Store Brands and Retail Grocery Competition in Breakfast Cereals

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Store Brands and Retail Grocery Competition in Breakfast Cereals"

Transcription

1 Store Brands and Retail Grocery Competition in Breakfast Cereals Rong Luo The Pennsylvania State University April 15, 2013 Abstract This paper empirically analyzes the impacts of store brands on grocery retailers and consumers in the market for breakfast cereals. On the supply side, store brands help a retailer to avoid direct competition with other retailers and change the set of retailer s products. On the demand side, introducing store brands changes the national brands prices and consumers choice set. We analyze the effects via demand estimation for a single grocery store chain Dominick s at Chicago in 1997 and counterfactual exercises. The estimation results show that consumers unobserved utility of buying at a competing retailer is higher for consumers that value national brands, and is lower for ones that value Dominick s store brands. This is consistent with the claim that store brands help a retailer to avoid competition. The counterfactual calculations show that the profit loss from removing store brands is higher if the retailer has more competitors, with a median loss of 4.33% of profits from cereals. Existence of store brands increases national brands prices and consumer welfare increases slightly when store brands are removed. Keywords: store brands, national brands, competition, nested logit model, random coefficient model The author is grateful to Mark Roberts, Paul Grieco, Peter Newberry for advising my research process and helpful suggestions. All errors are the authors own responsibility. Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA Comments are welcome. 1

2 1 Introduction This paper studies grocery retailer s profits on store brands of cereal when the degree of competition among retailers varies. Competition among retailers is direct in the sense that they sell goods produced by the same manufacturers. Introduction of store brands helps a retailer to avoid direct competition because store brands are sold exclusively by the corresponding retailer. We emphasize the following substitution pattern in this paper. For a retailer A selling both national brands and store brands of cereal, entry of competing retail stores has different effects on the demand for national brands and store brands. Given that competing retailers sell the same set of national brands, A s national brands consumers may switch to competing stores since they can buy exactly the same products there. But A s store brands consumers can t find the exact same products in competing stores. That is to say, competing retailers sell products that are better substitutes for A s national brands than A s store brands. This substitution pattern justifies a retailer s decision of introducing store brands. As more retailers enter to share the market, a retailer may use store brands to lock-in some consumers when its market share decreases with competition. As a result, we expect store brands to be more important in markets where the degree of competition is high. In this paper, we empirically analyze the relationship between a retailer s profit gain from introducing store brands and its competition with other retailers. There are several reasons why the analysis of store brands demand and the relationship between store brands profit and retailers competition is important. First, the demand side welfare effect of store brands can t be neglected. Hong and Li (2013) documents that the market share of private label grocery products (mainly store brands) is about 20% in the United States in 2012, 35% in Europe and 50% in Britain in So store brands are more and more important in retail markets. So are the welfare effects. Second, measuring the profit effect of introducing store brands is critical to retailers. Introducing store brands is a strategy for retailers to avoid competition and increase profit. So it is important to predict whether and by how much store brands will increase profits. 1 literature has not studied store brands and competition very well. So we believe it is 1 This importance is not limited to retail markets. For most multiproduct firms, measuring the profit of introducing a new product that is a substitute for existing products has significant effect on market structure. For example, companies in industries like electronics and automobile frequently introduce new products, the effects of which can be studied by similar methods as developed in this paper. The 2

3 important to pay more attention to this topic. This paper uses a structural model of demand and data on ready-to-eat cereal products to analyze store brands profit effect and its relationship with competition among retailers. In the demand side model, to allow flexible substitution patterns across products and heterogeneity in consumer choices, we use the random coefficient demand model as used by Nevo (2000). One difference between the demand model in this paper and Nevo(2000) lies in the mean utility of outside option. Since data for only one chain retailer (Dominick s) stores is available, we define the outside option as not buying from Dominick s (including buying from other retailers and not buying ready-to-eat cereal). So in order to capture the competition effect, we assume the mean utility of outside option depends linearly on number of competitors. If the coefficient is positive, then additional competitors will increase the mean utility of outside option, and lower the market share of Dominick s. The supply model here is simple. We assume that each Dominick s store chooses the optimal prices for all brands. Cohen and Cotterill (2011) justifies this assumption by comparing different pricing models of milk products and finds that retailers maximize profits taken the wholesale prices as given. Given the demand estimates, each store knows the cross- and own- price elasticities of substitution of all products and solves its profit maximization problem. Given the observed prices are in equilibrium the cost of each product can be calculated from retailer s first-order conditions. The costs will be used in counterfactual analysis. The demand estimation results imply that consumers unobserved utilities of national brands and the outside option are positively correlated, with correlation coefficient And the unobserved utilities of store brands and the outside option are negatively correlated, with correlation coefficient.44. These correlations explain the substitution patterns across national brands, store brands, and the outside option described earlier. The first counterfactual experiment calculates the effect of removing store brands. The results show that the median profit loss of removing Dominick s store brands readyto-eat cereals is $108 per store every week, which is 4.33% of profits in the ready-to-eat cereal category. When the number of competing retailers increases by 1%, the profit loss increases by 0.16%. If two Dominick s stores S1 and S2 have 100 and 101 competitors respectively, then the percentage profit loss of S2 is 0.15% higher than S1. Therefore, this counterfactual analysis implies that retailer s profit decreases from removing store 3

4 brands and the profit loss increases significantly as competition increases. In addition, the welfare of consumers increases after removing store brands. To clearly quantify the effects of competition, the second experiment assumes that each Dominick s store has 5 more competing retailers. The results show that the median profit loss is $502 per store every week, which is 20.21% of the ready-to-eat cereal profit. More importantly, Dominick s reduces prices of all brands to keep its consumers. On the consumer side, welfare increases when competition increases. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes related literature about store brands effects, demand estimation, and retailer-manufacturer relationship. In section 3, we introduce the data I used and some motivation facts on the substitution patterns across brands. The demand model and supply model are presented in section 4. Section 5 discusses the identification of parameters and estimation strategy of the demand model. The effects of two counterfactual cases, removing store brands and increasing competitors, are calculated in Section 6. The final section concludes the paper. 2 Literature There are several papers analyzing the effects of introducing store brands, but none has studied the horizontal competition effect of introducing store brands, which is also very important in addition to the vertical effects. Chintagunta, Bonfrer and Song(2002) analyzes the demand side price elasticity changes and supply side retailer-manufacturer relationships. Their test can t reject the hypothesis that there is no change in price e- lasticities after introducing store brands. On the supply side, they compare the markups before and after introducing store brands, and find that manufacturers taking a softer stand after store brands are introduced. Steiner (2004) theoretically argues that store brands are competitive weapons and consumer welfare is maximized when store brands and national brands compete vigorously. Cohen and Cotterill (2011) assesses the impact of retailer store brand products on manufacturer brand prices, profitability and consumer welfare. They calculate manufactural margins implied by different supply models between manufacturers and retailer and regress the implied costs of the models on input prices to choose the best fit supply model. They find that national brands prices are lower and consumer welfare is higher with store brands. In addition to analyzing prices and welfare effects of introducing store brands, our paper also emphasizes the relationship between 4

5 introducing store brands and competition among retailers, which hasn t been studied in the literature. Hong and Li (2013) analyzes the cost pass-though of national brands and private label products and finds that the pass-though rate of private labels is 40% higher than national brands. While we are also studying pricing of store brands, the purpose of our paper is quite different. The demand model and estimation strategy in this paper follow very popular specification in the literature, like BLP(1994), Nevo(2000), Petrin(2002), and so on. But there is one important distinction with the literature. To incorporate the effects of local competition, we allow the mean utility of outside option to depend on number of competitors. In contrast to being normalized to zero, the utility of the outside option in this paper is expected to increase with competition of retailers. If there are more retailers within a geographic area, consumers utility of not buying from Dominick s increases. So Dominick s consumers switch to the outside option as competition increases. Though including competition in the outside option utility is not an ideal way to model retailers competition, it is reasonable given we only have data for Dominick s stores and number of competing retailers. Analyzing effects of introducing store brands is also related to the vertical integration literature. Without store brands, retailers buy products from a manufacturer at wholesale prices. Theoretically, store brands eliminate the double marginalization problem of national brands, lower the national brands prices, and raise consumer welfare. However, Hastings(2004) analyzes the gasoline market in South California and finds that vertical integration significantly increases prices. The reason is that the vertical integration in her paper reduces competition among stations instead of increasing competition because large refining companies now control competing independent stations. In our paper, introducing low cost store brands makes the retailer to differentiate consumers, so the high quality national brands prices increase. Villas-Boas(2007) compares margins implied by different supply models between manufacturer and retailer to select the model most consistent with data. While comparing different supply models is important, our paper assumes reasonable pricing behavior of the retailer and focuses on relationship between vertical integrated store brands and retailer competition. 5

