Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics"

Transcription

1 Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics (see Chapter 5 of the textbook: erman, Ma, McGilvray, Common) - the starting point of most economic analysis is the neoclassical general equilibrium theory - this is the benchmark against which economists usually compare any types of inefficiency or market failure, e.g. related to imperfect competition or monopoly, incomplete information, or public good problems and externalities (e.g. related to environmental issues) - the nice thing about perfect competition in the neoclassical framework is, that it leads to areto efficiency, hence, a situation where nobody can be made better off unless somebody else is made worse off ( First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics ) - this is also a situation that society may want to achieve, because if somebody can be made better off without making someone else worse off, the social well-being can unambiguously be improved, hence, the original allocation was clearly not the best possible outcome - unfortunately, a areto efficient allocation can be very unfair, e.g. if some individuals are particularly poor and others rich - the problem is that areto efficiency alone says nothing about equity - to udge which of the many (in fact infinitely many) areto efficient allocations is optimal (the most desirable one from a social point of view), society (or philosophers) must come up with some definition of social welfare - whatever this definition might be, another nice thing about the neoclassical theory is, that it predicts that the resulting socially optimal allocation (one specific allocation among the continuum of areto efficient allocations) can always be achieved under market conditions, when the government uses lump-sum taxes and transfers to redistribute wealth - this is a result of the Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics, which states that to every areto efficient allocation, there corresponds a competitive market equilibrium, obtained under a particular distribution of initial endowments and, thus, wealth ( wealth is the value of a consumer s initial endowment, evaluated at market prices) - what do we learn from this? : if the assumptions of the neoclassical theory are (approximately) fulfilled, then the government must do only two things to maximize social welfare: 1. make sure that perfect competition prevails in all markets (hence, establish a functioning market economy): this assures areto efficiency, and 2. redistribute wealth for equity reasons to achieve not only economic efficiency, but also social optimality - to put this in other words: theory suggests that, in policy analysis, problems of efficiency and equity can be dealt with independently - furthermore, whenever economists think that there is a problem (e.g. global warming), it should be possible to identify one or several market failures; the assumptions of the 8

2 neoclassical theory are, then, violated; otherwise, there would be no problem, and perfect competition would automatically lead to an efficient allocation - hence, in this course on environmental economics, we will often try to identify or characterize the reasons why an unregulated market economy does not lead to efficiency (environmental externalities are one possible source of market failure, but there are many others) - furthermore, we will try to find out how a regulator can correct for these market failures, in order to achieve an efficient or optimal outcome, e.g. by using taxes - remember: if there is no market failure, then there is no reason why the government should do anything (except redistributing wealth for equity reasons); therefore, as economists, we need to identify sources of market failure in order to ustify a policy intervention 1.1 Welfare economics and efficiency in the static framework* - let us review the conditions of efficiency in a static framework (many of these things may be familiar to you) - suppose, there are only two individuals in our model economy ( and ), two goods or services (consumption quantities and ), and two inputs or resources and (think e.g. of capital and labor) that exist in fixed quantities (this is the endowment of the economy) - we assume away any externalities (hence, consumption or production of a good has no positive or negative side-effects on other consumers or firms) - and we assume that all goods are private (not public), hence, if somebody owns a commodity (has property rights over it), nobody else can consume it or use it for production - suppose, preferences over bundles of goods can be represented by utility functions: U = U (, ), U = U (, ) - if the output quantity depends only on the input quantities used in the production of this output ( and ), and similarly for output, the technological possibilities can be expressed by the following production functions (assuming efficient production): = (, ), ( =, ) - when there are several firms, we may assume that all firms have the same technology; however, here, we look at efficiency at a more abstract level, and do not discuss any specific institutional arrangements (such as the existence of firms or markets) - let MU / = U be s marginal utility from consumption of good (similarly for good, and for consumer...) - let M = / be the marginal product of the input in production of good 9

3 - let MRUS be consumer s marginal rate of utility substitution (the rate at which can be substituted for at the margin), given that s utility remains constant - to compute it, totally differentiate the utility function: U (, ) U (...) du = d + d = MU d + MU d - set this equal to 0 since utility is held constant (we move along an indifference curve), to get: MRUS d MU = = d MU - this is the slope of s indifference curve at the location (, ) (hence, constant but depends on the location in the - space) MRUS is not a - let MRTS be the marginal rate of technical substitution in the production of (the rate at which can be substituted for at the margin), given that the output quantity remains constant - totally differentiate the production function ( =, ) to get: (, ) (...) d = d + d = M d + M d - set this equal to 0 since the output is held constant (we move along an isoquant), to get: MRTS d M = = d M - this is the slope of the isoquant at the location (, ) (an isoquant connects all input combinations that yield a fixed output quantity ) - let MRT be the marginal rate of transformation of labor for the commodities and : this is the rate at which the output of one commodity can be transformed into the other by marginally shifting labor from one line of production to the other - hence, MRT is the increase in the output by shifting a marginal amount of labor from use in the production of to use in the production of - overall, the marginal rate of transformation (MRT) states the rate at which the output of one commodity () can be transformed into the other () by shifting both inputs in an efficient way; using the production functions ( =, ) and ( =, ), it can be written as (use the total differentials d and d ) : 10

4 MRT d + d = = = d M d + M d d d + d M d + M d - note, that since and are fixed, we have d = d and d = d - when and are constant (we now shift only labor from use in production of to ), the above formula simplifies to (similarly for MRT ): MRT d M = = = d M - the marginal rate of transformation is the slope of the production possibility frontier (combinations of and that the economy can generate with the given endowments) Utility: U U MRUS Consumption bundles: Output quantities: MRT MRTS Input mix: Endowment of the economy: - with these definitions, we can formally state the requirements for areto optimal allocations - there are three requirements: 1. efficiency in consumption, 2. efficiency in production, and 3. product mix efficiency 1.) Efficiency in consumption: MRUS = MRUS 11

5 - when the marginal rates of utility substitution are equal for the two individuals and, it is not possible to rearrange the allocation of the (given) output quantities and between them, so as to make one consumer better off without making the other one worse off - hence, there is no more scope for voluntary trade - MRUS = MRUS implies that the consumers indifference curves are tangent: U b U a - position a in the above Edgeworth-box indicates some initial allocation of and among the consumers, and position b is a areto efficient allocation after (voluntary) exchange took place (under market conditions, the connecting line between the dots represents the consumers budget lines, and the slope is the (negative) of the price ratio; however, we do not assume any market mechanism here, so the line is only for illustrative purposes) 2.) Efficiency in production: MRTS = MRTS - when the marginal rates of technical substitution are equal for both commodities and, it is not possible to reallocate inputs to production so as to produce more output of one commodity, without producing less of the other (otherwise production would be inefficient) - MRTS MRTS = implies that the isoquants for and are tangent: b a a b 12

6 - compare position a and b in the above box; each of them shows a different use of the (fixed amount of) input factors capital and labor ( and ) in the production of the two outputs and ; in position a, more capital is used in the production of instead of, and more labor in the production of than - however, the allocation of capital and labor in a is inefficient; moving along the isoquant, the output quantity remains constant; however, as we see in the figure, we move from the isoquant a to the isoquant b, that corresponds to a higher output quantity ; hence, the allocation of the input factors and in point a is inefficient, that in point b is efficient - note, however, that this condition is not sufficient to reach full efficiency in the economy; it only assures that any (given) output quantities and are produced efficiently with the inputs - but there is a whole continuum of efficient points (such as point b in the figure), each of which implying a different combination of the output quantities and ; these combinations of and are called production possibility frontier (output combinations that the economy can produce with its available resources) - to reach full economic efficiency, one must determine which point on the production possibility frontier yields the highest utility; therefore, we need one more efficiency condition 3.) roduct-mix efficiency: = = = MRT MRT MRUS MRUS - when the marginal rates of utility substitution are equal for the two individuals: MRUS = MRUS, we can imagine for the moment that both individuals have the same utility function (this is of course not correct, but given that MRUS = MRUS holds, the corresponding indifference curves have the same slope, and this is what really matters) - hence, think for the moment of a representative consumer, so we will only plot one indifference curve - to the same plot, we add the production possibility frontier: a b U roduction possibility frontier 13

