Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers"

Transcription

1 Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Thomas D. Jeitschko and Mark J. Tremblay Prepared for IIOC 2014: Not Intended for Circulation March 27, 2014 Abstract In this paper we investigate a two-sided market platform model. We develop a theoretical model for platforms with two sides, buyers or consumers and sellers or producers, who buy and sell through the platform. This occurs in the market for smartphones with consumers, app producers, and smartphone operating systems; similarly, it occurs in the video game market with consumers, video game producers, and video game consoles. Only consumers who purchase the platform can purchase content from the producers. In these markets consumers are heterogeneous in their gains from the producer side. Some consumers purchase many games while others only buy a few. In developing platform competition, instead of using the Hotelling model we develop a model of competition between two homogeneous platforms that allows consumers and firms to optimize with respect to how they home, i.e. we allow both individual consumers and individual producers to multi-home or single-home depending on whether it is optimal based on their type. This leads to multiple equilibrium allocations of consumers and firms all of which are seen in existing markets. 1 Introduction Many transactions among multiple parties are conducted through an intermediary or platform. For many consumers, purchases are made online through platforms like ebay or Amazon. Some buyers actually consume their purchases on the platform or network: Google users obtain searches on Google, Facebook users visit Facebook pages of their friends, smartphone users use apps on their phones, and video game users play games on their gaming console. Today, platforms provide many commodities in our society and their market structures vary considerably. For example, Google and Facebook are near monopolists who provide their services for free; however smartphones and video game consoles are generally priced well above zero. 1

2 The early development of the literature began with markets where network externalities were prominent, Katz and Shapiro (1985) and Economides (1996a). Caillaud and Jullien (2003) investigate competition further but assume that coordination favors the incumbent platform; otherwise platforms may fail to gain a critical mass, or fail to launch. There has been a considerable amount of focus on two-sided markets: Evans (2003); Rochet and Tirole (2003); Armstrong (2006); Rochet and Tirole (2006). Many have attempted to resolve the issues surrounding the failure to launch and the multiple equilibrium aspects which occur in multi-sided market models, see Ellison and Fudenberg (2003) and Hagiu (2006). Weyl (2010) generalizes many of the previous pricing models including those of Armstrong and Rochet and Tirole for the monopoly case using what he calls insulating tariffs. With an insulating tariff, the price that a platform charges on one side of the market depends on the number of agents on the other side. An insulating tariff makes price a function of the number of users on the other side and in doing so resolves the failure to launch and multiple equilibrium issues which occur in other models. Weyl and White (2013) extend this model with insulating tariffs to the case where there exist multiple competing platforms. Both models are very general, allowing for rich heterogeneity. However, they also find that more heterogeneity of agents can lead to issues with the platform s profit maximization platform; Deltas and Jeitschko (2007) come to a similar conclusion. One of the main empirical contributions is Lee (2013b). He investigates the video game market when Xbox entered the market from He finds that exclusive contracts with game developers allowed Microsoft to enter the video game market with Xbox. The market with video game consoles and smartphones as platforms are the examples of platforms that this paper aims to focus on. In the majority of the previous models on platforms, agents marginal utilities for the number of agents on the other side of the platform are homogeneous. In considering a two-sided market with consumers and firms then this assumption is not reasonable since consumers vary in their value for the other side. For example, in the market for video games, Lee 2013 finds there exists a large variance in the number of video games purchased across consumers. This suggests that there are many types of consumers whose marginal utilities for video games differ. To investigate markets with consumers and firms where consumers marginal utilities are heterogeneous we develop a model where consumer marginal utilities depend on the consumer type. This leads to equilibria where consumers who join the platform consume different amounts of video games or apps. This differs from much of the previous literature yet it closely resembles what is seen in reality. Furthermore, 2