6 3 Data and Facts 3.1 Data and Ready-to-eat Cereal Market We analyze the ready-to-eat cereal products in Dominick s chain stores in this paper. Dominick s is a chain grocery store in Chicago area. The data used in this paper has three parts. The first part is store level weekly scanner data, which records manufacturer, price, quantity sold, markup and size of every product sold in each Dominick s store every week. This data also provides demographic characteristics for the market of each store. The second part is data on retailer competition. We find the number of food retailing stores at zip code level from 1997 U.S. Economic Census report, and number of population at zip code level from Illinois state census. The last part is the product characteristics data, which we collected manually from Mrbreakfirst s website. We consider the most important 20 brands sold in every Dominick s store. A brand here corresponds to a manufacturer-shape pair. There are four shape types: ring, flake, shredded and other. For example, all Cheerios by General Mills are combined into one brand. One reason to aggregate products in this way is to balance choice sets for consumers of different Dominick s stores. The product characteristics contain information on the grain type dummy, fruit dummy and nut dummy of each brand. Since products are combined into brands, we use weighted averages for brand characteristics. A market in this paper is defined as a store in a week. For example, the same store at two different weeks are treated as two different markets. In 1997, Dominick s has 86 stores, and almost all stores are located in areas with different zip codes. Eighteen stores are located in the downtown Chicago area, where the number of competitors and population data are the same and large for all stores. We drop observations of all stores in downtown Chicago area which leaves us data for 68 stores. To match the data of competition and population, we only use Dominick s data in 1997, which has 28 week observations for all stores. To avoid consistent prices in consecutive weeks, we only use data for the first week of each month during So the number of markets decreases to 288. To further restrict the set of products to be the same for every market, we select stores that carry all the 20 brands defined above. In the end, there are 285 markets. The outside option is defined as not buying from a Dominick s store. For each consumer in a market, the outside option includes two possibilities, buying from a retailer 6

7 other than Dominick s and not buying ready-to-eat cereal at all. To calculate the market shares of the outside option, we assume each person s potential demand for ready-to-eat cereal is 1 pound per week 2. This leads the outside option s market share belongs to [33%, 99%], with median 91%. Dominick s stores sell national brands and store brand cereals. The main national brands are from manufacturers Kelloggs, General Mills, Post, Quaker, and Raltson. Store brands products have lower costs. The average Dominick s store brands cost is $1.58 per pound. But lowest national brands average cost is $2.35 per pound for Post and the highest is $3.35 for Ralston. Store brands prices are also lower. The average price for store brands is $2.60 per pound. But the lowest national brands average price is $2.97 for Post, and the highest is $4.23 for Ralston. While store brands have low prices, their market shares are quite low, 5.54% on average. So though store brands are available at all Dominick s stores, they are not good substitutes for national brands. In next section, we show some facts about the substitution pattern across brands and its relationship with retailer competition. 3.2 Facts about Substitution and Competition In this section, we first introduce summary statistics of the data, then reduced form regressions are used to show retailer competition s different effects on national brands and store brands. Table 1 shows mean prices, markups and market shares of all brands across markets. Market shares in the table are shares within each Dominick s store. Dominick s store brands have low prices (as low as $2.24 per pound), high markups and low market shares. Ralston brands have high prices (as high as $4.75 per pound) and low market shares. General Mill s ring brand and Kellogg s flakes have the highest market shares, with 11.61% and 14.04% respectively. Market shares do not change monotonously with prices. So besides prices, product characteristics also play an important role in consumer demand. 2 Granola and Breakfast Facts in Year 2006 stated that Americans consume 10 pounds per person per year, which means that actual consumption per person was 0.2 pound per week and potential demand should be higher than that. Assuming potential demand lower than 1 lb/week causes unreasonably negative market shares of the outside option in some markets. 7

8 Table 1: Product Summary Statistics Retail Price($/lb) Wholesale Cost Markup Within Store shares (%) Dominick s ring % 1.29 Dominick s flake % 2.93 Dominick s shred % 0.60 Dominick s puff % 0.54 General Mills ring % General Mills flake % 9.48 General Mills shred % 2.47 General Mills puff % 4.37 Quaker flake % 1.85 Quaker shred % 4.11 Quaker puff % 4.77 Kellogg s ring % 4.77 Kellogg s flake % Kellogg s shred % Kellogg s puff % 7.83 Post flake % 8.07 Post shred % 4.09 Post puff % 3.69 Ralston shred % 2.43 Ralston puff % 0.77 The ready-to-eat cereal market is highly concentrated. The five biggest national manufacturers are: Kelloggs, General Mills, Post, Quaker and Raltson. According to the sales data of all Dominick s stores in 1996, the total market share (in terms of quantity sold) of the five companies is 94.91%. The decomposed shares are: 36.92% for Kelloggs, 27.93% for General Mills, 15.85% for Post, 10.73% for Quaker and 3.20% for Ralston. The market demographics we use are population, number of food retailers, logarithm of median income, age distribution statistics, and percentage of people owning a car in every market. Table 2 summarizes the market characteristics. The mean number of food retailers within a zip code area is 17.56, and the mean outside option share is 86.40%. Next, we use simple regressions to see the different effects of retailer competition on store brands and national brands. Let j = 0, 1,..., J denote different brands of cereal products, i = 1, 2,..., S denote consumers, and t = 1, 2,..., M denote markets. The first regression is as following: m jt = b 1 R t + b 2 Inc t + ϵ 1jt 8

9 Table 2: Market Demographic Statistics mean standard deviation Log Median Income Population Age< 9 Percentage No car Percentage # Competitors Outside share 86.40% 12.18% where m jt is the markup of product j in market t, R t is the number of supermarkets in market t and Inc t be logarithm of median income in market t. m jt is defined as the ratio of gross profit per pound over price per pound, which is observed from data. For each product, gross profit is equal to revenue from sales of the product minus the wholesale cost of the product. Other than wholesale cost, there is distribution cost for each product, which will be calculated later. For example, m jt =.3 means that for every dollar revenue, $.30 is gross profit, and $.70 is wholesale cost. Table 3: Markups and Competition ˆb 1 ˆb2 Dominick s GeneralMills Quaker Kellogg s Post Ralston As table 3 shows, markups of most national brands decrease significantly with competition, while store brands markups don t decrease with competition. This fact implies that competing retailers affect the profitability of national brands more than that of Dominick s store brands. This is reasonable given that all competitors can sell national brands, but not store brands of Dominick s. Second, we regress the market (quantity) share of different brands within each store on number of competitors. log q jt q t = b 3 logr t + b 4 log p jt + ϵ 2jt 9

10 where q jt is the quantity sold of brand j in market t, q t is total quantity sold in market t, and p jt is price of brand j in market t. Table 4: Quantity Shares and Competition ˆb 3 ˆb4 Dominick s GeneralMills Quaker Kellogg s Post Ralston Table 4 shows that the quantity shares of store brands increase significantly with number of competitors. This is consistent with the reason about competition stated above. When number of competitors increases, previous Dominick s customers of national brands may switch to other stores, because these stores also sell national brands. But Dominick s store brands consumers do not switch to competing stores because store brands are unique to Dominick s. Last, we regress the gross profit share of different brands on number of competitors. log π jt π t = b 5 logr t + ϵ 3jt where π jt is gross profit from brand j in market t, and π t is profit from market t of all brands. So π jt /π t is the profit share of brand j in market t. Table 5 shows the simple regression results. As we can see, the gross profit share of store brands is low relative to national brands, but increases significantly with number of competitors, while national brands profit shares decrease except for Post brands. Again, these regression results are consistent with the competition effects stated above. In summary, the facts shown above imply that when the number of competitors increases, national brands are affected in the opposite direction from Dominick s store brands. 10