7 - consider allocation a; it is located on the production possibility frontier, hence, the inputs and are used efficiently in the production of the output quantities and - however, by producing more and less (moving towards allocation b), the representative consumer reaches a higher utility level - at the point of tangency between the production possibility frontier and the indifference curve U (point b), the representative consumer s utility is maximized, given the available resources in the economy - the slope of the production possibility frontier is the marginal rate of transformation (note, that at an efficient allocation, it holds that MRT = MRT = MRT ) - an economy attains a fully efficient static allocation of resources if all three of the above conditions are satisfied simultaneously; the output levels and, then, maximize the representative consumer s utility, given the available resources of the economy - these results generalize to economies with many inputs, many goods, and many individuals; for any pairwise combination of individuals, goods and inputs, the above conditions must, then, hold 14

8 1.2 Efficiency and optimality in the static framework* - we characterized conditions that must hold for economic efficiency of an allocation - if a given allocation is not efficient, this means that we can (by reallocating resources) make at least one consumer better off, without making any other consumer worse off - however, these efficiency conditions do not determine a unique allocation - there is a continuum of efficient allocations, and it is a matter of fairness or social preferences which of these efficient allocations is socially desirable; the most desirable allocation is referred to as the social optimum - before we discuss how the optimum can be defined, let us illustrate why there is a continuum of efficient allocations - suppose first that the output quantities and are fixed - they can be allocated in a variety of different ways between the individuals and - the efficient allocations satisfy MRUS = MRUS and are located on the contract curve : contract curve - similarly, in the production of the two outputs, there is not ust a single allocation of capital and labor in the two lines of production that is efficient and, hence, satisfies MRTS = MRTS, but a whole continuum of efficient allocations - hence, there are many combinations of and that are efficient in production, and for any particular combination, there are many allocations between and that are consistent with allocative efficiency - intuitively, the entire stock of resources could be used only for individual, while individual gets nothing; efficiency, then, still requires that some efficient combination of and is produced, and this also requires an efficient allocation of capital and labor in the 15

9 production of and ; let U max be s resulting utility, and suppose, s utility in this case is zero - alternatively, the entire stock of resources could be used only for individual, while gets nothing; let U be s resulting utility under efficiency, and suppose, s utility is zero max - in between these two extreme cases, there is a continuum of other efficient allocations that yield positive utility to both consumers - the resulting frontier in the utility-space is called the utility possibility frontier : U U max Social welfare indifference curve Social optimum Utility possibility frontier U max U - the utility possibility frontier represents all utility levels areto efficiency U and U that are consistent with - however, some of the allocations on this frontier assign a high utility level to one individual, and a low one to the other - until now, we do not know which one is the social optimum (the best allocation among all areto efficient allocations from a social point of view), because to determine this, we must be able to make interpersonal comparisons - to this end, a social welfare function may be defined, that permits a ranking of alternative allocations: W = W ( U, U ) - this function formalizes how society values utility of different individuals - two extreme cases are: min { W U, U } individuals, or W = U + U =, which requires equal utility levels for all - similarly as a utility function, also the social welfare function can be depicted using indifference curves (see the dotted line in the above figure) - optimality requires that, in addition to the above efficiency conditions, the following optimality condition holds (a formal derivation or explanation is omitted): 16

10 W / U MU MU = = W / U MU MU - unfortunately, there exists no widely agreed upon specification of a social welfare function - this is ultimately an ethical or cultural issue - therefore, economists usually avoid this, and try to focus on efficiency issues; if there is a policy of reallocation, the economist usually focuses on the question whether the gains exceed the losses; if they do, the policy can be recommended on efficiency grounds, since (in theory) the beneficiaries of the policy can compensate the losers - it is a separate matter for government to decide whether compensation should actually occur 1.3 llocation in a market economy (given ideal conditions)* - the ideal conditions under which a market economy leads to a areto optimal allocation (First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics) are: markets exist for all goods and services, there is perfect competition (price-taking behavior), perfect information, private property rights are assigned over all resources and commodities, there are no externalities, no public goods, and utility and production functions are well-behaved (preferences and technologies are convex) - here, we do not go through all the details of the neoclassical general equilibrium model; we only briefly illustrate why the equilibrium conditions in a market economy coincide with the above efficiency conditions of welfare economics - as you should know from other classes, utility maximization implies that the slope of the indifference curve in the consumer s optimum equals the slope of the budget line: optimal bundle U (indifference curve) budget line - the slope of the budget line is the negative of the price ratio / (the rate at which good can be substituted for good at a constant expenditure hence, the opportunity cost of consuming one more unit of one good, measured in units of the forgone consumption of the other good) 17

11 - this holds for all consumers, since all face the same prices in a market economy; hence: MRUS = MRUS = - comparison with our earlier results shows that the consumption efficiency condition is, thus, fulfilled under market conditions - now consider a firm that minimizes its production costs (given a target output quantity of ) - cost minimization requires that the slope of the isocost-line equals the slope of the isoquant at the optimum: optimal input mix to produce (isoquant) isocost line - the slope of the isoquant is the marginal rate of technical substitution, and the slope of the isocost line is / (the negative of the input price ratio) - this holds for all firms and commodities produced, hence: MRTS = MRTS = - therefore, the production efficiency condition we saw earlier is fulfilled - now consider the choice of the target output quantity - in choosing the optimal amount of the input labor, a firm compares the benefits of a marginal increase in with the resulting additional costs - the benefit is the marginal product of labor (hence, the additional output of ) times the output price : M - the marginal cost is the price of labor, hence - profit maximization requires that labor is used until the point where the marginal benefit of an increase in labor equals the marginal cost, hence: 18

12 M = - this holds also for capital, and also in the production of good, hence: M =, M =, M =, M = - eliminating the prices of capital and labor, we obtain: M = and M M =, hence: MRT = MRT = M - combined with the condition MRUS = MRUS =, this implies that the profitmaximizing output levels under market conditions satisfy the product mix efficiency condition - this completes the demonstration that in an ideal market system, the necessary conditions for allocative efficiency are satisfied - combined with the Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics, we, thus, learn that a social optimum can always be implemented in such an ideal market economy by simply redistributing the initial endowments or wealth 1.4 artial equilibrium approach - the above results reflect a general equilibrium approach (for illustrative purposes shown for two consumers, two commodities, and two inputs/resources) - in general, there are many consumers, commodities, and resources, but we may only be interested in one particular market (e.g. the market for electricity) - to reduce the complexity of the analysis, economists often aggregate all other goods (except the good of interest) into a combined commodity - the good of interest may, thus, be good, and the combined commodity (all other goods) be good - if a consumer s expenditure on good is small relative to the expenditure on all other goods (good ), saturation effects (declining marginal utility of good ) will typically be small when the consumer increases or reduces its consumption of good - hence, we may assume that a consumer s utility is (approximately) linear in ; we, thus, obtain quasi-linear utility functions of the type:, where U (, ) = U ( ) + U denotes the utility function used in the partial equilibrium model 19

