A GAME-THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE ON TRANSACTION COST AND THE DECISION TO MAKE, BUY OR MAKE-AND-BUY. December Khai Sheang LEE* & Wei Shi LIM**

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A GAME-THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE ON TRANSACTION COST AND THE DECISION TO MAKE, BUY OR MAKE-AND-BUY. December Khai Sheang LEE* & Wei Shi LIM**"

Transcription

1 A GAME-THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE ON TRANSACTION COST AND THE DECISION TO MAKE, BUY OR MAKE-AND-BUY December 2001 Khai Sheang LEE* & Wei Shi LIM** RPS # (MKTG) * Associate Professor, Department of Marketing, Faculty of Business Administration, Bldg. 1, National University of Singapore, Business Link, Singapore fbaleeks@nus.edu.sg ** Associate Professor, Department of Decision Sciences, Faculty of Business Administration, Bldg. 1, National University of Singapore, Business Link, Singapore fbalimws@nus.edu.sg Copyright Faculty of Business Administration, National University of Singapore.

2 A Game-Theoretic Perspective on Transaction Cost and The Decision to Make, Buy, or Make-and-Buy Abstract This paper examines a firm s outsourcing decision over time. We identify specific learning and the salvageability of specific learning by suppliers as reasons for a firm to adopt a make-and-buy strategy, even when outsourcing is less costly initially. We show that when specific learning effect is high, the firm follows a makeand-buy strategy, capitalizing on the cost savings in buying, while simultaneously acquiring specific know-how for an eventual switch to a make-only strategy. When specific learning effect is moderate, the firm adopts a make-and-buy strategy, followed by a buy-only strategy. In this way, the firm minimizes the appropriation risk in outsourcing. Finally, outsourcing completely is optimal for the firm only if specific learning effect is low. Key Words: Game Theory, Industrial Marketing, Transaction Cost Economics, Small Numbers Bargaining. 1. Introduction Since Coase's (1937) seminal work on transaction cost, which was later developed by Williamson (1979, and 1981), transaction cost economics (TCE) has been extensively applied to examine the procurement problem faced by firms. According to TCE, transaction cost varies depending on the characteristics of the transaction associated with the exchange relationship, for example, asset specificity, uncertainty, and frequency (Williamson 1985). TCE argues that, buyers should internalize (or make) their supply requirements to preempt against the hazards of opportunism in engaging external agents or suppliers when transaction specific assets are involved in exchange relationships, and outsource (or buy) their requirements otherwise. Based on the arguments of TCE, extensive empirical studies have been conducted to examine the effect of transaction specific assets on a firm s decision to 1

3 make or buy. Nonetheless, questions of whether a firm should make some of its requirements and buy the rest, or how a firm s governance decision changes over time, have largely been ignored. This is hardly surprising given that the paradigm problem of TCE is on the make-or-buy decision, and that in TCE, "organizational form is often modeled as a binary variable - make or buy" (Shelanski and Klein, 1995, p338). The emphasis of TCE on individual transaction as the unit of analysis ignores how different governance forms can be combined (Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). Some researchers have proposed that combined governance forms such as make-and-buy, franchised-and-owned units, and direct-and-indirect distribution channels, could be viewed conceptually as hybrid modes that lie on a continuum, with market exchange at one end and hierarchical integration at the other (Shelanski and Klein, 1995; and Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). Challenging this view, Bradach and Eccles (1989) proposed that combined governance forms were more appropriately viewed as plural forms, which they defined as "an arrangement where distinct organizational control mechanisms are operated simultaneously for the same function by the same firm" (Bradach and Eccles, 1989, p112). The authors suggested that, to understand why firms often follow plural forms, like make and buy, the focus must shift away from individual transactions to control mechanisms, and proposed three control mechanisms that govern economic transactions price, authority, and trust. However, like Dutta et al. (1995), we contend that it is not necessary to invoke these control mechanisms, and that plural forms can be examined through the lens of TCE. The objective of this paper is to formally examine how appropriation concerns (Klein et al., 1978; and Walker, 1988) arising from transaction specific assets and small numbers bargaining affect a firm's decision to make only, buy only, or make and buy, their supply requirements. We seek to provide an explanation as to why 2

4 firms both make and buy their supply requirements, and how their governance decision change over time. As the majority of prior research in TCE are empirical studies (Shelanski and Klien, 1995; and Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997) a formal analysis following a game theoretic approach could provide useful insights. A distinctive contribution of this paper is that it clarifies the findings (or lack of) in earlier empirical studies. In this paper, we propose that (1) specific learning and (2) the salvageability of this specific learning as two reasons for a buyer to change his governance decision over time and to follow a make-and-buy strategy, even if a supplier could supply at a lower cost initially. When transaction specific assets in the form of specific human capital are involved in an exchange relationship, buyers and suppliers may be "locked-into" transactions asymmetrically (Williamson, 1979 and 1981). This allows a supplier to transfer or salvage, in part or in full, the know-how that he has acquired from the specific relationship (Anderson and Weitz, 1986; and Pisano, 1990) to supply other buyers in the market. Furthermore, this specific learning, that is acquired by a supplier, may not be salvageable nor patentable (Monteverde and Teece, 1982) by a buyer. We show that such asymmetry in the salvageability of specific learning affects the outcome in small numbers bargaining, and hence a buyer s governance decision to make, buy, or make-and-buy. Furthermore, we show that a buyer s optimal governance decision changes as a supplier acquires specific learning over time. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The next section contains the literature review. Section 3 and Section 4 present a game theoretic model of industrial procurement and the analyses respectively. Section 5 examines the change in governance over time that arises from learning specificity and its salvageability, 3

5 while Section 6 discusses the results. The final section concludes and provides directions for future research. All proofs to the lemmas and propositions presented in this paper are included in the Appendix. 2. Literature Review 2.1 TCE and Governance Decision Extensive studies have been conducted to identify and to examine various governance mechanisms as safeguards against the hazards of opportunism in engaging external agents when transaction specific assets are involved in exchange relationships. For example, Williamson (1983, 1984) proposed the use of hostages to credibly commit to exchange relationships. Heidi and John (1990) examined the utility of relationships to safeguard relationship-specific investments and to facilitate adaptation to uncertainty. Stump and Heide (1996) suggested that opportunism by suppliers could be controlled through partner qualification and selection, incentive design, and monitoring. Anderson and Weitz (1992) proposed that pledges in idiosyncratic investments could be effective in reducing opportunism in channel relationships. Klein et al. (1978) proposed that reputation served as collateral against opportunism, while Klein and Leffler (1981) suggested that brand name is a form of specific asset that served as collateral by suppliers to deliver high quality. Others proposed that a multiple sourcing strategy could safeguard against delivery failures (Leavy, 1994; and Wilson, 1994) and suppliers' opportunism post contract award (Seshadri, 1991 and 1995). For small firms, for which internalization is not feasible because of resource limitations (Lee et al. 1999; Lim et al. 2000), Heidi and John (1988) proposed that close bonds with clients safeguard against opportunistic 4

6 behaviors by principals. In all these studies, the focus is on pure governance forms, rather than plural forms. 2.2 Plural Governance Forms More directly related to our study are those which examined plural forms. For example, Heidi (1994) recommended a typology of three governance forms market governance, hierarchical governance, and bilateral governance, and argued that nonmarket governance cannot be described by a single continuum. However, the author did not identify the determinants of plural governance structures. In Dutta et al. (1995, p194), it was proposed that adding a direct sales force to augment the rep channel serves as a safeguard against lock-in problems with the reps and provides a manufacturer with insight into downstream marketing activities when performance is ambiguous. The authors reported that the degree of lock-in problems faced by a manufacturer and performance ambiguity increases the probability that a dual channel will be used. However, since governance responses were coded as reps only and reps plus house accounts in their study, the authors did not distinguish when increasing asset specificity would increase the probability of dual channels vis-à-vis house accounts only. This is critical, as lock-in problems that arise from specific assets would also increase the probability in following a house accounts only strategy. In Gallini and Lutz's (1992) study of franchisors store-mix decision, it was suggested that, given the information asymmetry between franchisors and potential franchisees, stores owned by new franchisors signal business prospects to potential franchisees. As a result, when this information asymmetry between franchisors and potential new franchisees diminishes, all stores will be franchised. On the other hand, 5