3 the monopoly model we develop generalizes naturally to a model of competition between two homogeneous platforms which provides new insights regarding multiple equilibrium and equilibrium allocations of consumers and firms. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 constructs the base model for a monopoly platform. In Section 3, we generalize this model to include two competing platforms. We determine the equilibrium prices the platforms charge and determine how consumers and firm allocate in equilibrium. Unlike other models we allow both consumers and firms to optimize over participation, i.e. they choose whether or not to single-home, multi-home, or not participate on a platform. Section 4 concludes. 2 Base Model Consider two groups of agents who would benefit from interaction but are unable to do so without an intermediary. This intermediary platform charges agents in each group a price to participate on the platform. We will call this price the membership fee. The utility of one group depends on the number of agents of the other group who join the platform. Agents on both sides of the platform are described by continuous variables. Agents on side 1, the consumers or buyers, are indexed by τ [0, N 1 ] and agents on side 2, the firms or producers, are indexed by θ [0, ). The number of consumers that join the platform is denoted by n 1 [0, N 1 ] and the number of firms that join the platform is denoted by n 2 [0, ). The utility for a consumer of type τ is given by: u 1 (τ) = v + α 1 (τ) n 2 p 1. (1) Here, v is the membership value every consumer receives from joining the platform. This is the stand alone utility of being a member of the platform when no firms join the platform. Note that it is possible for v = 0 but for smartphones and video game consoles v > 0. For smartphones v is the utility from using a smartphone as a phone and for video game consoles v is the utility from using the console to watch DVDs. Also notice that consumers are homogeneous in their membership benefit to the platform; v does not depend on consumer type τ. The price or membership fee that consumers pay the platform is given by p 1. The network effect or the marginal benefit to a consumer for an additional firm on the platform is given by α 1 (τ). Thus, consumers are heterogeneous in their marginal benefit for firms. We focus on the case when network effects are positive so we assume α 1 (τ) 0 for all τ. We assume α 1 ( ) is a decreasing continuous and twice continuously differentiable function. 3

4 Since α 1 (τ) is decreasing, it orders consumers by their marginal benefits. Consumers whose type is τ close to zero have marginal benefits that are high relative to those consumers whose type is located far from zero. The platform knows v and α 1 (τ) but cannot distinguish the individual values for each consumer τ. Thus, it cannot price discriminate between consumers. On the other side of the platform, side 2, are the firms. Their utility or profits are given by: π 2 (θ) = α 2 n 1 cθ p 2, (2) Here c > 0 is the synchronization cost parameter for the firms. We assume firms must pay to synchronize their product to the platform s operating system and this cost depends on firm type. The price or membership fee the firms pay to the platform is given by p 2. The marginal benefit firms receive from an additional consumer on the platform is given by α 2 which does not depend on firm type. The platform knows the firm s profit structures but cannot identify firms individually; hence, it cannot price discriminate between firms. Firms differ from consumers in a few aspects. First, notice that the marginal benefit of firms for an additional consumer is homogeneous across firm type. The logic here is that an additional consumer will shift each firms demand curve up in the same way. The assumption we are making here is that each consumer sees firm products as homogeneous, but consumers differ in their preferences for the number of products they wish to consume. Second, firms are heterogeneous in their synchronization cost. Firms with type θ close to zero pay lower synchronization costs relative to those with higher type θ. Lastly we introduce the platform. The platform s profits are given by: Π M = n 1 (p 1 f 1 ) + n 2 (p 2 f 2 ), (3) The platform faces no fixed costs. The marginal cost the platform faces for an additional agent i to join the platform is given by f i. The platform is a price setter so it maximizes profits with respect to p 1 and p 2. This model for platforms is similar to much of the previous literature. One key difference of our model is that consumers preferences for the seller side is heterogeneous. This leads to consumers purchasing different amounts of products on the platform. In other models consumers are homogeneous with respect to their marginal benefit for firms and thus all purchase the same products once on the platform. 4

5 2.1 Pricing with a Monopoly Platform In this section we solve the platform s problem and determine the optimal prices it charges consumers and firms. Given prices p 1 and p 2 the last agent on each side to join the platform has utility or profit equal to zero. The last consumer to join the platform is denoted by τ [0, N 1 ] and the last firm to join the platform by θ [0, ). We assume consumers and firms are distributed uniformly. Furthermore, since α 1 ( ) is decreasing in τ, the last consumer to join, τ, gives the number of consumers who join: n 1 = τ. For firms, the relationship is similar since firm synchronization costs are increasing in firm type, hence firm profits will decrease in θ. Thus θ = n 2. Since u 1 (τ = τ) = 0, π 2 (θ = θ) = 0, θ = n 2, and τ = n 2 we can use equations (1) and (2) to solve for prices as a function of the number on consumers and firms that join the platform: p 1 (n 1, n 2 ) = v + α 1 (n 1 ) n 2, (4) p 2 (n 1, n 2 ) = α 2 n 1 cn 2. (5) By substituting these into the platform s profit function, equation (3), the platform maximizes its profits with respect to n 1 and n 2 to determine the optimal prices. This gives two first-order conditions and three second-order conditions that must be satisfied: [v + α 1 (n 1 )n 2 f 1 ] + n 1 [α 1(n 1 )n 2 ] + α 2 n 2 = 0, (6) n 1 α 1 (n 1 ) + [α 2 n 1 cn 2 f 2 ] cn 2 = 0, (7) 2n 2 α 1(n 1 ) + n 1 n 2 α 1(n 1 ) < 0, (8) 2c < 0, (9) 2c[2n 2 ( α 1(n 1 )) n 1 n 2 α 1(n 1 )] [α 1 (n 1 ) + n 1 α 1(n 1 ) + α 2 ] 2 > 0. (10) The first two equations, (6), and (7), implicitly define the optimal participation levels n 1 and n 2. Substituting these levels into the price equations, (4) and (5), determines the 5