13 - the price of the combined good is normalized to 1 (numeraire good, or simply money ) MU - the condition of tangency for utility maximization reads: = MU - since = 1 and MU = 1, this simplifies to (in the following, we simply use for ): ( ) = MU ( ) = MU ( ) the price of good equals its marginal utility (this holds for all consumers) - note, that demand for good depends only upon, but not on the consumer s income the market for good can effectively be analyzed separately (there are no income effects) - assuming a representative consumer, ( ) is the inverse market demand function - the above condition then implies that the inverse demand curve of a good is simply the MUcurve - now define consumer surplus (CS) as the willingness-to-pay for units minus the expenditure - the willingness to pay for units is given by the area under the inverse demand curve, and the expenditure for good is, a rectangle in a price-quantity diagram: inverse demand curve ( ) CS - a similar interpretation can be given to a supply curve in a partial equilibrium model - profit maximization for a given cost function requires: max π ( ) = C( ) (the cost function C() is derived by solving the firm s cost minimization problem, given the input prices and ; it contains essentially the same information as that which is embedded in the production function) - FOC: ( ) = MC( ) : each firm chooses its output quantity such that price equals marginal cost - here, ( ) is the inverse supply function 20

14 - the inverse supply curve, thus, coincides with the MC-curve - solving for, we obtain the firm s supply function; aggregating over all firms in this market, we get the market supply curve - the market clearing price is the price that equates demand and supply: D S - remember, that the inverse demand curve (D) reflects the marginal utility of the representative consumer, hence, the marginal benefit of an increase in - the inverse supply curve (S) reflects the marginal cost of an increase in - hence, the point where demand and supply are equal, is also the point where the marginal benefit of an increase in is equal to the marginal cost: MU = MC= - the net benefit is defined as the total benefit minus the total cost; it corresponds to the shaded area in the above figure (interpretation of the net benefit: it is the utility given the efficient provision of the good, net of the utility when good is not produced at all: =0) - if we assume that all other markets are perfectly competitive, but the quantity (that may be a consumption good, or a bad such as pollution) is chosen by the regulator (a benevolent social planner or the government), then the curves S and D in the above figure can be reinterpreted as marginal benefit function and marginal cost function (resp. marginal damage function depending on the problem) 21

15 Section 2: Market failure, public goods, externalities 2.1 Market failure, public goods (see Chapter 5 of the textbook) - we already mentioned conditions that must hold in an ideal market economy, under which the market outcome coincides with the allocation that a social planner would choose, hence, the social optimum - if any of these conditions is not fulfilled, the market outcome will be inefficient, and we say there is a market failure ; let us summarize these ideal conditions: 1. Markets exist for all goods and services produced and consumed 2. ll markets are perfectly competitive 3. ll transactors have perfect information 4. rivate property rights are fully assigned in all resources and commodities 5. No externalities exist 6. ll goods and services are private goods (there are no public goods ) 7. ll utility and production functions are well-behaved 8. ll agents are maximizers (utility/profit maximizers). - let us discuss a few examples where one or several of the above conditions are violated - e.g., private property rights often do not exist for renewable resources - an example is ocean fishery; if anyone can go out an fish, the exploitation of this resource is uncontrolled, and there will generally be over-exploitation - another example are stock-pollution problems, where the earth or the atmosphere is used as a waste sink, e.g. for carbon dioxide - generally, no private property rights are assigned, so the atmosphere is an open-access resource; note, that air pollution causes a negative externality - an important distinction that is often made in the literature is between private and public goods - private goods are characterized by rivalry and excludability - rivalry refers to whether one agent s consumption is at the expense of another agent s consumption (think, e.g., of ice cream) - excludability refers to whether agents can be prevented from consuming - a pure public good is e.g. national defense; no citizen can be excluded from enoying the benefits of it, and the consumption is clearly non-rival - some public goods are non-rival, but excludable; they are usually referred to as congestible resources ; an example are wilderness areas; enoying wilderness by one individual is 22

16 generally not at the expense of another agent s oy (unless it is used to such an extent that congestion occurs); however, using fences, individuals can be excluded from consumption - other public goods are rival in consumption, but non-excludable; they are usually referred to as open-access resources ; an example is the ocean-fishery; consumption is rival, because each fish can only be caught once, so the more boats are fishing, the harder it gets to fish; however, it is difficult to exclude anyone from fishing - let us now analyze the efficient allocation of a public good formally - to this end, we go back to our earlier model-economy with two consumers ( and ), and two goods ( and ) - the top-level product-mix condition for allocative efficiency was given by: MRUS = MRUS = MRT - intuitively, MRT describes how (given an efficient use of the inputs to production) good can be transformed into good, and vice versa; MRT, thus, describes how costly the production of good is in terms of forgone output of good - MRUS describes at what rate a consumer would exchange good for good, given that the consumer s utility remains unchanged; MRUS, thus, describes how valuable the consumption of good is in terms of forgone consumption of good - efficiency requires that these relative benefits / costs must be equal at the margin; otherwise, production or consumption of one of the goods may be raised, and the consumer who becomes better off can compensate the consumer who gets worse off such that both consumers benefit from the voluntary exchange (hence, a areto improvement is possible) - now suppose, is a public good, and a private good; this means that consumers do no longer care about their individual consumption of good, but only about the aggregate consumption: = + - hence, the utility functions are given by: U = U (, ), U = U (, ), where = + - it can be shown that in this case, the above top-level efficiency condition becomes: MRUS + MRUS = MRT - intuitively, this means that for efficiency, not the individual marginal benefit of consumption of good matters, but the aggregated marginal benefit of all consumers; in general, this implies that more of good will be provided in the optimum than under market conditions (the market provides to little of the public good the reverse holds true if is a public bad, such as pollution) The derivation and interpretation of the above efficiency condition is easier in the context of a partial equilibrium model; let us go through the details: 23

17 - in a partial equilibrium model, the utility functions are quasi-linear, and can be written as (the superscript stands for artial equilibrium model):, U = U ( ) +, U = U ( ) +, - let = f ( ) be the production possibility frontier (combinations of and that the economy can generate, given an efficient use of the available resources) - to determine the efficiency condition, set up the agrangian, - the target function is U, s utility, while s utility is held constant (this reflects the idea of areto efficiency: maximize s utility, without making worse off) - the technological constraint is = + = f ( ) ; for simplicity, we substitute for using this constraint, to obtain: - the first-order conditions (FOC) are: ( ) = U ( ) + λ U ( ) + ( f ( ) ) U,, 0 = MU λmu λ f '( ) and 0= 1+ λ d - using f '( ) = = MRT, and λ= 1 (second condition), the first condition becomes: d MU + MU = MRT - MRT is the slope of the production possibility frontier (note, that it is negative): ($) f (0), f ( ) roduction possiblily frontier - it is convenient to rewrite MRT as a cost function - note, that is the numeraire good, hence, its price is 1, and can be interpreted as money - the cost of good in terms of forgone production of good is, thus, simply f (0) (all resources are used to produce only good ) minus f ( ) (the quantity of good when units of the public good are produced); hence, the cost function is given by: 24