7 Weiss and Anderson (1992, p106) hypothesized that the more extensively the manufacturer uses house accounts in a sales district, the more likely it is to convert the district to a direct sales force. This suggests that a firm following a make-and-buy strategy would likely switch to a make-only strategy eventually, which is contrary to Gallini and Lutz's (1992) arguments. Compared to these studies, we clarify the conditions when a buyer, who follows a make-and-buy strategy initially, will eventually switch to a buy-only or a make-only strategy. In a related study, Farrel and Gallini (1988) proposed that a monopolist intentionally licenses other firms to utilize his proprietary technology to produce and compete directly with him, because second sourcing or invited competition served as a safeguard for a buyer s specific investment. Although the authors' proposition, which was empirically tested by Dutta and John (1995), provides an explanation as to why firms make-and-license, it is silent as to why firms both make and buy. Another study by Carlton (1979) suggested that partial integration arises because firms integrate and use the market to satisfy the high and low probability demands respectively. Compared to Carlton (1979), we propose an alternative explanation, based on TCE arguments, for the use of plural governance forms by firms. 2.3 Learning Specificity Williamson (1979) described asset specificity as the most important dimension affecting transactions. Although there are various forms of specific assets (e.g., Klein et al., 1978; Williamson, 1981; and Nooteboom, 1993a), we focus on learning specificity or specific human capital in the form technical know-how that arises from learning by doing (e.g., Williamson, 1981; Klein, 1988; Monteverde, 1995; Hart and Moore, 1990). This is because specific human capital has a stronger influence on 6

8 governance decisions than other forms of specific assets (Masten et al., 1989) and is the most commonly assessed form of specificity in TCE studies (Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). For example, it was postulated that specific know-how affects transaction cost and governance decisions (Pisano, 1990), could be a barrier to change (Nooteboom, 1993b), and increases the likelihood of vertically integrated production (Monteverde and Teece, 1982). Indeed, Monteverde and Teece (1982, p206) suggested that, Even if the title to specialized equipment used by the supplier is held by the assembler, this need not provide protection against rent appropriation if transaction specific know-how has been generated". We formalize the authors' argument and extend it to examine the effect of rent appropriation on plural forms over time. 3. A Game Theoretic Model To gain a more precise insight into the hazards of small numbers bargaining (Williamson, 1979; and 1981) when transaction specific assets are involved in exchange relationships, we propose a 2-period bargaining game. We will first describe the game before we discuss some characteristics of the model. In Period i (i = 1, 2), buyer B and supplier S bargain over price P i ( 0). We apply the Nash bargaining solution concept to derive the bargaining outcome. Let the unit cost of production for j (j {B, S}) be C j (q), which is endogenous on q ( 0), the cumulative quantity produced up to Period i for buyer B. Therefore, in Period 1, the supplier s production cost in producing for buyer B is C S (0). We normalize the buyer s purchase requirement per period to be 1, and use α to denote the portion of his requirement that he chooses to buy vis-à-vis to make. We define the learning-by-doing effect as an efficiency gain from cumulative production (Irwin 7

9 and Klenow, 1994). The learning effect is transaction specific in that a supplier learns, or acquires specific knowledge in production, only if it is awarded the supply contract in part or in full. Learning specificity, as we have defined, is a form of specific human capital that arises from learning-by-doing (Klein et al. 1978; Williamson 1979 and 1981; Schelanski and Klein 1995). Taking into account the effect of specific learning on cost, we therefore assume that the production cost function C j (q) has the following characteristics (Figure 1). (a) C B (α) > C S (α) for all α 0, that is, with the same amount of production experience α, suppliers have a cost advantage over buyer B (Maltz, 1994). This is because a "supplier who aggregates uncorrelated demands can realize collective pooling benefits" (Williamson, 1979, p245). (b) C B (1) < C S (0), that is, because of specific learning, buyer B could acquire a cost advantage over suppliers who did not possess any specific learning, if it chooses to produce in house. Otherwise, it will never be beneficial for the buyer to produce in house. (c) C j (α) is continuous and twice differentiable, such that C j (α) < 0 and C j (α) > 0, that is, C j (α) is strictly decreasing and convex with respect to α. This implies that, by Period 2, if supplier S was awarded a contract to supply α (α > 0), then supplier S would acquire specific learning in producing for buyer B and hence, gain a cost advantage over other suppliers in the market who did not possess such expertise (Monteverde and Teece, 1982). (d) d/dα C j (γα) d/dα C j (α) (j = B, S) for all γ between 0 and 1, that is, the rate of decrease of C j (γα) with respect to α is no more than that of C j (α). This implies that, if supplier S is to supply other buyers in the market, his rate of specific 8

10 learning in supplying these buyers will be no more than his rate of specific learning in producing for buyer B if he is to continue producing for buyer B. This is not unreasonable given that the specific learning that we are interested in is a form of specific asset and hence, is unique to the B-S dyadic relationship (Williamson, 1979), although it is salvageable (to an extent that is specified) in our model. (e) d 2 /dγ 2 C j (γα) > 0 (j = B, S). This property is similar to the requirement in (c) whereby we have C j (α) > 0. (Insert Figure 1 here) We consider the case when the market is competitive in that supplies are readily available from competing symmetric suppliers. Hence, in the initial period, the suppliers optimal choice of price P 1 is the competitive market price C S (0). However, in the presence of learning specificity, the situation is transformed from one of competitive market into one of small numbers bargaining. For each period i (i = 1, 2), depending on the bargaining outcome P i, supplier S decides on whether or not to supply buyer B, while the latter chooses to outsource a portion α i ( [0,1]) of his requirements to the supplier, while producing a portion (1- α i ) of the required supplies himself. That is, B decides on whether to make (α i = 0), buy (α i = 1), or make-and-buy (α i (0,1)). Hence, (α 1, P 1, α 2, P 2 ) defines the supply contract between buyer B and supplier S for the two-period game. For simplicity, our model consists of two periods instead of an arbitrary n periods. However, it is worthwhile to note that the results obtained are not compromised. 9

11 Let γ ( [0,1]) denote the degree of salvageability of learning by supplier S outside of the specific buyer-supplier (B and S) exchange relationship. This means that the specific knowledge acquired by S is transferable in that he can use this knowledge, in part or in full to the extent as defined by γ, to produce at a cost C S (γα), such that C S (0) C S (γα) C S (α) (Figure 1), to supply other buyers B' in the market at a price P S [C S (γα), P*], where P* = C S (0). Obviously, P S cannot be less than the production cost C S (γα) but neither can it be higher than the competitive market rate C S (0). In other words, the supplier S could benefit from the salvageability of the specific knowledge that he has acquired, by supplying other buyers B' in the market. In doing so, the supplier S earns a premium ω(γα) = ρ(c S (0) - C S (γα)) ( 0), by charging P S = (ω(γα) + C S (γα)) = (1-ρ)C S (γα) + ρc S (0), where ρ [0, 1] represents the bargaining power of the supplier S vis-à-vis other buyers B' in the market. The premium ω(γα) = ρ(c S (0) - C S (γα)) is maximized when ρ = 1. Note that ω(γα) is non-decreasing in γ and α if ρ = 0 and strictly increasing if ρ > 0 (Figure 1). Obviously, if α = 0, then ω(0) = 0. Given that supplier S earns a minimum premium ω(γα) by supplying other buyers B', he can therefore demand a minimum price (C S (α) + ω(γα)) from buyer B (Figure 1). The buyer B chooses a portion α (= {α 1, α 2 }) of his supply requirement to buy vis-à-vis to make, to minimize his total cost of purchase over the two periods. We assume that, whenever B is indifferent between producing internally and outsourcing, he chooses to produce internally. The payoff (cost) of buyer B over the two-period game is thus given by π B (α 1,P 1,α 2,P 2 ) = [α 1 P 1 + (1 - α 1 )C B (0)] + [α 2 P 2 + (1 - α 2 )C B (1-α 1 )], (1) where B chooses α to minimize π B (α 1,P 1,α 2,P 2 ). 10