11 Table 5: Gross profit shares and Competition Gross Profit Share ˆb5 Dominick s 6.62% (3.45%).0435 GeneralMills 31.82% (22.24%).0133 Quaker 13.64% (16.07%).0277 Kellogg s 28.58% (19.41%).0045 Post 11.49% (6.29%).0108 Ralston 7.85% (13.36%).0240 National brands markups and profit shares decrease with competition, while store brands profit share and quantity share increase with competition. This is due to the fact that store brands are sold only in Dominick s, while national brands are sold by all competing retailers. So retailers can use store brands to lock-in consumers and gain profit as more competitors enter the market. This is the question we are trying to answer in this paper -the relationship between store brands profit and retailer competition. We describe the demand and supply model in the next section. 4 Model In this section, we model a consumer s discrete choice over different brands and a retailer s profit maximization problem. For the demand model, we use random coefficient model, which is used in BLP(1995) and Nevo(2000). In the random coefficient model, consumer s utility contains two parts, the first is the mean utility of all consumers in the market, and the second part is the individual deviation from the mean, which depends on consumer characteristics. The outside good is defined as not buying from the 20 brands in Dominick s. So if a consumer buys cereal from other retailers or does not buy cereal at all, we interpret that he or she chooses the outside option. Defined in such a way, the outside good needs to capture the competition effect of other local retailers. Mean utility of the outside option is a linear function of number of competitors and local median income. The more competitive the market is, the higher utility the outside good provides. For the supply side, we assume that the retailer has monopoly power to choose prices for both store brands and national brands. The retailer chooses prices to maximize profit, given consumer s utility functions. For each price vector of both national brands and store brands, there is a corresponding market share vector of all brands. 11

12 4.1 Demand Model In the random coefficient model, consumers have heterogenous preferences over prices and brands. These heterogenous coefficients depend on individual demographics and random realization of unobserved shock term. The unobserved shock terms in the random coefficients of brand dummies can be correlated across different brands. If the correlation between national brands and the outside option is high, then when a consumer has high realization of random coefficient on national brands, he is also likely to have a high shock on the outside option coefficient. This feature of random coefficient model fits the facts we observed from data. If national brands and the outside option are highly positively correlated, then when there are more competitors so the mean utility of outside option increases, consumers of Dominick s national brands are likely to switch to the outside option. Let j = 0, 1,..., J denote different brands of cereal products, i = 1, 2,..., S denote consumers, and t = 1, 2,..., M denote markets. Products are differentiated in their characteristics. j = 0 denotes the outside option. Let x j be the vector of product characteristics of product j, which is same across markets. Let ξ jt be unobserved product characteristics of product j in market t and ϵ ijt be unobserved individual utility of product j in market t. We assume consumers have correlated heterogenous preferences on different brands. If we use brand dummies, we will need to estimate a 20 by 20 dimension covariance matrix. So instead of brand dummies, we use group dummies. There are three product groups: store brands, national brands and outside option. Let d j be the vector of dummies for the three groups. For example, if j is a national brand, then d j = [0, 1, 0], and if j is outside option, then d j = [0, 0, 1]. Hence, consumer i s utility of product j in market t is : u ijt = x j β + α i p jt + γ i d j + ξ jt + ϵ ijt, for j = 1, 2,..., J (1) β is the coefficients on product characteristics, which is the same across consumers. In BLP(1995), the product characteristic coefficients are individual specific for the automobile industry. Consumers with different demographic characteristics may value auto characteristics very differently. However, for ready-to-eat cereal, the product characteristics are grain type, fruits and nuts dummies, whose values do not seem to vary across 12

13 individuals. So we assume β to be the same across all consumers. This reasonable assumption also decreases the number of parameters to be estimated. α i is consumer specific. For example, consumers with different income levels have different disutility on price. γ i is a vector of group dummy coefficients, and depend on consumer characteristics.. To allow competition to affect Dominick s profit, we assume that competition affects consumers mean utility of the outside good. Intuitively, consumers utility of consuming the outside good increases when there are more competitors. So we assume the utility of outside option in market t to be: u i0t = η R R t + η I Inc t + ϵ i0t, for j = 0 (2) η R and η I are coefficients on number of competing retailers and logarithm of median income. If η R is positive, then as competition increases, the market share of Dominick s will decrease. We assume that ϵ ijt has Gumbel distribution (type-1 extreme value distribution). α i γ is γ in γ i0 α γ s = + Π γ n 0 Inc i Inc 2 i + D(age < 9) D(car) ν ip ν is ν in ν i0 (3) [α; γ s ; γ n ; 0] is the mean coefficients on group dummies without consumer demographics. The mean of random coefficient of the outside dummy is normalized to be 0. Matrix Π has all coefficients on consumer characteristics. Each individual is characterized by D i. We use income, age dummy and car dummy for consumer characteristics. Let F Dt ( ) be the distribution function of consumer characteristics in market t. The unobserved part of the coefficients is [ν ip ; ν is ; ν in ; ν io ], which is distributed normal with mean [0; 0; 0; 0] and covariance matrix Σ. Let F ν be the joint distribution function of vector ν. We assume the price coefficient shock ν ip is independent with the ν is, ν in and ν io. Then the covariance matrix is: σp σs 2 σ sn σ so Σ = 0 σ ns σn 2 σ no 0 σ os σ os σo 2 The covariance matrix can be written as the product of an lower-triangular matrix and 13

14 its transpose: Σ = L L, in which L = l p l s l ns l n 0 0 l os l on l o This decomposition is used to facilitate estimation. The elements in matrix L do not have economic meaning as those in Σ. We can rewrite consumer s utility in the following form: u ijt = δ jt + µ ijt + ϵ ijt (4) where δ jt = x j β + αp jt + γd j + ξ jt µ ijt = [p jt d j] (ΠD i + ν i ) δ jt is the mean utility of brand j in market t. µ ijt is individual deviation from mean utility. Given the distribution of ϵ ijt, we can calculate each individual s probabilities of choosing all brands. For consumer i, he chooses product j if u ijt u ikt, for any k = 0, 1,..., J. Define set of consumer draws such that brand j gives maximum utility to them. A jt = (D i, ν i ) u ijt >= u ikt, for all k = 0, 1,..., j Then market share of brand j is s jt = df Dt df ν (5) A jt The random coefficient model allows a very flexible substitution pattern. Conditional on product characteristics and prices, consumers demand elasticity is high between brands that have high correlation in ν. So if σ no is high, then Dominick s national brands consumers are likely to switch to outside option when outside option s mean utility increases. 14

15 4.2 Supply Model In this paper, we assume each Dominick s store chooses optimal prices for all products it carries. This assumption is different from papers that examine the pricing strategy of firms. In Nevo(2000), three competition models between manufacturers (single product firms, multi-product firms, and collusion between firms) are compared to match predicted markups. In Villas-Boas(2007), three vertical contract models between manufacturers (linear pricing model, vertically integrated model and nonlinear pricing model) are compared to match estimated cost and margins. Unlike Nevo(2000), we don t need to analyze competition between manufacturers, because the retailer Dominick s sells all products by different manufacturers. Unlike Villas-Boas(2007), the focus of this paper is not a comparison of the effects of different vertical models, but rather the downstream retailer s store brands effect and competition with other retailers. So it is reasonable to assume that Dominick s stores are free to choose optimal prices. We don t estimate the supply side game because we don t observe prices of other retailers than Dominick s in every market. And we don t compare different contracts between manufacturers and retailers, because the vertical relationship is not the focus of this paper and the assumption that retailers take wholesale prices as given is justified by Cohen and Cotterill (2011). For each product, there is a wholesale cost c jt and a distribution cost w jt. Wholesale cost is the price paid to manufacturers. Distribution cost includes the wage paid to store managers and other employees. Let M t be the market size of market t. Then each store s problem is to maximize total profit from all brands every week. max p t J (p jt c jt ω jt ) s jt (p jt )M jt (6) j=1 The first order conditions of the retailer s maximization problem is: s jt + J k=1 (p kt c kt ω kt ) s kt(p t ) p jt = 0, for j = 1, 2,..., J (7) Let Ω be the matrix of price elasticities. Its (i, j)th element is s it(p t) p jt. Then the vector of 15