18 - this yields for the marginal cost of : C( ) = f (0) f ( ) MC( ) = f '( ) = MRT - the marginal cost of good in terms of good is, thus, the absolute value of the marginal rate of transformation - the above first-order condition can, thus, be rewritten as follows (this is the partial equilibrium version of the top-level product-mix efficiency condition): MU + MU = MC - this means that the public good should be provided to the point where the aggregated marginal utility equals the marginal cost; since the marginal utility corresponds to the marginal willingness-to-pay, we can also say this as follows: supply the public good at the level where aggregate marginal willingness-to-pay is equal to marginal cost - under market conditions, the inverse demand functions of consumers and are given by: ( ) = MU and ( ) = MU - if consumer has a higher willingness-to-pay, this looks as follows: MU + MU MC MU MU - under market conditions, only consumer (the one with the higher willingness-to-pay) will pay for the public good, and it is supplied up to the point where s individual marginal utility equals the marginal cost of the public good; consumer does not pay anything for the public good; because it is non-rival and not excludable, this consumer can nevertheless enoy the same quantity of the public good as consumer - under efficiency, the public good is provided until the point where the aggregated marginal willingness-to-pay MU + MU equals the marginal cost, hence, a higher quantity is provided than under market conditions (this illustrates the existence of a market failure) 25

19 2.2 Externalities - an externality (external effect) occurs when the production or consumption decisions of one agent have an impact on the utility or profit of another agent in an unintended way, and when no compensation is made by the generator of the impact - externalities can be classified according to whether they arise during production processes or during consumption (e.g. smoking), and whether they affect firms or other consumers utility / consumption - externalities can be harmful (negative) or beneficial (positive) to the affected agents - an example of a positive externality is knowledge generated via R&D by one firm, that partially leaks to other firms and, thus, positively affects their productivity (knowledgespillovers) - externalities are a source of market failure; in the presence of a negative externality (e.g. pollution), the good or by-product is oversupplied; in the presence of a positive externality (e.g. knowledge spillovers), private agents face insufficient incentives to generate the good because they can not fully appropriate the rents, so it tends to be undersupplied under market conditions - consider for example a situation where some agent s activity generates an external effect (e.g. a firm that pollutes the environment, or a smoker) - let the agent s marginal benefit (e.g. marginal profit in case of a firm) be M(Z) if Z is the level of the activity that causes the externality, and let the marginal external cost to society or to some other individual be MEC(Z); the situation is illustrated in the following figure: ($) MEC(Z) M( Z ) Z - if the external costs are not taken into consideration (market outcome without policy intervention), the polluter chooses Z until the point where the private marginal benefit goes to zero; depending on the shape of the M-curve, this can be a very high quantity - if the external costs are taken into consideration (e.g. because of government intervention, or when private property rights can be assigned to the environment), hence, when the 26

20 externality is internalized in the polluter s decision-making, the efficient activity level is reached, located at the point where the marginal benefit equals the marginal external costs The Coase Theorem: - the problem that arises in the presence of external costs or benefits is that the involved individuals and firms do not own property rights over the polluted environment (e.g. the clean air in case of a smoker), or can not fully appropriate the rents generated by their R&D activities (knowledge spillovers) - suppose, it is possible to assign such property rights (to pollute the air, or property rights over clean air, over knowledge and ideas ) - the Coase theorem (Coase, 1960) states that, when property rights are assigned, individuals can bargain over the amount of pollution or other activity causing the externality, and the outcome of this bargaining process will be areto efficient, irrespective of the initial allocation of the property rights - hence, in a shared flat with one smoker and one non-smoker, the outcome of the bargaining process will be areto efficient, no matter whether rights of clean air are assigned to the nonsmoker, or whether rights to pollute are assigned to the smoker - note, however, that since a continuum of areto efficient allocations exists in a general equilibrium framework, nothing is said about which areto efficient allocation will be reached, and whether it is the socially optimal one; hence, although both cases lead to economic efficiency, the initial allocation of property rights can affect the resulting allocation via wealth effects - in a artial equilibrium framework (as in the above figure), the amount of pollution will, however, not depend on the initial allocation of property rights, because there are no income effects; the agent who gets the property rights benefits from a higher wealth, but this only leads to a higher consumption of the numeraire good (the location of the M and the MEC curves are independent of the initial endowments or wealth of the individuals) - this argument can also be applied to the issue of the initial allocation of emission certificates in a cap-and-trade scheme (grandfathering versus auctioning); we will come back to this issue later in this course - finally consider an example where the pollution is also costly to the polluter; e.g., if we discuss CO2-emissions that result from productive activities, then the costs to the firm are clearly correlated with the emissions (more output more pollution) - hence, in contrast to the above figure, we may distinguish between private marginal costs of some activity Z (that causes an externality), and social marginal costs (obtained when the external costs are added to the private costs of the activity Z): 27

21 ($) SMC(Z) = MC+MEC MC(Z) Z - if the polluter is a competitive firm, Z is the output, and the output price is, the firm will produce until the point where MC equals the output price (MC = ) - however, efficiency requires that the firm produces until the social marginal cost equals - to achieve this, the regulator can introduce a tax on the activity Z equal to the marginal external cost (t = MEC) - such a tax is often referred to as a igouvian tax, because it leads to an internalization of the external effect; the igouvian tax leads to areto efficiency - as a final note, consider situations that are characterized by multiple market failures (hence, more than ust one of the above conditions for an ideal market economy is violated) - it may sometimes be possible to correct some of these inefficiencies, but not all of them - in that case, it is not necessarily in the interest of society to correct the inefficiencies that can be corrected, given that others can not be corrected - sometimes, different market failures can distort the outcome in reverse directions (e.g. an environmental externality can imply too much economic activity, while knowledge spillovers can imply too little) - hence, when only one market failure is corrected, the outcome can actually be worse than without any government intervention - the problem to find an optimal policy, given that some market failures can not be corrected, is often referred to as the second-best problem (because the first-best outcome areto efficiency can not be obtained when some market failures can not be corrected) 28

22 2.3 batement of emissions - abatement means that less greenhouse gases are emitted under an environmental policy than without the policy - we usually refer to an outcome or a proection obtained in the absence of any environmental policy intervention as a U business as usual outcome or scenario - suppose, all other markets in the world economy are perfectly competitive, but there exists no market for CO2-emissions (these emissions are a public bad ) - hence, the assumptions of the neoclassical general equilibrium model are not fulfilled, and an inefficiency arises - the absence of a market for emissions implies that there will generally be an inefficiently high level of emissions, hence, there is a market failure (due to the negative externality they constitute) - to correct for this market failure, the regulator can simulate a market by introducing a price for CO2-emissions (e.g. using a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade scheme) - alternatively, suppose the regulator is a benevolent social planner who can directly control the amount of carbon used by all individuals and firms (this is less plausible, but corresponds to our earlier discussion of welfare economics); hence, the planner directly controls the abatement (and how much each individual or firm must abate) - when determining, the regulator must compare the benefits with the costs of CO2- abatement - suppose, if the world economy abates an amount of emissions (relative to baseline emissions U), then costs of C() are incurred (welfare losses) - at the same time, the problem of climate change becomes less severe, as less greenhouse gases are emitted than under U; suppose, the reduction in economic and social damages, measured in monetary units, when the amount of emissions is abated, equals () ( for benefit ) - suppose further that C() is convex, reflecting the idea that abatement costs rise more than proportionally; marginal abatement costs C () are, thus, increasing - () is assumed to be concave; the marginal benefit function () is, thus, downward sloping (this reflects the idea that when, say, 50 percent of total emissions are abated, a certain benefit is achieved; if the remaining 50 percent are also abated, the additional benefit (due to less severe climate change) is lower than before, because climate change is already much less severe than under U) 29