12 A supplier s unit profit is given by (P i - C S (α i )), and he bargains over prices P = {P 1, P 2 } to maximize his payoff, which is given by π S (α) = {α 1 [P 1 - C S (α 1 )] + α 2 [P 2 C S (α 2 )]}. Williamson (1979, p242) suggested that in a bilateral monopoly, Although both (buyer and seller) have a long term interest in effecting adaptations of a joint profit maximizing kind, each also has an interest in appropriating as much of the gains as he can on each occasion to adapt. Our model is consistent with the author's argument in that buyer B and supplier S bargain over prices in each period to maximize their individual payoffs. Supplier S in our model is opportunistic in that he maximizes rent appropriation by exploiting the fact that his possession of idiosyncratic know-how makes him difficult to be replaced. The quasi-rent (Klein et al., 1978) appropriable by the supplier, or the appropriation risk faced by the buyer, can be defined as τ = (P 2 - C S (α 1 )), which is also consistent with Monteverde and Teece s (1982) measure of opportunism as price hikes in follow-on periods. In the next section, we will present the formal analysis of the game, first stating the best responses of B and S in the respective subgames, and eventually the subgame perfect equilibrium of the game. 4. Analysis: Make, Buy, or Make-and-Buy We first state the following lemma, which will be useful in our analysis. Essentially, the lemma states that, given a fixed degree of salvageability γ, the minimum price that supplier S can demand from buyer B is strictly decreasing in α, the proportion of the buyer's supply requirement that is outsourced. 11

13 Lemma 1: Given γ, the curve (C S (α) + ω(γα)) is strictly decreasing in α ( (0, 1)), that is, / α [C S (α) + ω(γα)] < 0. Using backward induction, we begin our analysis of the game from the final period. Suppose buyer B buys α 1 and makes (1 - α 1 ) of his requirement in Period 1. In Period 2, the unit cost of production of supplier S becomes C S (α 1 ), due to learning from the earlier period. In contrast, suppliers who were not awarded any prior supply contract would not benefit from learning specificity, and hence their unit cost of production would remain at C S (0). The incumbent supplier S therefore has a cost advantage over other competing suppliers in Period 2, as a result of learning specificity, since C S (α 1 ) < C S (0), α 1 > 0. Given the prior production experience of buyer B, his unit cost of production in Period 2 becomes C B (1-α 1 ). For supplier S to secure the supply contact in Period 2, he must therefore offer a price that at least matches the buyer s unit cost C B (1-α 1 ) or the competitive market price C S (0), whichever is lower, that is, P 2 Min[C B (1-α 1 ), C S (0)]. On the other hand, since learning is partially salvageable by S outside of the specific buyer-seller relationship, supplier S is assured of a minimum premium ω(γα 1 ). Hence, he can demand a price P 2 (C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) from buyer B. We observe that (C S (α) + ω(γα)) C S (0), where equality holds when α = 0. The bargaining outcome in Period 2, P * 2, is therefore bounded below by the minimum price level (C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )), if (C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) C B (1-α 1 ), and bounded above by the maximum price level Min[C B (1-α 1 ), C S (0)]. That is, (C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) P * 2 Min[C B (1-α 1 ), C S (0)], in which case buyer B also chooses to outsource all his requirements in Period 2, that is, α 2 = 1. 12

14 On the other hand, if buyer B could produce at a cost that is lower than the minimum price demanded by supplier S, that is, (C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) > C B (1-α 1 ), then obviously buyer B will choose to produce all his requirements in Period 2. Lemma 2 states this result and the bargaining outcome, where λ denotes the bargaining power of supplier S vis-à-vis buyer B in Period 2. As Lemma 2 shows, the buyer's choice of α 1 in Period 1 affects both the buyer's and the supplier's unit production cost in Period 2, and the appropriation risk τ = (P * 2 (α 1,P 1 )) - C S (α 1 )). Lemma 2: Given (α 1, P 1 ) as the decision choices in Period 1, the Nash equilibrium of the subgame beginning at Period 2 is given by, (α 2 * (α 1,P 1 ), P 2 * (α 1,P 1 )) = (0, C B (1-α 1 )), if C B (1-α 1 ) C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ), (1, (1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) + λmin[c B (1-α 1 ), C S (0)]), otherwise. Next, we shall examine the cases when the effect of specific learning for the buyer is (i) high, such that C B (1-α 1 ) C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ), (ii) moderate, such that C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) < C B (1-α 1 ) C S (0), and (iii) low, such that C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) C S (0) < C B (1- α 1 ). Before we proceed with the analysis of the cases stated, we first define a few notations that will be used later. With reference to Figure 1, let α (0,1) be such that C B (1-α 1 ) C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) for all α 1 α. Note that α always exist, since C S (0) + ω(0) = C S (0) + 0 > C B (1) but C S (1) + ω(γ) = C S (1) + ρ[c S (0) - C S (γ)] < ρ C S (0) + (1 - ρ)c S (1) < C B (0). Hence, by the Intermediate Value Theorem, there exists an α in the interval (0,1) such that C B (1-α) = C S (α) + ω(γα). Similarly, since C B (1 - α) < C S (0) and C B (0) > C S (0), again by the Intermediate Value Theorem, the existence of α ( [α,1]) such that C B (1 - α) = C S (0) is assured. Given that C S (α) + ω(γα) is 13

15 decreasing in α (Lemma 1) and that C B (1-α) is increasing in α, we deduce that C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) < C B (1-α 1 ) C S (0) for all α 1 [α, α] and C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) C S (0) < C B (1-α 1 ) for α 1 ( α, 1). Finally, let Γ a,b denote the subgame where α 1 is between a and b. 3.1 High Specific Learning Effect: C B (1-α 1 ) C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) With reference to Figure 1, for values of α 1 between 0 and α, since C B (1-α 1 ) C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ), Lemma 2 implies that the buyer s 2-period payoff is given by π B (α 1,C S (0),0,C B (1-α 1 )) = [α 1 C S (0) + (1 - α 1 )C B (0)] + C B (1-α 1 ). Let α a denote the solution to the first order condition C S (0) - C B (0) - C B (1-α 1 ) = 0. It is easy to check that the second-order condition is C B (1-α 1 ) (> 0). Hence, the buyer s cost is minimized when α 1 equals α a, if it exists. Otherwise, the buyer s cost is minimized at one of the boundary points, 0 or α. Proposition 1 thus follows. Proposition 1: In the subgame Γ 0,α, the optimal decisions for buyer B are: 0, if C S (0) - C B (0) > C B (1-α 1 ), α 1 [0, α], α 1 * = α, if C S (0) - C B (0) < C B (1-α 1 ), α 1 [0, α], α a, if α a (0, α) such that C S (0) - C B (0) - C B (1-α a ) = 0. P * 1 = C S (0), α 2 = 0, and P * 2 = C B (1-α * 1 ). Furthermore, α * 1, α * 2 and P * 1, P * 2 are independent of γ, ρ, and λ. The appropriation risk faced by the buyer is τ = (C B (1- α * 1 ) - C S (α * 1 )). As Proposition 1 shows, when the effect of specific learning on the buyer s cost is high, such that C B (1 - α 1 ) C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) C S (0), the optimum choice of α 14

16 is independent of γ, ρ, and λ, and is driven solely by the effect of specific learning. This is consistent with Williamson's (1979) suggestion that asset specificity is the single most important factor that drives transaction cost and governance decision. Note also that, when the effect of specific learning is high, appropriation risk τ, and hence governance decision, is driven by the relative difference in production costs of the buyer vis-à-vis the supplier, that is, τ = (C B (1-α * 1 ) - C S (α * 1 )). This perhaps provides an explanation for Walker and Weber s (1984) observation that comparative production cost is the strongest predictor of governance decision, in their empirical study. When there exists α a ( (0, α)) such that the gradient of the buyer s cost function at (1 - α a ) equals C B (0) - C S (0), the buyer adopts the make-and-buy policy in Period 1. This is because, if the buyer chooses a make-only strategy in Period 1, then he is not capitalizing on the cost savings from outsourcing, given that his initial unit cost is higher than that of the supplier's. On the other hand, if the buyer chooses a buy-only strategy in Period 1, then he could not credibly internalize the production of his requirement in the next period. The buyer therefore optimizes by following a make-and-buy strategy initially, but switches to the make-only strategy when he has acquired a cost advantage over the supplier. Obviously, the greater the effect of specific learning on cost reduction, the earlier the buyer switches to the make-only strategy, to the extent that he would follow a make-only strategy right from the beginning if the effect of specific learning is sufficiently high. This happens when the gradient of the buyer's cost function C B (1 - α) is greater than C B (0) - C S (0) (Proposition 1). Proposition 1 therefore implies that, even though the effect of specific learning is high, which suggests that the buyer internalizes his production, he could do better 15