6 optimal prices the monopoly platform charges to guarantee the optimal participation levels. The second-order conditions, equations (8), (9), and (10), essentially imply α 1( ) cannot be too negative. Note, the second-order conditions hold for all linear α 1 ( ). The first-order conditions, equations (6) and (7), give the optimal prices the platform charges: p 1 = f 1 α 2 n 2 + [ α 1(n 1 )]n 1 n 2, (11) p 2 = f 2 α 1 (n 1 )n 1 + cn 2. (12) For the price consumers face, f 1 is the marginal cost to the platform for an additional consumer, n 2 α 2 is the marginal benefit to the firm side for an additional consumer, and [ α 1(n 1 )]n 1 n 2 > 0 is the monopoly markup. The consumer price is the marginal cost minus their benefit to the firm side plus the monopoly markup. For the firm price, f 2 is the marginal cost to the platform for an additional firm, α 1 (n 1 )n 1 is the benefit to the marginal consumer for an additional firm, and cn 2 is the monopoly markup. The firm price is the marginal cost minus their benefit to the consumer side plus the monopoly markup. α 1 (τ). Using this base model we derive closed form solutions assuming a specific functional form 2.2 Closed Form Solutions and Welfare In this subsection we investigate closed form solutions and welfare for the case when α 1 ( ) is linear. Assume α 1 (τ) = a bτ. This occurs when consumer α 1 s are distributed uniformly over [0, a] and the number of potential consumers present on the platform is N 1 = a. To b simplify calculations, we further assume v = f 1 and f 2 = 0. 1 These assumptions do not affect the firm s profit function but consumer utility is now given by: u 1 (τ) = v + [a bτ] n 2 p 1. (13) 1 These assumptions are not extremely critical in the analysis and they make computations simple. This case, with v = f 1 0 and f 2 = 0 fits with the smartphone and video game examples we have discussed. The marginal cost of firms, or app producers, for the platform is zero. Firms pay synchronization costs that drive marginal cost to zero for the platform. Consumers receive membership benefits from having a smartphone or a video game console, they can make phone calls or watch DVDs, and producing each piece of hardware for an individual consumer has a positive marginal cost for the platform. This assumption means these values are equal. 6

7 Since α 1 (τ) = a bτ, we have α 1(τ) = b for all τ [0, a b ]. conditions, (6) and (7), yields: 2 Using the first order n 1 = 1 2b [a + α 2], (14) n 2 = n 1 2c [a bn 1 + α 2 ]. (15) Since it must be that n 1 [0, a ], equation (14) implies a corner solution occurs when b α 2 > a. When α 2 > a, the marginal gain from the other side of the platform is greater for firms; firms have a higher marginal gain then every consumer. To extract the most surplus, the platform captures as many consumers as possible with a low consumer price; this will generate a much greater surplus on the firm side which the monopoly platform will extract from. When α 2 a we compare the platform profits between the corner solution and the interior solution and determine which parameter values result in each type of solution. For the interior solution, the assumptions α 2 < a, v = f 1 0, and f 2 = 0 and equations (11), (12), (14), and (15) imply: n 1 = 1 2b [a + α 2], (16) p 1 = v bc [a + α 2] 2 (a α 2 ) > 0, (17) n 2 = 1 8bc [a + α 2] 2, (18) p 2 = 1 8b [a + α 2](3α 2 a). (19) There are two key things to notice in this equilibrium. First, recall the usual monopoly problem with inverse demand, p = a bq and marginal cost equal to zero. The equilibrium number of consumers who purchase from the monopoly is given by Q = a < 2b n 1. So in equilibrium, a monopoly platform will have more consumers than a traditional monopolist. This is since additional consumers generate additional surplus on the platform so a monopoly platform will want to have more consumers then in the traditional monopoly model so that it 2 The second-order conditions hold for this example. This can be seen by substituting the linear α 1 ( ) into the second-order conditions, equations (8), (9), and (10). 7