23 C() () net benefit - the vertical distance between () and C() is the net benefit of the abatement Now what is the optimal amount of abatement (which maximizes the net benefit)? If, starting from any given abatement level, another unit of emissions is abated ( is marginally increased), then the costs of this marginal abatement are C (). The marginal benefit equals (). If the marginal benefit exceeds the marginal abatement cost, then it is overall beneficial to society to abate more (as the benefit of a marginal increase of exceeds the cost). If () is smaller than C (), then the benefit of a marginal increase in is lower than its cost. Therefore, it is instead beneficial to reduce the amount of abatement (so there can be too much abatement). The efficient amount of abatement is reached when: '( ) = C '( ) batement, hence, when the marginal benefit equals the marginal abatement cost: C () t () Optimal batement batement - the green shaded area is the net benefit () C(); it corresponds to the welfare gain due to the abatement (relative to a U allocation) - if the optimal abatement is to be achieved using a carbon tax, the regulator should set the tax at the level t as shown in the above figure; firms will, then, internalize the environmental damages caused by their CO2-emissions, and an allocation will be achieved as if CO2 were a private good (hence, areto efficiency is achieved under market conditions) - to see this more clearly, suppose there are J firms 30

24 - firms operate in different sectors, countries, and with different technologies - therefore, each firm has an individual abatement cost function C ( ), where is the amount of abatement by firm given the carbon tax t (relative to U) - from the point of view of a firm, the marginal revenue from abatement is equal to the tax, because when the amount is abated, tax expenditures of t are avoided - firm s marginal abatement cost is C '( ) ; if this is lower than t, the firm benefits from abating more emissions, because the tax savings exceed the abatement costs (at the margin) - therefore, a profit maximizing firm abates until the following condition holds: C '( ) = t C '( ) t Optimal batement batement - since the condition C '( ) = t holds for each firm, it follows that under a uniform carbon tax, the marginal abatement costs of all firms are equalized: C '( ) = C '( ), for all i, i i This is also required for efficiency (and, hence, from a welfare perspective). Suppose to the contrary that the marginal abatement costs were not equalized in the optimum. Then, there is a firm (say, firm 1) with higher marginal abatement costs than another firm (say, firm 2). This means that if firm 1 abates a bit less, and firm 2 abates an equal amount more, the aggregated (total) abatement costs are reduced, because at the margin, it is cheaper to abate for firm 2. Therefore, a situation where (any two) firms have different marginal abatement costs can not be areto efficient. - note, that this discussion yields an interesting and powerful conclusion: if a carbon tax is introduced to correct for the market failure caused by environmental externalities of the emissions, the tax should be identical for all firms, in all sectors of the economy, and in all countries around the world - otherwise, areto efficiency will not be achieved 31

25 - a similar conclusion holds for a cap-and-trade (emission trading) scheme, but this will be discussed in more detail in a later section - in the real world, however, the assumptions of the neoclassical model may not be fulfilled for many markets and for many reasons; the above conclusion must, thus, be treated with caution; e.g., a CO2-price of 50 Dollars per ton may be problematic in certain low-income countries, while it may not be a problem in high-income countries Review of the agrange multiplier method of constrained optimization: - the agrange multiplier method is widely used in resource and environmental economics - the multipliers have a very useful interpretation as shadow prices on the constraints: the value of a multiplier tells us what the effect on the maximized value of the obective function would be for a marginal relaxation of the corresponding constraint - let us briefly review this method and the interpretation of the constraints, using a simple example of an emission abatement problem - suppose, there are two firms, with the abatement cost functions: C ( ) =, C ( ) = the total abatement is constrained to be 10 units of emissions, and the regulator tries to find the cost-minimizing allocation of emissions / of abatement, given this constraint - hence, the problem is: min C1+ C2, s.t = 10 - agrangian: = C1+ C2 λ( ) - optimality conditions: 0= = 21 λ 1 = = + λ, eliminate λ to get: 21 = ; using = 10, this yields: * 1 = 7, =, and λ= 21 = 14 * interpretation: firm 1 has lower abatement costs, hence, in the optimum, this firm will be assigned a higher abatement level (if both firms had the same emissions before the regulation, firm 1 has lower emissions than firm 2 after the regulation) - the value of the agrange multiplier: λ = 14 tells us, that the total abatement cost C1+ C2 would rise by 14 units of money (since C 1 and C 2 are measured in units of money), if the total abatement level would be raised by one unit (this result holds at the margin) 32

26 - alternatively, the problem can be restated in terms of the emission levels of firm 1 and firm 2; if the total amount of emissions is allowed to rise by one (marginal) unit, then the total abatement costs would fall by λ= 14 units of money - knowledge of the value of the agrange multiplier is useful, because the regulator can achieve the cost-minimizing outcome (computed above) by simply imposing a tax on emissions equal to the value of the multiplier, hence: t= 14 - each firm then abates to the point where the marginal abatement cost equals the tax - to see this, suppose M 1 and M 2 are the U emissions of firm 1 and firm 2 (given no tax or other regulation) 2 - under the tax, firm 1 minimizes: 1 + t( M1 1 ), which yields the FOC: 0= 21 t, hence, * the same as above when λ is replaced by t; the same holds for firm 2, so for t= λ = 14, firms choose the cost-minimizing abatement levels and - if the regulatory authority instead issues tradable emission permits, such that total emissions fall from M1+ M 2 to M1+ M 2 10 ; the equilibrium permit price would also be 14 * 1 * 2 33

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 7

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 7 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 7 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 24, 2017 Administrative Stuff The midterm exam will be returned next week. I will post a new homework, HW #3, on the website later

More information

1 Competitive Equilibrium

1 Competitive Equilibrium 1 Competitive Equilibrium Each household and each firm in the economy act independently from each other, seeking their own interest, and taking as given the fact that other agents will also seek their

More information

ECON Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model (Part 1)

ECON Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model (Part 1) ECON3102-005 Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model (Part 1) Neha Bairoliya Spring 2014 Competitive Equilibrium A competitive equilibrium requires that 1. The representative consumer,

More information

Cambridge University Press Modeling Monetary Economies, Second Edition - Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman Excerpt More information.

Cambridge University Press Modeling Monetary Economies, Second Edition - Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman Excerpt More information. Part I Money IN PART I we develop and learn to work with our most basic model of money, applying it to the study of fiat and commodity monies, inflation, and international monetary systems. In studying

More information

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as Economists typically assume that firms or a firm s owners try to maximize their profit. et R be revenues of the firm, and C be the cost of production, then a firm s profit can be represented as follows,

More information

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments Chapter 8: Exchange 8.1: Introduction In many ways this chapter is the most important in the book. If you have time to study just one, this is the one that you should study (even though it might be a bit

More information

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) Public Economics by Luca Spataro Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) 1 Introduction Connection between agents outside the price system The level of externality

More information

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Producer Theory - Monopoly Producer Theory - Monopoly Mark Dean Lecture Notes for Fall 2009 Introductory Microeconomics - Brown University 1 Introduction Up until now, we have assumed that all the agents in our economies are price

More information

Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard

Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard This version 24 th January 2011 Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard 1. General Points About Public Goods Goods that are non rival and non excludable in consumption

More information

Lecture 14. A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: June 27, 2017

Lecture 14. A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: June 27, 2017 Lecture 14 A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: June 27, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Chapter 1- Introduction

Chapter 1- Introduction Chapter 1- Introduction A SIMPLE ECONOMY Central PROBLEMS OF AN ECONOMY: scarcity of resources problem of choice Every society has to decide on how to use its scarce resources. Production, exchange and

More information

Chapter 3 Outline. Consumer Theory. Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior. Challenge: Why Americans Buy E-Books and Germans Do Not

Chapter 3 Outline. Consumer Theory. Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior. Challenge: Why Americans Buy E-Books and Germans Do Not Chapter 3 Outline Chapter 3 Consumer Theory If this is coffee, please bring me some tea; but if this is tea, please bring me some coffee. Abraham Lincoln Challenge: Why Americans Buy E-Books and Germans

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 2 44706 (1394-95 2 nd term) - Group 2 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 11: Externalities & Public

More information

Final Exam - Answers

Final Exam - Answers Page 1 of 8 December 20, 2000 Answer all questions. Write your answers in a blue book. Be sure to look ahead and budget your time. Don t waste time on parts of questions that you can t answer. Leave space

More information

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function. Economics 101 Spring 2015 Answers to Homework #5 Due Thursday, May 7, 2015 Directions: The homework will be collected in a box before the lecture. Please place your name on top of the homework (legibly).