17 by following the make-and-buy strategy initially. An external supplier is engaged initially for part of the buyer s requirements, until the latter has acquired sufficient specific learning to produce more efficiently. Corollary 1 therefore follows. Corollary 1: When the effect of specific learning is high, a make-only strategy right from the beginning is not optimal. The buyer is better off following a make-and-buy strategy initially, then switching to a make-only strategy when he has acquired a cost advantage over his supplier. The buyer's decision is independent of the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier. 3.2 Moderate Specific Learning Effect: C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) < C B (1-α 1 ) C S (0) For the subgame Γ a,b = Γ α, α, where the specific learning effect is moderate, the minimum price demanded by supplier S (= C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) in Period 2 is less than buyer B s production cost, that is, C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) < C B (1-α 1 ) C S (0) for values of α 1 [α, α]. Hence, Lemma 2 implies that buyer B will outsource his entire demand in Period 2, that is, α 2 = 1. Given that α 2 = 1, the buyer s total cost is therefore given by, π B (α 1,C S (0),1,(1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) + λc B (1-α 1 )) = [α 1 C S (0) + (1 - α 1 )C B (0) + (1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) + λc B (1-α 1 )]. The buyer s optimal choice of α 1, which minimizes the buyer s cost, is therefore the interior solution, α b (α, α), such that it satisfies the first order condition C S (0) - C B (0) + [(1 - λ){c S (α) - γρc S (γα)} - λc B (1-α)] = 0 (2) However, if α b does not exist, then α 1 * is one of the boundary points α or α. When γ or ρ is sufficiently large, the left-hand-side of (2) is positive for all α 16

18 (α, α) and we have α * 1 = α. We therefore deduce that α * 1 is non-increasing in γ and ρ. By a similar argument, as λ increases, the left-hand-side of (2) increases since [{- C S (α * 1 ) + γρc S (γα * 1 )} - C B (1-α * 1 )] > 0 (Lemma 1), which implies that α * 1 = α. We therefore deduce that α * 1 is non-increasing in λ. These results are summarized in Proposition 2 below. Proposition 2: In the subgame Γ α, α, the optimal decisions for buyer B are: α, if [(1 - λ){c S (α 1 ) - γρc S (γα 1 )} - λc B (1-α 1 ) - C B (0) + C S (0)] > 0, α 1 [α, α]. α 1 = α, if [(1 - λ){c S (α 1 ) - γρc S (γα 1 )} - λc B (1-α 1 ) - C B (0) + C S (0)] < 0, α 1 [α, α]. α b, if α b (α, α) such that [(1 - λ){c S (α b ) - γρc S (γα b )} - λc B (1-α b ) - C B (0) + C S (0)] = 0. P 1 * = C S (0), α 2 = 1, and P 2 * = (1 - λ)(c S (α 1 * ) + ω(γα 1 * )) + λc B (1-α 1 * ). Furthermore, α 1 * is non-increasing in γ, ρ, and λ, while P 2 * is increasing in γ, ρ, and λ. The appropriation risk τ is given by λ(c B (1-α 1 * ) - C S (α 1 * )) + (1 - λ)ω(γα 1 ). When the effect of specific learning is moderate, such that C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) < C B (1-α 1 ) C S (0), Proposition 2 shows that both the salvageability of specific learning γ and the bargaining power of supplier S (ρ and λ) affect the buyer s decision in the optimal amount to outsource α * 1. At equilibrium, since the supplier s unit cost is lower than the buyer s unit cost, the buyer chooses the buy-only strategy in Period 2. However, in Period 1, the buyer chooses the make-and-buy strategy. This is rather counter intuitive, as the buyer s unit cost is always higher than that of the supplier s in both Periods 1 and 2, that is, C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) < C B (1-α 1 ) C S (0) and C S (0) < C B (0), which suggest that the buyer should outsource his entire requirement in both periods. 17

19 However, if the buyer outsources his entire requirement in Period 1, then in Period 2, the premium ω(γα 1 ) that supplier S can command outside of the specific buyer-supplier exchange relationship increases, thereby increasing the appropriation risk that the buyer faces. The appropriation risk τ = λ(c B (1-α * 1 ) - C S (α * 1 )) + (1 - λ)ω(γα 1 ), whose gradient with respect to α can be rewritten as λ(-c B (1-α * 1 ) C S (α * 1 )) + (1 - λ)(-ργ C S (γα)), is positive. The term τ is increasing in α * 1, which implies that appropriable quasi rent is increasing in the specific assets that the supplier acquires, just as Monteverde and Teece (1982) hypothesized. In addition, the appropriation risk τ is also increasing in salvageabiltiy γ, as the premium ω(γα 1 ) is increasing in γα 1 (Figure 1). Hence, while the lower cost in buying suggests that buyer B should follow a buy-only strategy in Period 1, the resulting higher bargaining outcome P * 2 and appropriation risk faced by buyer B in Period 2 suggest that buyer B should follow a make-only strategy in Period 1 instead. Taking these opposing forces into consideration, the buyer therefore optimally chooses to make-and-buy in Period 1. The buyer s production experience in Period 1 reduces the supplier s ability to engage in opportunistic bargaining (Walker and Weber, 1984), thereby reducing the bargaining outcome in price when the buyer switches to a buy-only strategy, in Period 2. As expected, the appropriation risk τ, is increasing in λ, the bargaining power of supplier S vis-à-vis buyer B, since C B (1-α * 1 ) - C S (α * 1 ) > ω(γα 1 ). As Proposition 2 also shows, the optimal proportion to buy α 1 * is nonincreasing in γ. This is because increasing salvageability of specific learning by supplier S increases the premium ω(γα 1 ) that he could command from other buyers B', thus improving his bargaining position with buyer B. A reduction in the amount outsourced, α * 1, therefore reduces the appropriable quasi rent by supplier S. Similarly, when the bargaining power of supplier S, vis-à-vis buyer B (as denoted by 18

20 λ) and other buyers B' (as denoted by ρ) increases, the amount that buyer B outsources in Period 1 reduces. Proposition 2 therefore implies that, under moderate specific learning effect, even though the buyer s unit cost is always higher than that of the supplier s, which suggests that the buyer should outsource his entire requirements in both Periods 1 and 2, he could do better by following the make-and-buy strategy initially. An external supplier is engaged to produce a portion of the buyer s requirements initially, which reduces as the salvageability of specific learning increases. Corollary 2 thus follows. Corollary 2: When the effect of specific learning is moderate, even though the buyer s unit cost is always higher than that of the supplier s, a buy-only strategy right from the beginning is not optimal. The buyer is better off following a make-and-buy strategy initially, reducing the quantity outsourced as the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier increases, and switches to a buy-only strategy eventually. 3.3 Low Specific Learning Effect: C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) C S (0) < C B (1-α 1 ). When α 1 [ α, 1] (Figure 1) and Γ a,b = Γ α, 1, Lemma 2 implies that buyer B will choose α 2 = 1 and P * 2 = (1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) + λc S (0), since C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) C S (0) < C B (1-α 1 ). Hence, in Period 1, the buyer's total cost is given by, π B (α 1,C S (0),1,(1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) + λc S (0)) = [α 1 C S (0) + (1 - α 1 )C B (0) + (1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 )) + λc S (0)]. The first order condition with respect to α 1 is therefore [C S (0) - C B (0) + (1 - λ)(c S (α 1 ) - γρc S (γα 1 ))], which is always negative because C S (0) < C B (0) and C S (α 1 ) - γρc S (γα 1 ) < 0 (Lemma 1). The optimal choice of α 1 is thus the boundary solution α * 1 = 1. Proposition 3 states this result. 19

21 Proposition 3: In the subgame Γ α, 1, the optimal decisions for buyer B are α 1 = 1, P * 1 = C S (0), α 2 = 1, and P * 2 = (1 - λ)(c S (1) + ω(γ)) + λc S (0). The optimal proportion α * 1 is independent of γ, ρ and λ, while P * 2 is increasing in γ, ρ, and λ. The appropriation risk faced by the buyer is given by τ = λ(c S (0) - C S (1)) + (1 - λ)ω(γ). Obviously, when the effect of specific learning on the buyer s cost function is low, such that it is not possible for the buyer to produce at a cost lower than the competitive market price (that is, C S (α 1 ) + ω(γα 1 ) C S (0) < C B (1 - α 1 )), the buyer optimal choice is to buy-only in both periods, regardless of the salvageability of specific learning γ and bargaining power ρ and λ. The appropriation risk that the buyer faces is limited by the low effect of specific learning. Proposition 3 therefore is consistent with the central argument of TCE that transaction specific assets gives rise to hazards of opportunism (Klein et al. 1978; and Williamson, 1979 and 1981), and hence, firms should outsource only under conditions of low asset specificity. However, although α * 1 is independent of γ, ρ, and λ, the bargaining outcome in price P * 2, and hence the appropriation risk τ, are both increasing in γ, ρ, and λ. This means that, as the supplier acquires increasing specific learning, and as the salvageability of specific learning increases, he can credibly demand an increasingly higher price in future negotiations. Corollary 3 thus follows from Proposition 3. Corollary 3: When the effect of specific learning is low, a buyer follows a buy-only strategy right from the beginning, and pays an increasingly higher price as his supplier acquires increasing specific learning and as the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier increases. 20