16 distribution costs can be calculated from the FOCs. ω t = p t c t + Ω 1 s t (8) where the variables with subscript t are vectors of all brands in market t. This supply side model is quite standard except for the distribution cost. The distribution cost here is important to rationalize the prices of each store. In Nevo(2000) and Villas-Boas(2007), because cost data is not available, price-cost-margins are calculated using demand side estimates and firm s first order conditions. However, in this paper, both retail prices and wholesale prices are observed and the demand side will be estimated separately. If we also calculate the price-cost-margins and costs as these papers did, the results may be inconsistent with observed wholesale costs. One explanation for this inconsistence is that the wholesale prices are not true costs. First, there may be measurement error in the cost data. Second, in addition to the wholesale costs, there are other costs to be able to sell the products. So introducing the distribution costs justifies the observed prices given the observed wholesale costs. The next section discusses the estimation strategy of the demand model, and the identification of the parameters. 5 Estimation 5.1 Instruments and Estimation The estimation strategy follows Nevo(2000). We use generalized methods of moments estimation. The moment conditions are based on the orthogonality between unobserved product utility and instruments. In the random coefficient demand model, the parameters to be estimated are θ = (β, α, η, γ, Π, Σ). θ has a linear part θ 1 and a nonlinear part θ 2. θ 1 = (β, α, η, γ) and θ 2 = (Π, Σ). The parameters in θ 1 enter the utility function linearly, while parameters in θ 2 interacts with distributions of observed or unobserved terms in utility function. The moment conditions are the orthogonality between unobserved product utility and instruments: E(ξ jt z jt ) = 0. The instruments used here are lagged prices and lagged wholesale costs. Prices are correlated over time, but current demand shocks are indepen- 16

17 dent of lagged prices. Lagged costs are also correlated of current prices, but independent with current demand shocks. ( ) The GMM objective function is to minimize ξz 1 ZZ Zξ over θ. To calculate the objective function for a given parameter θ, we use data and the model s equations to calculate ξ. First, we simulate S number of consumers in each market t according to the distributions of demographics. Specifically, for a given θ 2 and mean utility δ, we can calculate each consumer s probability of choosing each product. Then we take the averages to be the predicted market shares of each product given θ 2 and δ. Next, we match the predicted market shares and observed market shares to solve for mean utilities δ, for the given θ 2. After calculating the mean utilities, we estimate the parameter θ 1, which enter linearly in δ. The residuals of this regression is the value of ξ for the given θ 2. So we can find the value of objective function for each given parameter θ 2. Then we can search over θ 2 to find the estimates that minimizes the objective function. 5.2 Identification The identification of the demand model is quite clear. (β, α) are identified by products that differ in their characteristics and prices. Suppose that two products are exactly the same except that one has fruit and the other one does not. The difference in their market shares imply the value of β fruit. If β fruit = 0, then they will have the same market share. As β fruit increases, the difference between the products increases. The identification for α can be explained in a similar way. γ n and γ s are identified by the mean utility of store brands and national brands, controlling for the product characteristics, number of competitors and log of median income. The nonlinear parameter is θ 2 = (Π, Σ). Π is the matrix of coefficients on consumer demographics, and it is identified by the market shares of markets with different demographics. Suppose two markets have the same prices for all products, same age distribution and same percentage of people having a car. Then the difference between the two markets product shares identifies the coefficients on income. If the coefficients on income are zeros, then the two markets will have the same market shares. But if the coefficients on the interaction of income and price is positive(less elastic), then the market with higher level of income will have higher market shares of the more expensive products. Similarly, if the coefficients on the interaction of income and national brand group dummy is posi- 17

18 tive, then market with higher level of income will have higher market shares of the same national brands. The identification of all parameters in Π can be explained in this way. The diagonal terms of Σ are identified by consumers loyalty to different groups. The higher the diagonal terms are, the more loyal the consumers are to these groups. For example, if σ n is high, then consumers are very heterogenous in their evaluation of national brands and this will lead consumers to substitute into similar products when price changes. These consumers are not very likely to switch to store brands or the outside option when national brands prices increase. If σ n is low, then unobserved utility is not an important part of consumers utility of national brands. In this case, when national brands prices increase, the consumers are likely to switch to store brands or the outside option. The extent to which national brands market share changes when national brands prices change identifies σ n. The identification of σ s and σ o can be explained similarly. In BLP(1995), the variances are estimated while the covariance terms are assumed to be zero. However, the covariance terms are critical in our paper. We want to emphasize the substitution patterns that are determined by correlation of peoples preferences across group dummies, which can t be a common product characteristic for brands in different groups. The off-diagonal terms determine the substitution patterns across groups, and they are identified by the asymmetric substitution patterns of store brands and national brands. Suppose σ no = 0, and purchases of national brands and store brands of Dominick s decrease when the number of competing retailers increases. If σ no > 0, then national brands consumers are likely to prefer the outside option and the market shares of national brands will decrease more than they do when σ no = 0. Similarly, if σ so < 0, then store brands consumers are not likely to prefer the outside option. Then market shares of store brands will decrease less than the case when σ so = 0. We can use similar arguments when the mean utilities of store brands and national brands change, and these arguments strengthen the identification of the correlations. 6 Estimation Results This section shows the estimation results of the random coefficient model. To compare results, we also estimate the model with simple Logit model with instruments. The simple Logit model can be estimated using a linear IV estimation. In the random coefficient model, we set the interaction terms between price and squared income, between national 18

19 brands group and squared income, between outside option and squared income, between price and age, and between national brands group and age to be zero. Table 6: Demand Estimation Results Logit-IV Random Coefficients β wheat (0.08) (0.23) β oat (0.10) (0.19) β bran 1.20 (0.20) 1.95 (0.56) β corn/rice 0.70 (0.05) 0.71 (0.13) β fruit (0.06) (0.17) β nut 2.59 (0.15) 2.60 (0.30) α (0.09) (0.12) γ store (0.64) (0.56) γ national -3.8 (0.68) 1.31 (0.48) η R 0.06 (0.00) 0.05 (0.00) η Inc (0.06) (0.00) l p (0.11) l n 2.66 (2.00) l s (1.06) l o 2.61 (1.58) l no 7.44 (0.80) l so (2.86) l ns (4.36) The demand estimation results of the two models imply significant coefficients of price. The Logit model underestimates the price coefficient because consumers who are less price elastic are not differentiated with more elastic consumers. The Logit model doesn t allow consumers characteristics to affect price coefficient. So high income consumers who have small price coefficients are mixed with lower income consumers who have larger price coefficients. As a result, price coefficient in Logit model is underestimated. The coefficient on the number of competitors in outside option s mean utility is also significant and positive. So as the number of competitors increases, the mean utility of outside option increases. In both models, the mean utility of outside option increases as local median income rises. The estimation results show the estimates of elements in the lower-triangular matrix L. All elements but the last two are significant. We set the last two entries to be zero 19

20 when calculating the covariance matrix. The implied covariance matrix is: ˆΣ = The variance of unobserved utility for store brands is This high variance means that store brands consumers are very loyal to Dominick s store brands. These consumers are not likely to switch to national brands or the outside option when store brands prices change. The variances for national brands and the outside option are lower, meaning that consumers of national brands and the outside option are likely to switch to other groups when prices change. Let ρ denote the implied correlation between groups. In the random coefficient demand model, the estimates of the covariance matrix implies that correlation between random shocks on national brands and outside option is ρ no = So consumers with a strong preference for national brands will also have a strong preference for the outside option. The estimated correlation between the random coefficients of store brand dummy and outside option dummy is ρ so = Then if a consumer has high value of store brands, he is likely to have low value of the outside option. So Dominick s national brands and the outside option are close substitutes for each other. In addition, ρ ns = 0.44, which means that consumers preferences for Dominick s national brands and store brands are negatively correlated. Given these estimated results, retailers competition, which changes the utility of outside option, will substantially affect Dominick s national brands demand. The estimates of parameters in Π are shown in the table 7. The positive coefficient of interaction term between price and income level is positive, which means that the higher income the consumer has, the less dis-utility he gets from prices because we estimate negative price coefficients. The own- and cross- elasticities are shown in following table. elasticities are higher within the groups than across groups. We find that price 20

21 Table 7: Demand Estimation Results Random Coefficient Model(std) π price,inc 0.12 (0.07) π price,car (0.10) π national,inc (0.19) π national,car (0.23) π store,inc 8.31 (0.07) π store,inc (2.03) π store,age< (4.61) π store,car (1.03) π out,inc (2.44) π out,age< (1.41) π out,car (2.63) 7 Counterfactual Comparison 7.1 Without Store Brands One question that we are interested in is whether store brands are more important in markets with more competitors. In order to answer this question, we consider the case in which there is no store brand. One important assumption made is that wholesale costs stay the same when store brands are removed. Though this assumption is not reasonable when analyzing the vertical relationships between retailer and manufacturers, it is not problematic to analyze the relationship between store brands and retailers competition. We compare the optimal profits with and without store brands, and analyze the relationship between the profit change and competition. We also compare the welfare effect of removing store brands. Without loss of generality, assume the first K brands are national brands. Now each store chooses optimal prices of all national brands to maximize profit, given the mean utility of outside option. The profit maximization problem of any store is now: max p t K (p kt c kt ω kt ) s kt (p kt )M kt The F.O.C.s with respect to prices of national brands are: j=1 p t = c t + ω t Ω 1 (p t ) s(p t ) (9) 21