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly Outline Barriers to Entry Profit Maximization under Monopoly Welfare Loss of Monopoly Multiplant Monopolist Price Discrimination Advertising in Monopoly

More information

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit by Robin Boadway, Queen s University, Canada Zhen Song, Central University of Finance and Economics, China Jean-François Tremblay,

More information

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals. Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals. We will deal with a particular set of assumptions, but we can modify

More information

Introduction. Consumer Choice 20/09/2017

Introduction. Consumer Choice 20/09/2017 Consumer Choice Introduction Managerial Problem Paying employees to relocate: when Google wants to transfer an employee from its Seattle office to its London branch, it has to decide how much compensation

More information

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 5: Externalities. External costs and benefits

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 5: Externalities. External costs and benefits ECONOMICS 103 External costs and benefits Topic 5: Externalities Marginal external costs, marginal external benefits Marginal social costs and benefits v marginal private costs and benefits Environmental

More information

Text: Reader, based on Griffin and two journal articles

Text: Reader, based on Griffin and two journal articles Chapter B) Market-failure, efficiency, and government intervention Text: Reader, based on Griffin 2.7-2.10 + 4.1-4.6 + 5.1-5.7 + 8.1-8.6 and two journal articles This chapter is organized as: Lesson 1:

More information

Welfare economics and the environment

Welfare economics and the environment CHPTER 5 Welfare economics and the environment Welfare economics is the branch of economic theory which has investigated the nature of the policy recommendations that the economist is entitled to make.

More information

Environmental Economics Spring 2009

Environmental Economics Spring 2009 ECON4910 Environmental Economics Spring 2009 Karine Nyborg Kjell Arne Brekke Why study environmental economics? Economic activity > environmental problems emissions to air, water, soil land use, noise

More information

The economics of competitive markets Rolands Irklis

The economics of competitive markets Rolands Irklis The economics of competitive markets Rolands Irklis www. erranet.org Presentation outline 1. Introduction and motivation 2. Consumer s demand 3. Producer costs and supply decisions 4. Market equilibrium

More information

Lecture 4: Aggregation and Partial Equilibrium

Lecture 4: Aggregation and Partial Equilibrium Lecture 4: Aggregation and Partial Equilibrium Aggregation on the Production Side Aggregation of Consumers demands Partial Equilibrium Over the past few weeks we have analyzed single firms and then individual

More information

Externalities and the Environment

Externalities and the Environment Externalities and the Environment What is an Externality? When a person/firm does something that affects the interests of another person or firm without affecting prices. Examples: Traffic/telephone/internet

More information

MARKETS AND MARKET FAILURES

MARKETS AND MARKET FAILURES MARKETS AND MARKET FAILURES I Social Choice: How much environmental protection? A Utility Recall that environmental protection costs resources. How are we to decide how much resources to allocate to environmental

More information

Economics 155/Earth Systems 112 Spring Final Exam

Economics 155/Earth Systems 112 Spring Final Exam Economics 55/Earth Systems Spring 006-07 Final Exam Instructions Do not open this exam before it is time to begin. If you are a graduating, write Grad on your first bluebook so we can get your grades submitted.

More information

MEMO. 1 Single-Product Monopolist. 1.1 Inverse Elasticity Rule. Date: October Subject: Notes from Tirole on Monopoly Ch.1: pp

MEMO. 1 Single-Product Monopolist. 1.1 Inverse Elasticity Rule. Date: October Subject: Notes from Tirole on Monopoly Ch.1: pp MEMO To: From: File FM Date: October 2018 Subject: Notes from Tirole on Monopoly Ch.1: pp. 65-78. Competitive options. Consider 3 mutually excluive choices for competitive market: as follows: (i) choice

More information

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Introduce the government. Construct closed-economy one-period macroeconomic model, which has: (i) representative consumer; (ii) representative

More information

I. An Introduction to Externalities and Market Failures. II. Externalities. EC 441: Handout 5A: Externalities and Solutions

I. An Introduction to Externalities and Market Failures. II. Externalities. EC 441: Handout 5A: Externalities and Solutions I. An Introduction to Externalities and Market Failures A. The first part of the course addressed how a governments efforts to raise its revenues and its associated pattern of expenditures affect private

More information

Externalities in the Koopmans Diagram

Externalities in the Koopmans Diagram Externalities in the Koopmans Diagram Peter Norman Sørensen Institute of Economics, University of Copenhagen Translation of August 2000 Danish version March 23, 2004 1 Introduction The two Welfare Theorems

More information

In Chapter 3 we pointed out that there are two reasons why countries

In Chapter 3 we pointed out that there are two reasons why countries Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade 6 Chapter In Chapter 3 we pointed out that there are two reasons why countries specialize and trade. First, countries differ either in

More information

Equilibrium and E ciency

Equilibrium and E ciency 2 Equilibrium and E ciency 2.1 Introduction The link between competition and e ciency can be traced back, at least, to Adam Smith s eighteenth-century description of the working of the invisible hand.

More information

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 2: Specialization & Trade

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 2: Specialization & Trade ECONOMICS 103 Topic 2: Specialization & Trade Key concepts: production possibilities, absolute advantage, comparative advantage, trade, gains from trade, economic efficiency. Model: production possibility

More information

Study Guide Final Exam, Microeconomics

Study Guide Final Exam, Microeconomics Study Guide Final Exam, Microeconomics 1. If the price-consumption curve of a commodity slopes downward how can you tell whether the consumer spends more or less on this commodity from her budget (income)?

More information

International Economics Twelfth Edition

International Economics Twelfth Edition CHAPTER T H R E E 3 International Economics Twelfth Edition The Standard Theory Of International Trade Dominick Salvatore John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Learning Goals: Understand how relative commodity prices

More information

Full file at

Full file at CHAPTER 2 Efficiency, Markets, and Government INSTRUCTIONAL OBJECTIVES The main objective of this chapter is to develop the concept of efficiency and show students how it is used to evaluate economic performance.

More information

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By Break-even point : the point at which price equals the minimum of average total cost. Externalities : the spillover effects of production or consumption for which no

More information

Chapter 3. Labour Demand. Introduction. purchase a variety of goods and services.

Chapter 3. Labour Demand. Introduction. purchase a variety of goods and services. Chapter 3 Labour Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-2 Introduction Firms hire workers because consumers want to

More information

Econ190 May 1, No baseball caps are allowed (turn it backwards if you have one on).