22 Corollaries 1 and 3 are in general agreement with the central thesis of TCE in that, in the long run, firms should internalize and outsource under conditions of high and low specific assets respectively, which has been extensively tested and found to possess high predictive validity (Shelanski and Klein, 1995; and Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). However, prior empirical research in TCE has overlooked the implications of moderate specific asset condition, under which, the salvageability of specific assets affects governance decision in terms of the optimal quantity to make vis-à-vis to buy (Corollary 2). We next examine how a buyer s decision to make, buy, or make-and-buy, changes over time as a result of learning specificity and its salvageability by the supplier. 5. Change in Governance over Time From Propositions 1, 2, and 3, we obtain Theorem 1, which states that specific learning and its salvageability by a supplier interact to affect a buyer's decision in following a make-only, a buy-only, or a make-and-buy strategy. Observe that the buyer s payoff in (3) and (5) in Theorem 1 are the same by the definition of α. Theorem 1: Depending on the parameters of the game: γ the degree of salvageability of specific learning by a supplier, ρ and λ the bargaining power of the supplier vis-à-vis other buyers B and buyer B respectively, and the effect of specific learning on the cost functions C S (α) and C B (α), one of the following is a subgame perfect equilibrium. 21

23 α 1 P 1 * α 2 P 2 * Π B (1) α a C S (0) 0 C B (1-α 1 * ) α a C S (0) + (1-α a )C B (0) + C B (1-α a ) (2) 0 C S (0) 0 C B (1-α 1 * ) C B (0) + C B (1) (3) α C S (0) 0 C B (1-α 1 * ) α C S (0) + (1-α)C B (0) + C B (1-α) (4) α b C S (0) 1 (1 - λ)(c S (α * 1 ) + ω(γα * 1 )) + λc B (1-α * 1 ) (5) α C S (0) 1 (1 - λ)(c S (α * 1 ) + ω(γα * 1 )) + λc B (1-α * 1 ) (6) α C S (0) 1 (1 - λ)(c S (α * 1 ) + ω(γα * 1 )) + λc B (1-α * 1 ) (7) 1 C S (0) 1 (1 - λ)(c S (1) + ω(γ)) + λc S (0) α b C S (0) + (1-α b )C B (0) + (1- λ)(c S (α b ) + ω(γα b )) + λc B (1-α b ) αc S (0) + (1-α)C B (0) + (1-λ)(C S (α) + ω(γα)) + λc B (1-α) αc S (0) + (1- α)c B (0) + (1- λ)(c S ( α) + ω(γ α)) + λc B (1- α) C S (0) + (1-λ)(C S (1) + ω(γ)) + λc B (0) From Theorem 1, it is evident that, when a buyer follows a make-and-buy strategy, he does so only for the initial period, but eventually adopts a buy-only and a make-only strategy under conditions of moderate and high specific learning effects respectively. Hence, from Theorem 1, Corollary 4 follows. Corollary 4: When a buyer follows a make-and-buy strategy, he does so only for an initial period. Eventually, he switches to a buy-only and a make-only strategy under conditions of moderate and high specific learning effects respectively. Conversely, as Theorem 1 implies, a buyer following a pure form of governance (that is, make-only or buy-only) would not change to a plural form nor another pure form, based on asset specificity considerations alone. 22

24 Corollary 5: When a buyer follows a make-only (buy-only) strategy, he would not switch to a buy-only (make-only) strategy or a make-and-buy strategy, based on specific learning considerations alone. Corollaries 4 and 5 thus describe and clarify how governance decision, in terms of make-only, buy-only, or make-and-buy, changes over time under different asset specificity conditions, which is an important issue that has generally been neglected by prior TCE research. Compared to earlier studies on plural governance forms (Dutta et al., 1995; Gallini and Lutz, 1992; and Weiss and Anderson, 1992), Corollary 4 shows that, a firm that follows a make-and-buy strategy will eventually switch to a buy-only and a make-only strategy when specific learning effects are moderate and high respectively. (Insert Table 1 here) Table 1 summarizes our results and illustrates the interaction effect of specific learning and its salvageability on governance decision over time. Under conditions of high and low specific learning, a buyer's decision to make-only, buy-only, or makeand-buy, is driven solely by the effect of specific learning, while the salvageability of specific learning by a supplier has no effect on the decision. However, under moderate effect of specific learning, salvageability of specific learning by a supplier reduces the amount a buyer outsources when he follows a make-and-buy strategy. 23

25 6. Discussion The marketability of the know-how acquired by a supplier outside of a specific buyer-supplier exchange relationship improves the supplier s bargaining position. The supplier could therefore demand a higher price in future negotiations, thereby increasing the appropriation risk that the buyer faces. A make-and-buy strategy enables a buyer to acquire production experience, which improves his bargaining position vis-à-vis his supplier s in future renegotiations. Hence, when specific learning effect is moderate, such that it is not possible for a buyer to acquire a cost advantage over his supplier through specific learning, although the buyer s optimal strategy in the long run is to outsource completely, his optimal strategy is to makeand-buy initially. This is despite the fact that it is less costly initially to outsource completely. In addition, when following the make-and-buy strategy initially, the buyer should also reduce the quantity outsourced as the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier increases. Doing so reduces the price premium that arises from the supplier s market option, thereby reducing the appropriation risk that the buyer faces in future renegotiations. On the other hand, when the effect of specific learning on cost reduction is high, such that it is possible for a buyer to acquire a cost advantage over his supplier, a make-and-buy strategy allows the buyer to capitalize on the cost savings in buying initially. At the same time, the buyer could acquire specific know-how in production for the eventual switch to the make-only strategy, when he has acquired a cost advantage over his supplier. As the buyer could (and would) credibly internalize eventually, salvageability of specific learning by the supplier therefore does not affect the buyer s outsourcing decision in this case. 24

26 Obviously, when the effect of specific learning on cost reduction is low, such that it is not possible for a buyer to produce at a cost lower than the competitive market price, a buy-only strategy right from the beginning is optimal. It is also obvious that, in this case, the salvageability of specific learning by a supplier would not affect the buyer s outsourcing decision. Our analysis and results contributes to the understanding of TCE and its application to governance decision-making in several research areas, which we shall next discuss. 6.1 Transaction Cost Economics and Long Term Contracts Uncertainty has been identified as a factor that affects transaction costs, and hence governance decision (Williamson; 1985), and has received much research attention (e.g. Walker and Weber, 1984 and 1987; Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt, 1986; Weiss and Anderson, 1992; and Stump and Heidi, 1996). We did not include uncertainty in our analysis. This is because we wish to show that the presence of specific learning and its salvageability by a supplier are sufficient to give rise to appropriation risk, and hence to affect governance decisions, even in the absence of uncertainty. Like Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1994), we examine the implications of the hold-up problem, when a firm cannot costlessly replace an agent if the latter possesses specific human capital. However, unlike Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1994), who focused on the make-or-buy decision and the optimal debt repayment path, respectively, our concern is on plural forms in terms of make-only, buy-only, or make-and-buy. 25