22 Table 8: Demand Elasticities Own KL s flake Dominick s puff Dominick s ring Dominick s flake Dominick s shred Dominick s puff General Mills ring General Mills flake General Mills shred General Mills puff Quaker flake Quaker shred Quaker puff Kellogg s ring Kellogg s flake Kellogg s shred Kellogg s puff Post flake Post shred Post puff Ralston shred Ralston puff where the upper script denotes variables in counterfactural case. Ω is the matrix of partial derivatives, the (i, j)th element is s it(p t) p jt optimal prices solve the vector equations. Let Π t at any given price vector p t. So the new be the new profit for the Dominick s store in market t. So Π t = K (p kt c kt ω kt ) s kt (p kt)m kt j=1 For stores in different markets, the profit loss from not selling store brands will be different. Market sizes, consumer characteristic distributions, and competition degrees are all different for different markets. We are especially interested in the relationship between profit loss and local competition. Previous facts show that the profit share of store brands increases significantly with competition. So when store brands are removed, the profit loss in terms of profit percentage is expected to increase with competition. We find that after Dominick s removing store brands, its profits decrease in all 285 markets. The median prices of the 16 national brands decrease. For all national brands in all markets, prices of 65% of them decrease when store brands are removed, and 35% 22

23 of national brands prices increase. The decrease in national brands prices implies that Dominick s chooses high prices for national brands after introducing store brands. With store brands, Dominick s increase national brands prices to differentiate national brands consumers from store brands consumers. Table 9: Median Prices of National Brands No Store Brands/$ Data/$ General Mills ring 3.51 (.26) 3.52 (.26) General Mills flake 3.32 (.09) 3.32 (.09) General Mills shred 3.57 (.12) 3.58 (.12) General Mills puff 3.74 (.41) 3.74 (.40) Quaker flake 3.12 (.14) 3.12 (.14) Quaker shred 2.46 (.11) 2.46 (.11) Quaker puff 2.94 (.28) 2.94 (.28) Kellogg s ring 3.35 (.24) 3.35 (.24) Kellogg s flake 3.07 (.34) 3.08 (.34) Kellogg s shred 2.68 (.19) 2.68 (.20) Kellogg s puff 3.62 (.46) 3.62 (.46) Post flake 2.61 (.19) 2.61 (.19) Post shred 2.88 (.11) 2.88 (.10) Post puff 3.21 (.32) 3.21 (.32) Ralston shred 3.98 (.79) 3.98 (.79) Ralston puff 5.11 (.31) 5.12 (.31) Table 10 shows the own elasticities of national brands with and without store brands. We find that consumers are less elastic when there is no store brand. This result is intuitive. First, consumers demand are more elastic when store brands are available because they have more alternatives in their choice set. Second, consumers are more elastic when prices are higher. The national brands prices are higher when store brands are sold, so the consumers elasticities are higher. The first two columns of table 11 shows the profit loss and market share changes of removing store brands. We find that the median profit loss is $108 per week per store, 23

24 Table 10: Demand Elasticities Without Store Brands Store Brands Dominick s ring Dominick s flake Dominick s shred Dominick s puff General Mills ring General Mills flake General Mills shred General Mills puff Quaker flake Quaker shred Quaker puff Kellogg s ring Kellogg s flake Kellogg s shred Kellogg s puff Post flake Post shred Post puff Ralston shred Ralston puff Table 11: Percentage of Profit Loss and Competition Profit Loss Outside Share Loss Elasticity Median 4.33% +0.24% ˆλ St.d 7.07% 0.73% ˆλ which corresponds to 4.33% of profits before removing store brands. And the total profit loss for all the 285 markets is $37853 every week. The $108 loss per week leads to a $5616 loss per store every year. Removing store brands increases market share of the outside option, with a median increase of 0.24%. The last column of table 11 shows the relationship between profit loss of removing store brands and retailers competition. To check this relationship, we regress log of profit losses of all markets on corresponding log of number of competitors and log market median income. Let π st be profit loss in market t after removing store brands. The results show that profit loss increases with competition significantly, with elasticity That is to say, when the degree of competition increases by 1%, the profit loss increases by.16%. 24

25 Suppose a Dominick s store has 10 competitors, and its profit loss from removing store brands is $500 every week, then this loss will increase to $540 if it has 15 competitors. Profit loss decreases with the market level income, with elasticity So when a Dominick s store is in a market with higher income level, the profit loss is smaller when store brands are removed. log( π st π st ) = λ 1 log(r ( t)) + λ 2 log(inc t ) We calculate consumers welfare change when store brands are removed. Given prices and characteristics of all alternatives, define consumer i s expected utility as E(u it ) = 20 k=0 s ikt (δ kt + µ ikt ), where 0 represents the outside option. We find that welfare increases when store brands are removed. The mean welfare increase is about $6662 per market every year. Two sources affect the welfare of consumers. On one hand, removing store brands reduces consumers welfare because there are less alternatives. On the other hand, removing store brands changes the optimal prices of national brands. These two effects lead to the relatively small change of consumer welfare. 7.2 Increasing Competition In this part, we want to find out the effects of increasing competition on Dominick s prices and profits. To calculate new optimal prices for all markets, we first check whether wholesale costs vary with number of retailers in a market. We use wholesale cost data to check whether wholesale prices change with competition. Using fixed effects for all brands, we found that coefficient in front of competition is 0, and not significant. This result implies that wholesale prices don t vary with number of retailers in a market. So we assume that wholesale prices in all markets remain the same when competition increases. Suppose each Dominick s number of competitors increases by 5, then mean utility of the outside option increases by 5 η R. Now consumers mean utility of the outside option increases and we expect Dominick s to decrease prices and lose profit. Given there are 5 more competitors, we solve the supply side s profit maximization problem to calculate the new optimal prices and find the profit loss of each store. The first two columns of table 12 are median prices after and before increasing competition. We see that prices of all brands decrease. The third column shows the median changes in markups of all brands. Markup for every brand is defined as the ratio of profit 25

BLP applications: Nevo (2001) and Petrin(2002)

BLP applications: Nevo (2001) and Petrin(2002) BLP applications: Nevo (2001) and Petrin(2002) February 16, 2009 1 Nevo 2001 (Econometrica): Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry Main question: The ready-to-eat (RTE) cereal industry

More information

Applications and Choice of IVs

Applications and Choice of IVs Applications and Choice of IVs NBER Methods Lectures Aviv Nevo Northwestern University and NBER July 2012 Introduction In the previous lecture we discussed the estimation of DC model using market level

More information

"VERTICAL CONTRACTS BETWEEN MANUFACTURERS AND RETAILERS: INFERENCE WITH LIMITED DATA"

VERTICAL CONTRACTS BETWEEN MANUFACTURERS AND RETAILERS: INFERENCE WITH LIMITED DATA Session: (June 4 th Product Differentiation Applied) "VERTICAL CONTRACTS BETWEEN MANUFACTURERS AND RETAILERS: INFERENCE WITH LIMITED DATA" Sofia Berto Villas-Boas UC Berkeley Prepared for: The 6 th INRA-IDEI

More information

Differentiated Products: Applications

Differentiated Products: Applications Differentiated Products: Applications Commonly used instrumental variables BLP (1995) demand for autos using aggregate data Goldberg (1995) demand for autos using consumer level data Nevo (2001) testing

More information

Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand. Data

Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand. Data Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand Aggregate (market) aggregate (market-level) quantity prices + characteristics (+advertising) distribution of demographics (optional) sample from distribution

More information

Estimating the Effects of Deregulation in the Ontario Wine Retail Market

Estimating the Effects of Deregulation in the Ontario Wine Retail Market Estimating the Effects of Deregulation in the Ontario Wine Retail Market Victor Aguirregabiria, Daniel Ershov, Junichi Suzuki University of Toronto April 20, 2016 Syracuse University Syracuse University

More information

Pricing Policy and Welfare in Retail Chains: A Case for Vertical Incentives

Pricing Policy and Welfare in Retail Chains: A Case for Vertical Incentives Pricing Policy and Welfare in Retail Chains: A Case for Vertical Incentives Adam Dearing November 7, 2016 (Click Here for the Current Version) Abstract I illustrate how in industries with vertically separated

