discount. This behavior by Bob is an example of A. First Degree Price

More information

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Department of Applied Economics Faculty of Economics University of

More information

Ryan Oprea. Economics 176

Ryan Oprea. Economics 176 1. s and Ryan Oprea University of California, Santa Barbara Induced Supply and Demand One of the most important tools in experimental economics is the ability to induce preferences. Induced Supply and

More information

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden http://io.tholden.org/ Game theory refresher 2 Sequential games Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibria More static oligopoly: Entry Welfare Cournot versus Bertrand

More information

Product Quality, Reputation, and Market Structure

Product Quality, Reputation, and Market Structure Northwestern University From the SelectedWorks of Yuk-Fai Fong 2008 Product Quality, Reputation, and Market Structure James D Dana Yuk-Fai Fong, Northwestern University Available at: https://works.bepress.com/yuk_fai_fong/9/

More information

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of 137 Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of BMW 1,3,5,7. Hyperlink Harald Schmidt Show: rtsp://streamer2.streaming.szm.de/sat1/schmidt/media//03/03/20/procter_56.rm

More information

Competition With Captive Customers

Competition With Captive Customers Competition With Captive Customers Mark Armstrong & John Vickers CRESSE: July 2018 Armstrong & Vickers () Captive Customers CRESSE: July 2018 1 / 19 Introduction Captive customers can only buy from a particular

More information

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand WP-2009-001 Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand Rupayan Pal Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai January 2009 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2009-001.pdf

More information

PRICE SETTING IN A DIFFERENTIATED-PRODUCT DUOPOLY WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION ABOUT DEMAND BY MIGUEL ÁNGEL ROPERO 1

PRICE SETTING IN A DIFFERENTIATED-PRODUCT DUOPOLY WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION ABOUT DEMAND BY MIGUEL ÁNGEL ROPERO 1 PRICE SETTING IN A DIFFERENTIATED-PRODUCT DUOPOLY WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION ABOUT DEMAND BY MIGUEL ÁNGEL ROPERO 1 Department of Applied Economics, University of Malaga, Spain. ABSTRACT This paper explores

More information

Consumer Search with Observational Learning

Consumer Search with Observational Learning Consumer Search with Observational Learning Daniel Garcia Sandro Shelegia December 1, 2014 Abstract This paper studies social learning in a search environment. New consumers observe previous consumers

More information

Two Lectures on Information Design

Two Lectures on Information Design Two Lectures on nformation Design 10th DSE Winter School Stephen Morris December 2015 nformation Design Usually in information economics, we ask what can happen for a xed information structure... nformation

More information

Collusion with secret price cuts: an experimental investigation. Abstract

Collusion with secret price cuts: an experimental investigation. Abstract Collusion with secret price cuts: an experimental investigation Robert Feinberg American University Christopher Snyder George Washington University Abstract Theoretical work starting with Stigler (1964)

More information

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist Economics 335 March 3, 999 Notes 8: Models of Spatial Competition I. Product differentiation A. Definition Products are said to be differentiated if consumers consider them to be imperfect substitutes.

More information

5 Market Games For Teaching Economics

5 Market Games For Teaching Economics 5 Market Games For Teaching Economics Progression 5 Market Games from website economics-games.com To be played separately or as a sequence: Market Game 1: Sunk costs, monopoly, and introduction to the

More information

Vertical Mergers. The retailer has marginal cost of Pu+lOO where PU is the price per unit charged by the upstream manufacturer Grapefruit.

Vertical Mergers. The retailer has marginal cost of Pu+lOO where PU is the price per unit charged by the upstream manufacturer Grapefruit. Vertical Mergers Suppose that Grapefruit Computers makes a unique product that is distributed exclusively by the retailer Better Buy. Both firms act as monopolists to maximize their profits. Consumers

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2600 5 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 944 JULY 2005 SNOBS AND QUALITY GAPS by Suren Basov Department of Economics The University of

More information

REGIONAL RESTRICTION, STRATEGIC DELEGATION, AND WELFARE

REGIONAL RESTRICTION, STRATEGIC DELEGATION, AND WELFARE Discussion Paper No. 761 REGIONAL RESTRICTION, STRATEGIC DELEGATION, AND WELFARE Toshihiro Matsumura Noriaki Matsushima November 2009 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka University 6-1

More information

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes): Lesson-28 Perfect Competition Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes): Perfect Competition Monopoly Oligopoly Monopolistic competition Market

More information

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Hongru Tan and Julian Wright March, 2018 Abstract We show that in the context of pricing by a multi-sided platform, in addition to the classical market-power

More information

FDI as a signal of quality *

FDI as a signal of quality * FDI as a signal of quality * Seiichi Katayama * and Kaz Miyagiwa ** Abstract: This paper considers a new-product firm s choice between exporting and foreign direct investment (FDI) to access foreign markets.

More information

EconS Asymmetric Information

EconS Asymmetric Information cons 425 - Asymmetric Information ric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization ric Dunaway (WSU) cons 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 45 Introduction Today, we are

More information

Robust Supply Function Bidding in Electricity Markets With Renewables

Robust Supply Function Bidding in Electricity Markets With Renewables Robust Supply Function Bidding in Electricity Markets With Renewables Yuanzhang Xiao Department of EECS Email: xyz.xiao@gmail.com Chaithanya Bandi Kellogg School of Management Email: c-bandi@kellogg.northwestern.edu

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET Chapter 6 We recall that perfect competition was theorised as a market structure where both consumers and firms were price takers. The behaviour of the firm in such circumstances was described in the Chapter

More information

Vertical Networks, Integration, and Connectivity

Vertical Networks, Integration, and Connectivity Vertical Networks, Integration, and Connectivity The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Dogan, Pinar. 2009.

More information

Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited. Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand.

Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited. Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand. Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand May, 2005 Abstract Quality levels have been widely discussed in the

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Essi Eerola RUESG, University of Helsinki, Helsinki, Finland Niku Määttänen Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain and The Research Institute

More information

OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS. Golovko Sergiy

OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS. Golovko Sergiy OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS by Golovko Sergiy A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MA in Economics Kyiv School of Economics

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly Outline Barriers to Entry Profit Maximization under Monopoly Welfare Loss of Monopoly Multiplant Monopolist Price Discrimination Advertising in Monopoly

More information

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Simona Grassi Ching-to Albert Ma Max Weber Fellow Department of Economics European University Institute Boston University Villa La Fonte, Via Delle Fontanelle,

More information

Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure

Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure Maryam Khajeh Afzali, Poh Kim Leng, Jeff Obbard Abstract The issue of channel power in supply chain has recently received considerable attention in literature.

More information

Industrial Organization 04

Industrial Organization 04 Industrial Organization 04 Product differentiation Marc Bourreau Telecom ParisTech Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 04: Product differentiation 1 / 43 Outline 1 Introduction: forms of product differentiation

More information