27 In our model, the appropriation risk is endogenous on specific learning and its salvageability. This ex-post cost differs from the agency cost that arises from the private information that agents have of their own productivity (Olsen, 1996). Several researchers applied the principal-agent approach in examining long term contracts (e.g., Aghion et al., 1994; Dewatripont and Maskin 1995; and Holden 1999), which were proposed as a substitute for vertical integration (e.g., Kleindorfer and Knieps 1982; and Joskow 1987). The underlying theme of the majority of the studies on long-term contracting (Aghion et al., 1994; Chung, 1991 and 1995; Dewatripont, 1988; Dewatripont and Maskin, 1995; Grout, 1984; Hart and Moore, 1988; Holden, 1999; Huberman and Kahn, 1988; and MacLeod and Malcomson, 1993) is one of ensuring an efficient level of investment when re-negotiation is possible. Compared to these studies, which followed the risk-sharing principal-agent approach, we follow the risk neutral transaction cost approach, in examining governance issues. It is worthwhile to note that Allen and Leuck (1995) reported that the transaction cost approach has a greater predictive validity than the former approach. We did not explicitly examine long term contracts between the supplier and the buyer. However, from our analysis, it can be shown that, any long-term contract that is re-negotiation and performance proof must take the form of subgame-perfect equilibrium (7) (Theorem 1) in our model, where the buyer adopts a buy-only strategy. The argument is as follows. Klein and Leffler (1981, p615) showed that a necessary and sufficient condition for (contractual) performance is the existence of price sufficiently above salvageable production costs. Applied to our model, this means that any performance assured long-term contract must satisfy the conditions that P 1 C S (0) and P 2 C S (1). These conditions are satisfied by P * 1 and P * 2 in our results, as evident from Theorem 1. It is also clear that any long-term contract that 26

28 appropriates all rents from the supplier, that is, P 1 = C S (0) and P 2 = C S (1), cannot be re-negotiation proof. This is because the supplier possesses a market option, which earns him a premium ω(γ) from other buyers in the market, and which arises from the transferable specific assets that he has acquired. Hence, if P 1 = C S (0) and P 2 = C S (1), unless the contract is re-negotiated, the supplier would stop or disrupt supplies in Period 2. Any long term contract that is re-negotiation proof and performanceassured must therefore necessarily satisfy the condition that (P 1 + P 2 ) > (C S (0) + C S (1)), and in particular, take the form of subgame perfect equilibrium (7) as described in Theorem Empirical Studies on TCE and Procurement In a study that examines how small numbers bargaining and appropriation concerns affect firms procurement decisions, Pisano (1990) reported that a firm s historical propensity to procure R&D internally does not affect its R&D procurement decision. In the author's study, historical propensity is measured as a ratio of the number of own, to total, R&D products in development. This suggested that the firms sampled in the author's study were following a make-and-buy strategy, which the author regarded as a hybrid mode when measuring governance responses. Our analysis suggests that combined governance forms were more appropriately viewed as plural forms, instead of hybrid modes, and that asset specificity conditions be accurately categorized into three low, moderate, and high, instead of the usual two high and low, as in Pisano s (1990) study. These are important considerations because, given that the firms sampled were following a make-and-buy strategy, Corollary 4 implies that they will eventually follow a buy-only and a make-only strategy under moderate and high asset specificity conditions respectively (Table 1). 27

29 Our results, which are derived theoretically, are in agreement with previous empirical findings by Masten et al. (1989) and Pisano (1990). The former reported that specific human capital has a positive and significant influence on the percentage of the component produced in-house while the latter found that small-numbers bargaining problems and the accumulation of specific technical capabilities influenced firms to internalize their R&D. These findings of theirs are in agreement with Propositions 1, 2, and 3 here, which imply that learning specificity has a positive effect on the proportion of a buyer s supply requirements that he chooses to make visà-vis to buy (Table 1). However, Masten et al. (1989) and Pisano (1990) did not examine how governance decision might change over time, or how it could be affected by the salvageability of specific human capital by the supplier. 6.3 Empirical Studies on TCE and Channels of Distribution Anderson (1985) examined how specific assets affect a firm s decision to internalize its sales function. It was reported that, when salespeople had high specific assets in their interactions with their clients, firms were more likely not to internalize their sales function. This observation, the author suggested, is contrary to basic TCE prediction. However, our analysis suggests that Anderson s observation could be explained by the asymmetry in the salvageability of specific assets by salespeople visà-vis the firms. Client related specific assets are likely to be more salvageable by the salespeople, than by the firm. Given that this is the case, Corollary 3 implies that firms are likely to outsource their entire sales function eventually, if they had started with a plural form initially. However, under sufficiently high specific asset condition, firms will internalize their entire sales function eventually (Corollary 1). 28

Copyright Faculty of Business Administration, National University of Singapore.

Copyright Faculty of Business Administration, National University of Singapore. A GAME-THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE ON TRANSECTION COST AND THE DECISION TO MAKE, BUY OR MAKE-AND-BUY December 2001 Khai Sheang LEE* & Wei Shi LIM** RPS #2001-034 (MKTG) ** Associate Professor, Department of

More information

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power May 19, 2012 Eric B. Rasmusen Dan R. and Catherine M. Dalton Professor, Department of Business Economics and Public Policy, Kelley

More information

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Yasuhiro Arai Hitotsubashi University August 2009 Abstract We capture the differences between patent and copyright by considering the optimal

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Simona Grassi Ching-to Albert Ma Max Weber Fellow Department of Economics European University Institute Boston University Villa La Fonte, Via Delle Fontanelle,

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

Competition: Boon or Bane for Reputation Building. Behavior. Somdutta Basu. October Abstract

Competition: Boon or Bane for Reputation Building. Behavior. Somdutta Basu. October Abstract Competition: Boon or Bane for Reputation Building Behavior Somdutta Basu October 2014 Abstract This paper investigates whether competition aids or hinders reputation building behavior in experience goods

More information

THE U-SHAPED RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND COMPETITION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE

THE U-SHAPED RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND COMPETITION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE THE U-SHAPED RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND COMPETITION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE Philippe Aghion Rachel Griffith Peter Howitt THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP06/1 The U-Shaped Relationship

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki Department of Economics, University of Crete, Gallos University Campus, Rethymnon 74100, Greece

More information

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. October 13, 2011 Abstract In a durable good market where sellers have private

More information

The Relationship between Pricing and Consumers Switching Costs: Comparisons between the Myopic and Perfect-foresight Equilibria

The Relationship between Pricing and Consumers Switching Costs: Comparisons between the Myopic and Perfect-foresight Equilibria International Business Research; Vol. 10, No. 3; 2017 ISSN 1913-9004 E-ISSN 1913-9012 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education The Relationship between Pricing and Consumers Switching Costs:

More information

Industrial Organization 04

Industrial Organization 04 Industrial Organization 04 Product differentiation Marc Bourreau Telecom ParisTech Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 04: Product differentiation 1 / 43 Outline 1 Introduction: forms of product differentiation

More information

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market Manas Paul Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research Gen. Vaidya Marg Goregaon (East) Bombay 400 065. Sougata Poddar Department of Economics

More information

A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing

A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing Jean J. Gabszewicz and Filomena Garcia CORE Discussion Paper 2005/95 Abstract We obtain explicitly the optimal path of prices for a monopolist operating

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

Innovation and the comparative efficiency of governance structures in the Dutch electricity industry: a TCE application.

Innovation and the comparative efficiency of governance structures in the Dutch electricity industry: a TCE application. Innovation and the comparative efficiency of governance structures in the Dutch electricity industry: a TCE application. Eva Niesten and Albert Jolink Erasmus University Rotterdam & University of Amsterdam

More information

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis Indrani Roy Chowdhury* and Sandwip K. Das** Abstract We provide a new formulation of the Porter hypothesis that we feel is in the spirit of the hypothesis. Under this

More information

Using Last-Minute Sales for Vertical Differentiation on the Internet

Using Last-Minute Sales for Vertical Differentiation on the Internet Abstract Number 011-0050 Using Last-Minute Sales for Vertical Differentiation on the Internet Ori Marom RSM Erasmus University Burgmeester Oudlaan 50 3062 PA Rotterdam, The Netherlands omarom@rsm.nl Abraham

More information

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition Besanko, Dranove, Shanley and Schaefer Chapter 5 The Vertical Boundaries of the Firm Slides by: Richard Ponarul, California State University, Chico Copyright 2010 John

More information

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Gerhard Clemenz March 2012 Abstract: According to the Porter Hypothesis (PH) stricter environmental regulations

More information

:RUNLQJ3DSHU1R ([SODLQLQJYHUWLFDOLQWHJUDWLRQ 7UDQVDFWLRQFRVWHFRQRPLFVDQG FRPSHWHQFHFRQVLGHUDWLRQV E\ %RJH*XOGEUDQGVHQ 6YHQ$+DXJODQG

:RUNLQJ3DSHU1R ([SODLQLQJYHUWLFDOLQWHJUDWLRQ 7UDQVDFWLRQFRVWHFRQRPLFVDQG FRPSHWHQFHFRQVLGHUDWLRQV E\ %RJH*XOGEUDQGVHQ 6YHQ$+DXJODQG :RUNLQJ3DSHU1R ([SODLQLQJYHUWLFDOLQWHJUDWLRQ 7UDQVDFWLRQFRVWHFRQRPLFVDQG FRPSHWHQFHFRQVLGHUDWLRQV E\ %RJH*XOGEUDQGVHQ 6YHQ$+DXJODQG )281'$7,21)255(6($5&+,1(&2120,&6$1'%86,1(66$'0,1,675$7,21 %(5*(1'(&(0%(5,661

More information

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the open text license amendment to version 2 of the GNU General

More information

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives Paolo Fulghieri University of North Carolina Merih Sevilir University of North Carolina Abstract This paper studies mergers between competing firms and shows

More information

Outsourcing service production in the public sector: Are we addressing the right question?