More information

Structural versus Reduced Form

Structural versus Reduced Form Econometric Analysis: Hausman and Leonard (2002) and Hosken et al (2011) Class 6 1 Structural versus Reduced Form Empirical papers can be broadly classified as: Structural: Empirical specification based

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics University of Minnesota June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING AND PRODUCTION ECONOMICS FIELD Instructions: Write your code

More information

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector Yizao Liu Assistant Professor Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Connecticut yizao.liu@uconn.edu Adam N. Rabinowitz Assistant

More information

Lecture 11 Applications of BLP. Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005

Lecture 11 Applications of BLP. Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005 Lecture 11 Applications of BLP Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005 Outline Autos Breakfast cereal Spring 2005 Economics 220C 2 Autos Petrin, A. (2002), Quantifying the Benefits of New

More information

Organic label and profits sharing in the French fluid milk. market

Organic label and profits sharing in the French fluid milk. market Organic label and profits sharing in the French fluid milk market Céline Bonnet 1, Zohra Bouamra-Mechemache 2 1 Toulouse School of Economics (Gremaq, INRA), Celine.Bonnet@toulouse.inra.fr 2 Toulouse School

More information

All Tuna is not Created Equal: The Existence of Quantity Surcharges Due to Product. Differentiation. # AAEA Annual Meetings 2004

All Tuna is not Created Equal: The Existence of Quantity Surcharges Due to Product. Differentiation. # AAEA Annual Meetings 2004 All Tuna is not Created Equal: The Existence of Quantity Surcharges Due to Product Differentiation. #117955 AAEA Annual Meetings 2004 Hayley Chouinard Assistant Professor School of Economic Sciences Washington

More information

Mazzeo (RAND 2002) Seim (RAND 2006) Grieco (RAND 2014) Discrete Games. Jonathan Williams 1. 1 UNC - Chapel Hill

Mazzeo (RAND 2002) Seim (RAND 2006) Grieco (RAND 2014) Discrete Games. Jonathan Williams 1. 1 UNC - Chapel Hill Discrete Games Jonathan Williams 1 1 UNC - Chapel Hill Mazzeo (RAND 2002) - Introduction As far back as Hotelling (1929), firms tradeoff intensity of competition against selection of product with strongest

More information

Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods

Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods Gautam Gowrisankaran Marc Rysman University of Arizona, HEC Montreal, and NBER Boston University December 15, 2012 Introduction If you don t need a new

More information

Vertical Contracts and Exchange-Rate Pass-Through: An Empirical Analysis

Vertical Contracts and Exchange-Rate Pass-Through: An Empirical Analysis Vertical Contracts and Exchange-Rate Pass-Through: An Empirical Analysis Rebecca Hellerstein International Research Group Federal Reserve Bank of New York March 2004 Abstract Despite a growing recognition

More information

Mergers with differentiated products: the case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry

Mergers with differentiated products: the case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry RAND Journal of Economics Vol. 31, No. 3, Autumn 2000 pp. 395 421 Mergers with differentiated products: the case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry Aviv Nevo* Traditional merger analysis is difficult

More information

Merger Analysis with Endogenous Prices and Product. Characteristics Generalized Theorem and Application to the U.S.

Merger Analysis with Endogenous Prices and Product. Characteristics Generalized Theorem and Application to the U.S. 1 Merger Analysis with Endogenous Prices and Product Characteristics Generalized Theorem and Application to the U.S. Airline Industry Ziyi Qiu July 28, 2018 University of Chicago 1 University of Illinois

More information

Food Marketing Policy Center

Food Marketing Policy Center Food Marketing Policy Center The Competitive and Welfare Effects of New Product Introduction: The Case of Crystal Pepsi by Wei Xiao Food Marketing Policy Center Research Report No. 112 November 2008 Research

More information

Food Waste and the Sharing Economy

Food Waste and the Sharing Economy Food Waste and the Sharing Economy Timothy J. Richards* and Stephen F. Hamilton** Morrison School of Agribusiness, Arizona State University Department of Economics, Cal Poly San Luis Obispo January 2018

More information

The Operating System Network Effect and Carriers Dynamic Pricing of Smartphones

The Operating System Network Effect and Carriers Dynamic Pricing of Smartphones The Operating System Network Effect and Carriers Dynamic Pricing of Smartphones Rong Luo Department of Economics, Penn State University December 22, 2014 Abstract The utility a consumer realizes from owning

More information

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change Christian Michel Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona GSE This version: March 30, 2016 (First version: November

More information

Measuring Price Sensitivity Differences for Inner-City and Suburban Consumers: An Analysis of Breakfast Cereals with Supermarket Scanner Data

Measuring Price Sensitivity Differences for Inner-City and Suburban Consumers: An Analysis of Breakfast Cereals with Supermarket Scanner Data Measuring Price Sensitivity Differences for Inner-City and Suburban Consumers: An Analysis of Breakfast Cereals with Supermarket Scanner Data Eugene Jones Department of Agricultural, Environmental & Development

More information

How well targeted are soda taxes?

How well targeted are soda taxes? How well targeted are soda taxes? Pierre Dubois, Rachel Griffith and Martin O Connell Institute for Fiscal Studies Imperial, February 2018 1 / 28 Motivation Sugar consumption is far in excess of recommended

More information

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change Christian Michel Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona GSE This version: May 09, 2016 (First version: November 2012)

More information

A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation

A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation Igal Hendel Aviv Nevo Northwestern University December 14, 2009 Hendel & Nevo (Northwestern University) A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation December 14, 2009 1 /

More information

ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory MARKET FAILURES. Asymmetric Information Externalities Public Goods

ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory MARKET FAILURES. Asymmetric Information Externalities Public Goods ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory MARKET FAILURES Asymmetric Information Externalities Public Goods Markets can and do fail to achieve the efficiency and welfare ideals that we have presented thus far. Asymmetric

More information

Oligopolistic Competition, Technology Innovation, and Multiproduct Firms

Oligopolistic Competition, Technology Innovation, and Multiproduct Firms NEMO English Seminar Oligopolistic Competition, Technology Innovation, and Multiproduct Firms Jiandong Ju Department of Economics, University of Oklahoma Review of International Economics, 11(2):346-359,

More information

A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, Paper by: Robert H. Porter

A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, Paper by: Robert H. Porter A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, 1880-1886 Paper by: Robert H. Porter Joint Executive Committee Cartels can increase profits by restricting output from competitive levels. However,

More information

Identification in differentiated product markets

Identification in differentiated product markets Identification in differentiated product markets Steven Berry Philip Haile The Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP47/15 Identification in Differentiated Products

More information

Advertising and Market Share Dynamics. Minjung Park University of Minnesota

Advertising and Market Share Dynamics. Minjung Park University of Minnesota Advertising and Market Share Dynamics Minjung Park University of Minnesota Introduction Sutton (1991) s Model of Endogenous Sunk Costs - As market size increases, (1) Market structure in exogenous sunk

More information

MERGER ANALYSIS WITH ENDOGENOUS PRICES AND PRODUCT QUALITIES

MERGER ANALYSIS WITH ENDOGENOUS PRICES AND PRODUCT QUALITIES Generalized Theorem and Application to the U.S. Airline Industry MERGER ANALYSIS WITH ENDOGENOUS PRICES AND PRODUCT QUALITIES Ziyi Qiu University of Chicago This paper studies firms endogenous choices

More information

Food Marketing Policy Center

Food Marketing Policy Center Food Marketing Policy Center The Impact of Retail Store Brands on Manufacturer Brands: A Generalization of Steiner s Elasticity Model by Michael A. Cohen and Ronald W. Cotterill Food Marketing Policy Center

More information

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity Countervailing Power and Product Diversity by Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Work in Progress December 6, 2003 Abstract To analyse the effects of countervailing power on product variety, I construct a

More information

Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub

Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub Jian-Da Zhu National Taiwan University April 2018 Abstract This paper uses both listing and transaction data on

More information

Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry

Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry Aviv Nevo* 549 Evans Hall [3880, Department of Economics, UC Berkeley, Berkeley,

More information

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services By Ian Small of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. This article (1) reviews how price-cost mark-ups

More information

Identifying Competition Structure from Cross Price Elasticity Matrix

Identifying Competition Structure from Cross Price Elasticity Matrix Identifying Competition Structure from Cross Price Elasticity Matrix Inseong Song* Abstract Ill Data and Results I Introduction N Conclus~on and D~rect~on Il Model and Est~mat~on for Future Research Procedure

More information

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Chapter 8. Group pricing and personalized pricing Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge

More information

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review 14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14 Lecture 2 - Review Prof. Sara Ellison MIT OpenCourseWare 4 basic things I want to get across in this review: Monopoly pricing function of demand, elasticity, & marginal

More information

R&D, International Sourcing, and the Joint Impact on Firm Performance April / 25

R&D, International Sourcing, and the Joint Impact on Firm Performance April / 25 R&D, International Sourcing, and the Joint Impact on Firm Performance Esther Ann Boler, Andreas Moxnes, and Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe American Economic Review (2015) Presented by Beatriz González April

More information

1.. There are two complementary goods that are consumed together (each individual good

1.. There are two complementary goods that are consumed together (each individual good University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 22, 2004 Answer four of the six

More information

Our MCMC algorithm is based on approach adopted by Rutz and Trusov (2011) and Rutz et al. (2012).