Econ190 May 1, No baseball caps are allowed (turn it backwards if you have one on). Heather Krull Final Exam Econ190 May 1, 2006 Name: Instructions: 1. Write your name above. 2. No baseball caps are allowed (turn it backwards if you have one on). 3. Write your answers in the space provided

More information

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari These notes cover the basics of the first part of our classical model discussion. Review them in detail prior to the second class

More information

Homework 2:: Homework 2

Homework 2:: Homework 2 Homework 2:: Hendrik Wolff Environmental Economics ECON436 Homework 2 Kolstad, Chapter 3 Answer Question 6, part a) and part b). Use Excel Kolstad, Chapter. 4 1. Consider the market for electricity. Suppose

More information

This exam has 33 points. There are six questions on the exam; you should work all of them. Half the questions are worth 5 points each and the other

This exam has 33 points. There are six questions on the exam; you should work all of them. Half the questions are worth 5 points each and the other Economics 5250/6250 Fall 2017 Dr. Lozada Midterm Exam This exam has 33 points. There are six questions on the exam; you should work all of them. Half the questions are worth 5 points each and the other

More information

Econ 303. Weeks 3-4 Consumer Theory

Econ 303. Weeks 3-4 Consumer Theory Econ 303 Weeks 3-4 Consumer Theory CHAPTER 3 OUTLINE 3.1 Consumer Preferences 3.2 Budget Constraints 3.3 Consumer Choice 3.4 Revealed Preference 3.5 Marginal Utility and Consumer Choice Consumer Behavior

More information

Exercise 2. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Exercise

Exercise 2. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Exercise Exercise 2 Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich Exercise 2 13.03.2018 1 Outline Exercise 1 Exercise 2 Exercise 3 Exercise 2 13.03.2018 2 Exercise 1 Exercise 2 13.03.2018

More information

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination Microeconomics I - Lecture #7, March 31, 2009 7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination 7.1 Monopoly Up to now we have analyzed the behavior of a competitive industry, a market structure that is

More information

Tools of Normative Analysis

Tools of Normative Analysis Rosench3 1 Tools of Normative Analysis January 20, 2006 Questions: Under what circumstances do we expect markets to perform well? Under what circumstances do we expect markets to fail to produce desirable

More information

General Equilibrium and Efficiency. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved. 1

General Equilibrium and Efficiency. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved. 1 General Equilibrium and Efficiency Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved. 1 After reading this chapter, you will have learned: The difference between a partial and general equilibrium

More information

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Pricing Under Homogeneous Oligopoly We will assume that the

More information

6) Consumer surplus is the red area in the following graph. It is 0.5*5*5=12.5. The answer is C.

6) Consumer surplus is the red area in the following graph. It is 0.5*5*5=12.5. The answer is C. These are solutions to Fall 2013 s Econ 1101 Midterm 1. No guarantees are made that this guide is error free, so please consult your TA or instructor if anything looks wrong. 1) If the price of sweeteners,

More information

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of 137 Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of BMW 1,3,5,7. Hyperlink Harald Schmidt Show: rtsp://streamer2.streaming.szm.de/sat1/schmidt/media//03/03/20/procter_56.rm

More information

Intermediate Microeconomic Theory, 12/29/2002. Lecture 6 Exchange

Intermediate Microeconomic Theory, 12/29/2002. Lecture 6 Exchange Lecture 6 Exchange The Digital Economist Usually, we study the behavior of the markets using the traditional supply and demand framework. Through the use of supply and demand, we have determined the equilibrium

More information

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 3

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 3 Economics 2 Spring 2018 rofessor Christina Romer rofessor David Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO ROBLEM SET 3 1.a. A monopolist is the only seller of a good. As a result, it faces the downward-sloping market

More information

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony 28.1: Introduction The previous chapter showed that if the government imposes a tax on some good that there is a loss of surplus. We show a similar result in this chapter

More information

Additional Questions. Externalities and Public Goods.

Additional Questions. Externalities and Public Goods. Additional Questions. Externalities and Public Goods. Problem 1. The purpose of this problem is to help you understand the difference in market demand for purely private and purely public good. For each

More information

Econ 300: Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring 2014 Final Exam Study Guide 1

Econ 300: Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring 2014 Final Exam Study Guide 1 Econ 300: Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring 2014 Final Exam Study Guide 1 Chronological order of topics covered in class (to the best of my memory). Introduction to Microeconomics (Chapter 1) What is

More information

Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities

Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities Externalities and imperfect competition share the characteristic of diverting market outcomes from Pareto optimality. Though

More information

Economics 361 Assessment

Economics 361 Assessment Economics 361 Assessment (1) Learning Objectives: Students who complete Economics 361 are expected to be able to use microeconomics as a means for evaluating alternative choices (e.g., policy choices;

More information

Lectures Notes on General Equilibrium

Lectures Notes on General Equilibrium 16 October 2013 Johan Stennek Lectures Notes on General Equilibrium These lecture notes are used for the second time this year (fall 2014). I would appreciate a lot if you could inform me about any errors

More information

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS 4265 FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION Preliminary Examination for Philosophy, Politics and Economics Preliminary Examination for Economics and Management Preliminary Examination for History and Economics INTRODUCTORY

More information

MICRO-ECONOMIC THEORY I STUDY NOTES CHAPTER ONE

MICRO-ECONOMIC THEORY I STUDY NOTES CHAPTER ONE MICRO-ECONOMIC THEORY I STUDY NOTES CHAPTER ONE UNIT 1 BASIC CONCEPT OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR CHAPTER ONE CONTENTS Introduction Objectives Main Content Theory of Consumer Behaviour Consumer Preferences Decisiveness

More information

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007 AS/ECON 4070 3.0AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007 Q1. Find all the efficient allocations in the following 2 person, 2 good, 2 input economy. The 2 goods, food and clothing, are produced using labour

More information

The Need for Information

The Need for Information The Need for Information 1 / 49 The Fundamentals Benevolent government trying to implement Pareto efficient policies Population members have private information Personal preferences Effort choices Costs

More information

Econ Microeconomics Notes

Econ Microeconomics Notes Econ 120 - Microeconomics Notes Daniel Bramucci December 1, 2016 1 Section 1 - Thinking like an economist 1.1 Definitions Cost-Benefit Principle An action should be taken only when its benefit exceeds

More information

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly EconS 425 - Perfect Competition and Monopoly Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 Introduction

More information

Introduction Question Bank

Introduction Question Bank Introduction Question Bank 1. Science of wealth is the definition given by 2. Economics is the study of mankind of the ordinary business of life given by 3. Science which tells about what it is & what

More information

The Need for Information

The Need for Information The Need for Information 1 / 49 The Fundamentals Benevolent government trying to implement Pareto efficient policies Population members have private information Personal preferences Effort choices Costs

More information

Introduction: What is the role of public finance? Efficiency of Markets: How and When Reasons for Market Failures. Externalities Public Goods

Introduction: What is the role of public finance? Efficiency of Markets: How and When Reasons for Market Failures. Externalities Public Goods Public Goods, Externalities, and the Role of Government Francesco Saraceno OFCE-Research Center in Economics of Sciences Po Luiss School of European Political Economy Jakarta School of Government and Public

More information

AP Microeconomics Chapter 4 Outline

AP Microeconomics Chapter 4 Outline I. Learning Objectives In this chapter students should learn: A. How to differentiate demand-side market failures and supply-side market failures. B. The origin of consumer surplus and producer surplus,

More information

Economics 384 A1. Intermediate Microeconomics II. Review Questions 1. S Landon Fall 2007

Economics 384 A1. Intermediate Microeconomics II. Review Questions 1. S Landon Fall 2007 Economics 384 A1 Intermediate Microeconomics II Review Questions 1 S Landon Fall 2007 The following questions are intended to help you review the course material as well as to give you some rough idea

More information

Question # 1 of 15 ( Start time: 01:24:42 PM ) Total Marks: 1 A person with a diminishing marginal utility of income: Will be risk averse. Will be risk neutral. Will be risk loving. Cannot decide without

More information

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd ) Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd ) In today s session, we will continue our discussion on monopoly.