Outsourcing service production in the public sector: Are we addressing the right question? Editors corner Outsourcing service production in the public sector: Are we addressing the right question? By Per Nikolaj Bukh, Kurt Klaudi Klausen, Dana Minbaeva, Niels Peter Mols and Flemming Poulfelt

More information

Licensing under Bargaining

Licensing under Bargaining Licensing under Bargaining Chun-Chieh Wang, Assistant Professor, National Sun Yat-Sen University, Taiwan ABSTRACT To relax the assumption that licensees have no bargaining power, which is prevalent in

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

Carlton & Perloff Chapter 12 Vertical Integration and Vertical Restrictions. I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS A. Vertical Integration

Carlton & Perloff Chapter 12 Vertical Integration and Vertical Restrictions. I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS A. Vertical Integration I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS A. Vertical Integration Carlton & Perloff II. 1. Operating at successive stages of production a. downstream: towards final consumers b. upstream: towards

More information

Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs

Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs Quyen Nguyen University of Arizona November 14, 2015 Abstract Access to product information changes a consumer s initial belief about the product s

More information

Volume 29, Issue 4. Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition

Volume 29, Issue 4. Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition Volume 29, Issue 4 Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition Oksana Loginova University of Missouri-Columbia X. Henry Wang University of Missouri-Columbia Abstract We study

More information

Competitive Franchising

Competitive Franchising Brett Graham and Dan Bernhardt University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign 2008 North American Summer Meeting of the Econometric Society Motivation What happens when firms compete using both prices and franchise

More information

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research Alex John London Carnegie Mellon University Kevin J.S. Zollman Carnegie Mellon

More information

Consumers Some consumers choose to become entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs. Firms. Markets and Organizations. Economic Equilibria

Consumers Some consumers choose to become entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs. Firms. Markets and Organizations. Economic Equilibria Introduction The purpose of this book is to present a general theory of the firm. The theory provides a microeconomic framework in which entrepreneurs, firms, markets, and organizations are endogenous.

More information

Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory. September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science

Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory. September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science What is Organizational/Personnel Economics? 1. Key Component 1: Human Capital Theory + Heterogeneous skills/tasks

More information

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO 20015 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II Candidates should attempt TWO questions. marks. Each question carries equal When presenting numerical results, please give a complete

More information

BSM906 Economic Environment of Business

BSM906 Economic Environment of Business BSM906 Economic Environment of Business Lecture 5 Transactions cost Dr Sumon Bhaumik http://www.sumonbhaumik.net Problems with contracts What have we learnt so far? Property rights Are property rights

More information

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note Giorgos Stamatopoulos University of Crete 12 April 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86143/ MPRA Paper No. 86143,

More information

Credence goods. Even when the success of the service is observable to the consumer ex post, consumers typically

Credence goods. Even when the success of the service is observable to the consumer ex post, consumers typically Credence goods Credence goods: products and services purchased from informed experts such as auto mechanics, home improvement contractors, appliance service-persons, physicians, lawyers... The provider

More information

VALUE OF SHARING DATA

VALUE OF SHARING DATA VALUE OF SHARING DATA PATRICK HUMMEL* FEBRUARY 12, 2018 Abstract. This paper analyzes whether advertisers would be better off using data that would enable them to target users more accurately if the only

More information

Pricing in Dynamic Advance Reservation Games

Pricing in Dynamic Advance Reservation Games Pricing in Dynamic Advance Reservation Games Eran Simhon, Carrie Cramer, Zachary Lister and David Starobinski College of Engineering, Boston University, Boston, MA 02215 Abstract We analyze the dynamics

More information

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results *

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results * Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results * Xavier Cuadras-Morató Department of Economics Universitat Pompeu Fabra Ramon Trias Fargas, 25-27 08005 BRCELON e-mail: xavier.cuadras@econ.upf.es

More information

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013 ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013 David S. Evans University of Chicago, Global Economics Group Elisa Mariscal CIDE, ITAM, CPI TOPIC 6: MARKET FAILURES, REMEDIES, AND WELFARE Date Topic 6 Part 1 2 May 2013 2 Overview

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman Working Paper 11407 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11407 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup Theory Appendix In this appendix, we provide a stylized model based on our empirical setting to analyze the effect of competition on author behavior. The general idea is that in a market with imperfect

More information

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity Countervailing Power and Product Diversity by Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Work in Progress December 6, 2003 Abstract To analyse the effects of countervailing power on product variety, I construct a

More information

THE EFFECT OF MARKET AND INTERNAL FAILURES ON CAPABILITY SOURCING CHOICES. LAURENCE CAPRON INSEAD, France

THE EFFECT OF MARKET AND INTERNAL FAILURES ON CAPABILITY SOURCING CHOICES. LAURENCE CAPRON INSEAD, France THE EFFECT OF MARKET AND INTERNAL FAILURES ON CAPABILITY SOURCING CHOICES LAURENCE CAPRON INSEAD, France WILL MITCHELL The Fuqua School of Business, Duke University INTRODUCTION Where do firms obtain new

More information

Information and the Coase Theorem. Joseph Farrell. "The Journal of Economic Perspectives," Vol. 1, No. 2 (Autumn, 1987), pp.

Information and the Coase Theorem. Joseph Farrell. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 1, No. 2 (Autumn, 1987), pp. Joseph Farrell. "The Journal of Economic Perspectives," Vol. 1, No. 2 (Autumn, 1987), pp. 113-129 Introduction On rst acquaintance, the Coase theorem seems much more robust. Like the welfare theorem, it

More information

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms A Glossary of Terms The Digital Economist -A- Abundance--A physical or economic condition where the quantity available of a resource exceeds the quantity desired in the absence of a rationing system. Arbitrage

More information

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement Hideo Konishi Michael T. Sandfort June 21, 2001 Abstract Retail stores frequently advertise prices. When consumer search is costly, advertising low prices expands

More information

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit by Robin Boadway, Queen s University, Canada Zhen Song, Central University of Finance and Economics, China Jean-François Tremblay,

More information

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence Learning Objectives: Students should learn to: 1. Define and give examples of predatory conduct. 2. Explain stylized facts about the entry of firms into industries.

More information

THE EFFECT OF MARKET AND INTERNAL FAILURES ON CAPABILITY SOURCING CHOICES. LAURENCE CAPRON INSEAD, France

THE EFFECT OF MARKET AND INTERNAL FAILURES ON CAPABILITY SOURCING CHOICES. LAURENCE CAPRON INSEAD, France THE EFFECT OF MARKET AND INTERNAL FAILURES ON CAPABILITY SOURCING CHOICES LAURENCE CAPRON INSEAD, France WILL MITCHELL The Fuqua School of Business, Duke University INTRODUCTION Where do firms obtain new

More information

Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction

Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction David McAdams September 23, 20 Abstract Suppose bidders may publicly choose not to learn their values prior to a second-price auction with costly bidding.

More information

Exclusive dealing with network effects

Exclusive dealing with network effects Exclusive dealing with network effects Toker Doganoglu Julian Wright Abstract This paper explores the ability of an incumbent to use exclusive deals or introductory offers to dominate a market in the face

More information

Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty

Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty Yu-Hung Chen and Baojun Jiang January 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model to examine how a firm with a new, non-durable

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Session 7: Concentration, Mergers, and Entry Barriers Jiangli Dou School of Economics Jiangli Dou (School of Economics) Industrial Organization 1 / 100 Introduction The study of

More information

Title: Transferring service operations to the customer: an outsourcing perspective.