Our MCMC algorithm is based on approach adopted by Rutz and Trusov (2011) and Rutz et al. (2012). 1 ONLINE APPENDIX A MCMC Algorithm Our MCMC algorithm is based on approach adopted by Rutz and Trusov (2011) and Rutz et al. (2012). The model can be written in the hierarchical form: β X,ω,Δ,V,ε ε β,x,ω

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Arm s-length Transactions as a Source of Incomplete Cross-Border Transmission: The Case of Autos Rebecca Hellerstein Sofia Berto Villas-Boas Staff Report

More information

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets C. Bonnet P. Dubois M. Simioni Contributed paper prepared for presentation

More information

Skimming from the bottom: Empirical evidence of adverse selection when poaching customers Online Appendix

Skimming from the bottom: Empirical evidence of adverse selection when poaching customers Online Appendix Skimming from the bottom: Empirical evidence of adverse selection when poaching customers Online Appendix Przemys law Jeziorski Elena Krasnokutskaya Olivia Ceccarini January 22, 2018 Corresponding author.

More information

Using Random Utility Structural Demand Models to Infer the Value of Quality Information

Using Random Utility Structural Demand Models to Infer the Value of Quality Information Using Random Utility Structural Demand Models to Infer the Value of Quality Information Celine Bonnet, James Hilger, and Sofia Berto Villas-Boas September 7, 2017 Abstract By conducting a field experiment,

More information

Inference on Vertical Contracts between Manufacturers and Retailers Allowing for Nonlinear Pricing and Resale Price Maintenance

Inference on Vertical Contracts between Manufacturers and Retailers Allowing for Nonlinear Pricing and Resale Price Maintenance Inference on Vertical Contracts between Manufacturers and Retailers Allowing for Nonlinear Pricing and Resale Price Maintenance Céline Bonnet, Pierre Dubois First Version: April 2004. This Version: May

More information

University of California, Davis Date: June 24, PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE. Answer four questions (out of five)

University of California, Davis Date: June 24, PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE. Answer four questions (out of five) University of California, Davis Date: June 24, 203 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PREIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Answer four questions (out of

More information

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK. University of California, Berkeley Department of Economics Field Exam January 2017 Labor Economics There are three parts of the exam. Please answer all three parts. You should plan to spend about one hour

More information

ECON 8010 (Spring 2012) Exam 3

ECON 8010 (Spring 2012) Exam 3 ECON 8010 (Spring 2012) Exam 3 Name _A. Key Multiple Choice Questions: (4 points each) 1. Which of the following is NOT one of the three basic elements of a game? D. None of the above answers is correct

More information

Appendix 1: Agency in product range choice with di erent

Appendix 1: Agency in product range choice with di erent Too Many roducts: Decentralized Decision-Making in Multinational Firms Catherine Thomas. August 5, 2010. Online Appendix Appendix 1: Agency in product range choice with di erent transfer pricing methods

More information

Prices, Markups and Quality at the Firm-Product Level

Prices, Markups and Quality at the Firm-Product Level Prices, Markups and Quality at the Firm-Product Level Emmanuel Dhyne National Bank of Belgium Frederic Warzynski Aarhus University March 13, 2012 Amil Petrin University of Minnesota Abstract In this paper,

More information

Market Structure and Product Quality in the U.S. Daily Newspaper Market (Job Market Paper)

Market Structure and Product Quality in the U.S. Daily Newspaper Market (Job Market Paper) Market Structure and Product Quality in the U.S. Daily Newspaper Market (Job Market Paper Ying Fan November 29, 2008 Abstract This paper studies the effects of market structure changes on newspaper quality,

More information

Lecture 7: More on product differentiation Introduction to the economics of advertising Tom Holden

Lecture 7: More on product differentiation Introduction to the economics of advertising Tom Holden Lecture 7: More on product differentiation Introduction to the economics of advertising Tom Holden http://io.tholden.org/ Endogenous differentiation: Horizontal (different consumers prefer different products)

More information

Wholesale Price Discrimination: Inference and Simulation

Wholesale Price Discrimination: Inference and Simulation Wholesale Price Discrimination: Inference and Simulation Sofia Berto Villas-Boas (U.C. Berkeley) January 25 2006 ABSTRACT In this paper we demonstrate a method for making inferences about wholesale price

More information

The Decision to Import

The Decision to Import March 2010 The Decision to Import Mark J. Gibson Washington State University Tim A. Graciano Washington State University ABSTRACT Why do some producers choose to use imported intermediate inputs while

More information

Search markets: Introduction

Search markets: Introduction Search markets: Introduction Caltech Ec106 (Caltech) Search Feb 2010 1 / 16 Why are prices for the same item so different across stores? (see evidence) A puzzle considering basic economic theory: review

More information

IO Field Examination Department of Economics, Michigan State University May 17, 2004

IO Field Examination Department of Economics, Michigan State University May 17, 2004 IO Field Examination Department of Economics, Michigan State University May 17, 004 This examination is four hours long. The weight of each question in the overall grade is indicated. It is important to

More information

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 27, 2006 Answer four of the six

More information

Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub

Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub Pricing Strategy under Reference-Dependent Preferences: Evidence from Sellers on StubHub Jian-Da Zhu National Taiwan University January 2018 Abstract This paper uses both listing and transaction data on

More information

Empirical evidence on the role of nonlinear wholesale pricing and vertical restraints on cost pass-through

Empirical evidence on the role of nonlinear wholesale pricing and vertical restraints on cost pass-through University of California, Berkeley Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics CUDARE Working Papers Year 2009 Paper 1089 Empirical evidence on the role of nonlinear wholesale pricing and vertical

More information

The Welfare Effects of Sunday Shopping Regulation in Retail Markets

The Welfare Effects of Sunday Shopping Regulation in Retail Markets The Welfare Effects of Sunday Shopping Regulation in Retail Markets A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF MINNESOTA BY Bitmaro Kim IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE

More information

USING EXPECTATIONS DATA TO INFER MANAGERIAL OBJECTIVES AND CHOICES. Tat Y. Chan,* Barton H. Hamilton,* and Christopher Makler** November 1, 2006

USING EXPECTATIONS DATA TO INFER MANAGERIAL OBJECTIVES AND CHOICES. Tat Y. Chan,* Barton H. Hamilton,* and Christopher Makler** November 1, 2006 USING EXPECTATIONS DATA TO INFER MANAGERIAL OBJECTIVES AND CHOICES Tat Y. Chan,* Barton H. Hamilton,* and Christopher Makler** November 1, 6 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. PLEASE DO NOT CITE OR QUOTE!

More information

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of 137 Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of BMW 1,3,5,7. Hyperlink Harald Schmidt Show: rtsp://streamer2.streaming.szm.de/sat1/schmidt/media//03/03/20/procter_56.rm

More information

Informal Input Suppliers

Informal Input Suppliers Sergio Daga Pedro Mendi February 3, 2016 Abstract While a large number of contributions have considered how market outcomes are affected by the presence of informal producers, there is scarce empirical

More information

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many THE HOUSEHOLD SECTOR IN THE SMETS-WOUTERS DSGE MODEL: COMPARISONS WITH THE STANDARD OPTIMAL GROWTH MODEL L. Tesfatsion, Econ 502, Fall 2014 Last Revised: 19 November 2014 Basic References: [1] ** L. Tesfatsion,

More information

Estimating Industry Conduct in Differentiated Products Markets

Estimating Industry Conduct in Differentiated Products Markets Estimating Industry Conduct in Differentiated Products Markets The Evolution of Pricing Behavior in the RTE Cereal Industry Christian Michel Stefan Weiergraeber April 5, 2018 Abstract We estimate the evolution

More information

A Structural Approach to Identifying the Sources of Local-Currency Price Stability

A Structural Approach to Identifying the Sources of Local-Currency Price Stability A Structural Approach to Identifying the Sources of Local-Currency Price Stability Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg Department of Economics Yale University, NBER and BREAD Rebecca Hellerstein Research Department

More information

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB CUDARE Working Papers (University of California, Berkeley) Year 2007 Paper 1030 Using Retail Scanner Data for Upstream Merger Analysis: Counterfactual

More information

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007 AS/ECON 4070 3.0AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007 Q1. Find all the efficient allocations in the following 2 person, 2 good, 2 input economy. The 2 goods, food and clothing, are produced using labour

More information

Competition Policy Center UC Berkeley

Competition Policy Center UC Berkeley Competition Policy Center UC Berkeley Title: Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry Author: Nevo, Aviv, Economics Department, University of California, Berkeley and NBER Publication

More information

Investigating Income Effects in Scanner Data: Do Gasoline Prices Affect Grocery Purchases?