More information

Learning Outcomes Assessment. Instructor: Timothy Dang Academic year Economics 361

Learning Outcomes Assessment. Instructor: Timothy Dang Academic year Economics 361 Learning Outcomes Assessment Economics 361 Instructor: Timothy Dang Academic year 2012-13 Overview Students who complete Economics 361 are expected to be able to use microeconomics to evaluate alternative

More information

Adam Smith Theorem. Lecture 9 Monday, Sept 28. Lecture. 1. More about Pareto Efficiency. 1. Midterm two weeks from today. In class, Monday, Oct 12.

Adam Smith Theorem. Lecture 9 Monday, Sept 28. Lecture. 1. More about Pareto Efficiency. 1. Midterm two weeks from today. In class, Monday, Oct 12. Lecture 9 Monday, Sept 28 1. Midterm two weeks from today. In class, Monday, Oct 12. 2. Posted midterms from Fall 2007 at course home page. (The class is a bit different. There is some overlap and this

More information

Also, big thank you to fellow TA Enoch Hill for edits and some additions to the guide.

Also, big thank you to fellow TA Enoch Hill for edits and some additions to the guide. Hello class, once again, here s an unofficial guide to the sample midterm. Please use this with caution, since 1) I am prone to error so incorrect explanations are entirely possible and 2) you should do

More information

You can find the consultant s raw data here:

You can find the consultant s raw data here: Problem Set 1 Econ 475 Spring 2014 Arik Levinson, Georgetown University 1 [Travel Cost] A US city with a vibrant tourist industry has an industrial accident (a spill ) The mayor wants to sue the company

More information

FINAL EXAMINATION. Special Instructions: Date: DECEMBER 15, 2000 School Year: Course and No.: ECON1006EA Time: 1:30 PM- 3:30 PM

FINAL EXAMINATION. Special Instructions: Date: DECEMBER 15, 2000 School Year: Course and No.: ECON1006EA Time: 1:30 PM- 3:30 PM FINAL EXAMINATION Date: DECEMBER 15, 2000 School Year: 2000-2001 Course and No.: ECON1006EA Time: 1:30 PM- 3:30 PM Professor: SARLO, C Department: Arts & Science Number of Pages: 11 + cover Time Allowed:

More information

Econ 101, Final, Fall ANSWER KEY

Econ 101, Final, Fall ANSWER KEY Econ 101, Final, Fall 2008. ANSWER KEY Prof. Guse, W & L University 1. [ 3 Points ] The bowed-out shape of the Production Possibility Frontier (PPF): (a) reflects the existence of opportunity cost. (b)

More information

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market This firm may choose to produce

More information

Perfectly Competitive Markets, Market Equilibrium, Welfare Economics, Efficiency, and Market Failure

Perfectly Competitive Markets, Market Equilibrium, Welfare Economics, Efficiency, and Market Failure Perfectly Competitive Markets, Market Equilibrium, Welfare Economics, Efficiency, and Market Failure Markets--Putting Market Supply and Market Demand Together So far in this course, we have studied consumers

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET Chapter 6 We recall that perfect competition was theorised as a market structure where both consumers and firms were price takers. The behaviour of the firm in such circumstances was described in the Chapter

More information

Chapter 5. Market Equilibrium 5.1 EQUILIBRIUM, EXCESS DEMAND, EXCESS SUPPLY

Chapter 5. Market Equilibrium 5.1 EQUILIBRIUM, EXCESS DEMAND, EXCESS SUPPLY Chapter 5 Price SS p f This chapter will be built on the foundation laid down in Chapters 2 and 4 where we studied the consumer and firm behaviour when they are price takers. In Chapter 2, we have seen

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice Paul A Johnson Economics 304 Advanced Topics in Macroeconomics Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice A: The Two-Period Model Consider an individual who faces the problem of allocating their available

More information

First Hour Exam Public Finance Fall, 2007

First Hour Exam Public Finance Fall, 2007 HourExam1-Fall07, October 23, 2007 First Hour Exam Public Finance - 180.365 Fall, 2007 Name You must answer all parts of the exam. If you run out of space, use the back of the preceding page. If you get

More information

Midterm Review. B. How should the government intervene? - Often multiple options; to choose, need answer to know effects of policies.

Midterm Review. B. How should the government intervene? - Often multiple options; to choose, need answer to know effects of policies. 14.41 Public Economics Section Handout #5 Midterm Review I. Intro to Public Economics & Micro Review A. When should the government intervene? - Lesson of basic micro: the private market equilibrium is

More information

COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition Chapter 13 COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition Overview and Objectives This chapter provides a classification of different types of goods

More information

EC 201 Lecture Notes 1 Page 1 of 1

EC 201 Lecture Notes 1 Page 1 of 1 EC 201 Lecture Notes 1 Page 1 of 1 ECON 201 - Macroeconomics Lecture Notes 1 Metropolitan State University Allen Bellas The textbooks for this course are Macroeconomics: Principles and Policy by William

More information

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro Microfoundations and General Equilibrium I. Introduction Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro economic theories and the general equilibrium approach to economic

More information

5-3 - Copyright 2017 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved

5-3 - Copyright 2017 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Chapter 5 Lecture - Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods 1 What s the Best Level of Pollution? Is there a way to know what is the optimal level of pollution for a society? No pollution

More information

iii

iii Foreword 1.. I NTRODUCTION I N 1 1.1 A Simple Economy 1 1.2 Central Problems of an Economy 2 1.3 Organisation of Economic Activities 4 1.3.1 The Centrally Planned Economy 4 1.3.2 The Market Economy 5 1.4

More information

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402 SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402 Question: How does opportunity cost relate to problem of scarcity? Answer: The problem of scarcity exists because of limited production. Thus, each society must make

More information

THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION

THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION Lecture 5 Producer Behavior THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION The Digital Economist Production refers to the conversion of inputs, the factors of production, into desired output. This relationship is about making

More information

Final Exam - Solutions

Final Exam - Solutions Ecn 100 - Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis June 8, 2010 Instructor: John Parman Final Exam - Solutions You have until 10:00am to complete this exam. Be certain to put your name,

More information

Chapter 4. Labour Demand. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition. Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Chapter 4. Labour Demand. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition. Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Labour Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-2 Introduction Firms hire workers because consumers want to

More information

Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money

Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money Main Aims: 1. Answer following two questions: Why money is used as a medium of exchange? How and why money improves allocations in an economy and

More information

Total Factor Productivity and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: A Comment and Some Intuition

Total Factor Productivity and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: A Comment and Some Intuition 1 Total Factor roductivity and the nvironmental Kuznets urve: A omment and Some Intuition eha Khanna* Department of conomics Binghamton niversity,.o. Box 6000 Binghamton, Y 13902-6000 hone: 607-777-2689,

More information

Principles of Economics

Principles of Economics Principles of Economics Sylvain Barde Fall term 2009-2010: Microeconomics Course Outline Week 1: Introduction Part 1: Theories of the agent Week 2: Consumer preferences and Utility Week 3: The budget constraint

More information

Midterm Review. B. How should the government intervene? - Often multiple options; to choose, need answer to know effects of policies.

Midterm Review. B. How should the government intervene? - Often multiple options; to choose, need answer to know effects of policies. 14.41 Public Economics Section Handout #5 Midterm Review I. Intro to Public Economics & Micro Review A. When should the government intervene? - Lesson of basic micro: the private market equilibrium is

More information

Welfare Economics. The Edgeworth Box. The Basic Theorem. Some Basic Assumptions

Welfare Economics. The Edgeworth Box. The Basic Theorem. Some Basic Assumptions Welfare Economics The Edgeworth Box The Basic Theorem The basic theorem in welfare economics: A market, exchange, economy will achieve efficient resource allocation. We intend to show the basics of that

More information