Title: Transferring service operations to the customer: an outsourcing perspective. POMS, College of Service Operations Conference July 2007 Student paper Title: Transferring service operations to the customer: an outsourcing perspective. Marlene Amorim, PhD Student docmcastro@iese.edu

More information

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) Public Economics by Luca Spataro Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) 1 Introduction Connection between agents outside the price system The level of externality

More information

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition by Joshua S. Gans and Stephen P. King University of Melbourne 0 th March, 000 This paper demonstrates that low (below marginal

More information

Outsourcing Internet Security: The Effect of Transaction Costs on Managed Service Providers

Outsourcing Internet Security: The Effect of Transaction Costs on Managed Service Providers Outsourcing Internet Security: The Effect of Transaction Costs on Managed Service Providers Abstract Wen Ding William Yurcik National Center for Supercomputing Applications (NCSA) University of Illinois

More information

Network Interconnection with Participation Constraints

Network Interconnection with Participation Constraints Network Interconnection with Participation Constraints Stephen Poletti a,,julian Wright b a Department of Economics, University of Auckland, Private Bag 9019, Auckland, New Zealand b Department of Economics,

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming Market mechanisms and stochastic programming Kjetil K. Haugen and Stein W. Wallace Molde University College, Servicebox 8, N-6405 Molde, Norway E-mail: Kjetil.Haugen/Stein.W.Wallace@himolde.no 18.12.01

More information

Competition, Disclosure and Signaling.

Competition, Disclosure and Signaling. Competition, Disclosure and Signaling. Maarten C.W. Janssen University of Vienna, Austria. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. December 6, 2012 Abstract Competition creates strategic

More information

Competing Payment Schemes

Competing Payment Schemes Competing Payment Schemes Graeme Guthrie and Julian Wright Victoria University of Wellington and National University of Singapore September 9, 2003 Abstract This paper presents a model of competing payment

More information

Mixed Duopoly Under Vertical Differentiation

Mixed Duopoly Under Vertical Differentiation ANNALES D ÉCONOMIE ET DE STATISTIQUE. N 33 1994 Mixed Duopoly Under Vertical Differentiation Isabel GRILO* ABSTRACT. In this paper we study a vertically differentiated duopoly market with a profit maximizing

More information

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth. Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine April 4, 2007

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth. Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine April 4, 2007 Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine April 4, 2007 The Conventional View innovation along quality ladder, driven by short-term monopoly power fixed costs

More information

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley 1 Overview of the Course This is a readings course. The lectures

More information

2 Theoretical background

2 Theoretical background 2 Theoretical background 2.1 Theoretical framework: New Institutional Economics The analysis of businesses between actors based in unstable institutional setups demands a theoretical basis that takes the

More information

HOW MUCH TO MAKE AND HOW MUCH TO BUY? AN ANALYSIS OF PLURAL SOURCING STRATEGIES

HOW MUCH TO MAKE AND HOW MUCH TO BUY? AN ANALYSIS OF PLURAL SOURCING STRATEGIES HOW MUCH TO MAKE AND HOW MUCH TO BUY? AN ANALYSIS OF PLURAL SOURCING STRATEGIES Phanish Puranam 1 London Business School University of London ppuranam@london.edu Ranjay Gulati Harvard Business School Harvard

More information

STRATEGIC OUTSOURCING WITH TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER

STRATEGIC OUTSOURCING WITH TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER CDE August 0 STRATEGIC OUTSOURCING WITH TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER TARUN KABIRAJ Email: tarunkabiraj@hotmail.com Economic Research Unit Indian Statistical Institute 0 B. T. Road, Kolkata UDAY BHANU SINHA Email:

More information

Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center

Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center Journal of Logistics Management 017, 6(): 35-40 DOI: 10.593/j.logistics.017060.01 Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center Aika Monden Graduate School of

More information

Matching Markets with Endogenous Information

Matching Markets with Endogenous Information Matching Markets with Endogenous Information Tracy Lewis Duke University Li, Hao University of British Columbia Matching Problems in Chicago 2012 Lewis and Li Endogenous Matching 1 Introduction: Motivation

More information

Privacy, Information Acquisition, and Market Competition

Privacy, Information Acquisition, and Market Competition Privacy, Information Acquisition, and Market Competition Soo Jin Kim Michigan State University May 2017 1 / 19 Background - Facebook Ad Targeting Example 2 / 19 Background - Facebook Ad Targeting Example

More information

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik)

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik) BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik) Why advertise? Building brands Creating markets for new products (scope economies) Price competition / Price protection Barrier to entry Product

More information

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects Peter M. Kort, Pauli Murto, and Grzegorz Pawlina April 25, 2005 Preliminary and incomplete. Please do not quote. Abstract This paper is about

More information

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 27, 2006 Answer four of the six

More information

A Managerial Decision Tool for R&D Outsourcing and Partner Selection in High-Technology Industries

A Managerial Decision Tool for R&D Outsourcing and Partner Selection in High-Technology Industries A Managerial Decision Tool for R&D Outsourcing and Partner Selection in High-Technology Industries Our own R&D relies quite heavily on long-term relationships with competent R&D suppliers. However, we

More information

First-Price Auctions with General Information Structures: A Short Introduction

First-Price Auctions with General Information Structures: A Short Introduction First-Price Auctions with General Information Structures: A Short Introduction DIRK BERGEMANN Yale University and BENJAMIN BROOKS University of Chicago and STEPHEN MORRIS Princeton University We explore

More information

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly Lin Liu Marshal School of Management University of Southern California X. Henry Wang Department of Economics University of Missouri-Columbia and Bill

More information

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo Abstract I introduce uncertainty into the model of strategic cost reducing R and D investments

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia February 15, 2014 Abstract We analyze two unexplored aspects of the Wolinsky model (Wolinsky (1986)

More information

OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS. Golovko Sergiy

OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS. Golovko Sergiy OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS by Golovko Sergiy A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MA in Economics Kyiv School of Economics

More information

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Abstract. Revenue management (RM) is the art and science of predicting consumer behavior and optimizing price and product availability to maximize

More information

Ownership Structure and Productivity of Vertical Research Collaboration

Ownership Structure and Productivity of Vertical Research Collaboration RIETI Discussion Paper Series 10-E-064 Ownership Structure and Productivity of Vertical Research Collaboration NAGAOKA Sadao RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Reputation and Performance

Reputation and Performance Reputation and Performance Armin Falk, Ernst Fehr and Christian Zehnder 1 University of Zürich February 2004 - Very preliminary - Please do not circulate Abstract In this paper we provide experimental

More information

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Julian Wright Abstract In a recent paper, Chiara Fumagalli and Massimo Motta (2006) challenge the idea that an incumbent can foreclose efficient

More information

Centre for Development Economics

Centre for Development Economics CDE April, 2004 Networks, Network Externalities and Market Segmentation A. Banerji Delhi School of Economics Email: a.banerji@econdse.org Bhaskar Dutta University of Warwick Email: B.Dutta@warwick.ac.uk

More information

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction 1 Intermediate Microeconomics W3211 Lecture 25: Recap 2 Introduction Columbia University, Spring 2016 Mark Dean: mark.dean@columbia.edu 2 The Story So Far. 3 The Story So Far. 4 Topic Topic 1 The Consumer

More information

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22 Monopoly. Principles of Microeconomics, Fall Chia-Hui Chen November, Lecture Monopoly Outline. Chap : Monopoly. Chap : Shift in Demand and Effect of Tax Monopoly The monopolist is the single supply-side

More information

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Lisa Planer-Friedrich Otto-Friedrich-Universität Bamberg Marco Sahm Otto-Friedrich-Universität Bamberg and CESifo This Version: June 15, 2015 Abstract We examine

More information

Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion

Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion Aim of this lecture (1) To understand the idea of repeated game. (2) To understand the idea of the stability of collusion. Oligopoly Theory 1 Outline of the 11th Lecture

More information

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Thomas D. Jeitschko and Mark J. Tremblay Prepared for IIOC 2014: Not Intended for Circulation March 27, 2014 Abstract In this paper we investigate

More information

Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices

Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices Luís Cabral New York University and CEPR October 2008 Abstract I argue that the numerical result obtained by Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) is fairly general:

More information

Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition

Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition Nicolas Boccard & Xavier Wauthy April 2003 Abstract A regulator imposing sales restrictions on firms competing in oligopolistic markets

More information

Exclusion by a manufacturer without a first-mover advantage

Exclusion by a manufacturer without a first-mover advantage Exclusion by a manufacturer without a first-mover advantage Bo Shen Jan, 2014 Abstract The existing literature on naked exclusion argues that exclusive contracts can be used by an incumbent firm to anti-competitively

More information