Investigating Income Effects in Scanner Data: Do Gasoline Prices Affect Grocery Purchases? Investigating Income Effects in Scanner Data: Do Gasoline Prices Affect Grocery Purchases? By Dora Gicheva, Justine Hastings, and Sofia Villas-Boas Gicheva, Dora, Hastings, Justine, Villas-Boas, Sofia.

More information

Measuring the Effects of Demand and Supply Factors on Service Sector Productivity

Measuring the Effects of Demand and Supply Factors on Service Sector Productivity RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-042 Measuring the Effects of Demand and Supply Factors on Service Sector Productivity OHYAMA Atsushi Hitotsubashi University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade

More information

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro Eco 300 Intermediate Micro Instructor: Amalia Jerison Office Hours: T 12:00-1:00, Th 12:00-1:00, and by appointment BA 127A, aj4575@albany.edu A. Jerison (BA 127A) Eco 300 Spring 2010 1 / 61 Monopoly Market

More information

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Hongru Tan and Julian Wright March, 2018 Abstract We show that in the context of pricing by a multi-sided platform, in addition to the classical market-power

More information

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory Econ 500 - Microeconomic Analysis and Policy Monopoly Monopoly A monopoly is a single firm that serves an entire market and faces the market demand curve for its output. Unlike

More information

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 30, 2005 Answer four of the six

More information

Measuring the Effect of Infant Indu Title The Japanese Automobile Industry in.

Measuring the Effect of Infant Indu Title The Japanese Automobile Industry in. Measuring the Effect of Infant Indu Title The Japanese Automobile Industry in Author(s) Nishiwaki, Masato Citation Issue 2007-03 Date Type Technical Report Text Version URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/16967

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Competition Policy Center

Competition Policy Center Institute of Business and Economic Research Competition Policy Center (University of California, Berkeley) Year 1999 Paper CPC99 001 Measuring Market Power in the Ready to Eat Cereal Industry Aviv Nevo

More information

Customer Learning and Revenue Maximizing Trial Provision

Customer Learning and Revenue Maximizing Trial Provision Customer Learning and Revenue Maximizing Trial Provision Department of Economics: University of Pennsylvania December 27, 2017 Trial products Trial (demo) product: common practice in selling experience-durable

More information

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

Reading Essentials and Study Guide Lesson 1 Market Structures ESSENTIAL QUESTION How do varying market structures impact prices in a market economy? Reading HELPDESK Academic Vocabulary theoretical existing only in theory; not practical

More information

USING RETAIL DATA FOR UPSTREAM MERGER ANALYSIS. Sofia Berto Villas-Boas

USING RETAIL DATA FOR UPSTREAM MERGER ANALYSIS. Sofia Berto Villas-Boas Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 3(4), 689 715 doi:10.1093/joclec/nhm030 Advance Access publication 30 October 2007 USING RETAIL DATA FOR UPSTREAM MERGER ANALYSIS Sofia Berto Villas-Boas ABSTRACT

More information

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers Filip Matějka and Alisdair McKay January 16, 2012 Prepared for American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings Abstract We study a market

More information

Supermarkets Price Competition in Dallas Fort Worth Fluid Milk Market. Benaissa Chidmi

Supermarkets Price Competition in Dallas Fort Worth Fluid Milk Market. Benaissa Chidmi Supermarkets Price Competition in Dallas Fort Worth Fluid Milk Market Benaissa Chidmi Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics, Texas Tech University, Box 42132, Lubbock Texas 79409. Email: benaissa.chidmi@ttu.edu

More information

APPENDIX THEORY MODEL DETAILS

APPENDIX THEORY MODEL DETAILS APPENDIX A THEORY MODEL DETAILS This appendix provides additional information and results for the theory model that is described briefly in section V. We focus on implications unique to intergenerational

More information

Zone Pricing and Spatial Menu Costs: Estimates for Drywall

Zone Pricing and Spatial Menu Costs: Estimates for Drywall Zone Pricing and Spatial Menu Costs: Estimates for Drywall Brian Adams and Kevin R. Williams Department of Economics University of Minnesota May 20, 2013 Abstract In the empirical industrial organization

More information

EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in)

EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in) Econ. 240B, Second Half Daniel McFadden, 2001 EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in) Several oil refinery accidents in California in the Spring of 1999 restricted production of gasoline

More information

Price Discrimination. The Effects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Price Discrimination. The Effects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination Price Discrimination The Effects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination Add-on Pricing Bundling Nonlinear Pricing Third Degree Distinguish from First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimation Large literature

More information

A Structural Model of a Decentralized, Dynamic Auction Market

A Structural Model of a Decentralized, Dynamic Auction Market A Structural Model of a Decentralized, Dynamic Auction Market Ken Hendricks University of Wisconsin & NBER Alan Sorensen University of Wisconsin & NBER March 2017 Motivation Many goods and assets are traded

More information

Empirical Studies of Pricing: Homogenous Goods

Empirical Studies of Pricing: Homogenous Goods Empirical Studies of Pricing: Homogenous Goods Goal: Infer the competitiveness of market from data; The Structure Conduct Performance Paradigm (SCPP) Question: How does concentration effect conduct? Theory

More information

Ricardo Lopez Indiana University. Abstract

Ricardo Lopez Indiana University. Abstract Foreign technology acquisition, spillovers, and sunk costs: evidence from plant-level data Ricardo Lopez Indiana University Abstract This paper studies empirically the determinants of foreign technology

More information

Retail Pricing under Contract Self-Selection: An Empirical Exploration

Retail Pricing under Contract Self-Selection: An Empirical Exploration Technology and Investment, 2013, 4, 31-35 Published Online February 2013 (http://www.scirp.org/journal/ti) Retail Pricing under Contract Self-Selection: An Empirical Exploration Yuanfang Lin, Lianhua Li

More information

Citation Journal of Integrated Creative Stud

Citation Journal of Integrated Creative Stud TitleReport on my Stay at the Kyoto Inst Author(s) Nicolas, Schutz Citation Journal of Integrated Creative Stud Issue Date 2016-02-04 URL https://doi.org/10.14989/204550 Right Type Departmental Bulletin

More information

Economics of Information and Communication Technology

Economics of Information and Communication Technology Economics of Information and Communication Technology Alessio Moro, University of Cagliari October 5, 2017 What are digital markets? ICT technologies allow firms to sell their products online. The internet

More information

Inference of Service with Limited Data Apple and China Unicom s iphone Exclusivity

Inference of Service with Limited Data Apple and China Unicom s iphone Exclusivity Inference of Service with Limited Data Apple and China Unicom s iphone Exclusivity Grace Wei Yu Boston University December 2, 2014 Abstract This paper provides a framework for evaluating retailers service

More information

Foreign Retail Entry under Domestic Rivals

Foreign Retail Entry under Domestic Rivals Foreign Retail Entry under Domestic Rivals Kyung-In Hwang University of Nottingham Midwest International Trade Conference 2017 Motivation Oligopolistic competition between Tesco(FDI) and Emart(Korean firm).

More information

Empirical Models of Pricing in Industries with Differentiated-Products

Empirical Models of Pricing in Industries with Differentiated-Products Empirical Models of Pricing in Industries with Differentiated-Products Up to now we assumed that the products were homogenous (at least as an approximation. Bresnahan, JIE 87, Competition and Collusion

More information

Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods

Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods Gautam Gowrisankaran John M. Olin School of Business Washington University in St. Louis and NBER Marc Rysman Department of Economics Boston University

More information