8 can generate more surplus on the firm side which it will then extract through the firm price. Second, firm price can be negative. Firms are subsidized to join the platform when a > 3α 2. Intuitively this means that if adding firms generates a significantly larger amount of surplus for consumers than consumers generate for firms, then the total surplus on the firm side is less important. The platform will subsidize firms allowing for a greater extraction of surplus on the consumer side. Given equilibrium prices, the number of consumers, and the number of firms, we calculate platform profits. The superscript i denotes the interior solution. Π i = n 1 (p 1 f 1 ) + n 2 (p 2 f 2 ) = 1 64b 2 c [a + α 2] 4. (20) Looking at the comparative statics we see that Πi, Πi < 0. This implies that an increase in c b c, the synchronizing cost firms face, will decrease platform profits, and an increase in b, the rate at which α 1 decreases across consumers, will also decrease platform profits. We also have Π i a, Πi α 2 > 0. This implies an increase in a, or an upward shift in α 1 for all consumers, will increase platform profits, and an increase in the gain firms receive from additional consumers, α 2, will increase platform profits. These are the comparative static results one would expect and they give insight as to how the platform would like to affect these parameters if they were made endogenous through some form of technological improvement. We can also derive consumer, firm, and total surplus given the platform s optimal pricing scheme: CS i n 1 0 [v + α 1 (τ)n 2 p 1]dτ = (a + α 2) 4 64b 2 c = Π M, (21) F S i n 2 0 [α 2 n 1 cθ p 2]dθ = (a + α 2) 4 128b 2 c = (1/2)Π M, (22) W i = T S i = 5(a + α 2) 4. (23) 128b 2 c Notice, consumer surplus is equal to platform profits which are twice as large as firm surplus. Thus, comparative statics for the types of surplus are the same as those for the platform s profit. This is not surprising since the comparative statics are all in relation to generating or reducing some kind of surplus which affects all agents through the platform in this model. We now investigate the corner solution which always occurs when α 2 a, and once this is 8

9 complete we investigate for which cases it occurs when α 2 < a. In the corner solution we know all consumers participate on the platform so for the consumer side of the market we have: n 1 = a b = ˆN 1, (24) p 1 = v = f 1 0. (25) where p 1 = v = f 1 is the highest consumer price the platform can charge that will induce all consumers to join the platform. Given this, the platform maximizes profits with respect to n 2 with p 2 = p 2 (n 1 = a/b, n 2 ) = α 2 a b cn 2. This gives the firm side equilibrium for the corner solution: n 2 = aα 2 2bc, (26) p 2 = aα 2 2b. (27) Given the corner solution, we calculate welfare. The superscript c denotes the corner solution results. Π c = n 1 (p 1 f 1 ) + n 2 (p 2 f 2 ) = n 1 (0) + n 2 p 2 = α2 2a 2 F S c CS c n 2 0 n 1 0 4b 2 c, (28) [v + α 1 (τ)n 2 p 1 ]dτ = a3 α 2 4b 2 c, (29) [α 2 n 1 cθ p 2 ]dθ = α2 2a 2 8b 2 c = (1/2)Πc, (30) W c = T S c = α 2a 2 8b 2 c [3α 2 + 2a]. (31) The comparative statics are what we expect. Surpluses, firm price and firm participation are increasing in a and α 2, which are the parameters that generate surplus, and are decreasing in b and c, which are the parameters that reduce surplus. By comparing platform profits for when α 2 < a, Π c > Π i if and only if a 4 + 4a 3 α 2 10a 2 α aα α 4 2 < 0. This inequality never holds for α 2, a 0; so when α 2 < a we 9

10 have the interior solution and when α 2 a we have the corner solution. The relationship between a and α 2 will play a key role throughout the paper in determining welfare. In the next section we generalize the base model to include platform competition and we determine the equilibria and welfare. 3 Homogeneous Platform Competition 3.1 The Model Setup Assume there exists two platforms, A and B, that play a static pricing game. With multiple platforms consumers and firms can either join a single platform (single-home) or join multiple platforms (multi-home). Previous work has made restricting assumptions on how some of the agents can participate; for example, they assume that on one side of the platform agents can only multi-home and on the other side agents can only single-home. In this model, the allocation of consumers and firms is part of the equilibrium. We assume the synchronization cost for a firm to join the platform is the same for platforms A and B. So the cost to joining one platform for firm θ is cθ and 2cθ to join both platforms. This means synchronization to one platform has no affect on the cost to synchronize to the other platform, there are no economies of scale for synchronization. On the consumer side, if a consumer participates on two platforms his benefit from membership to the second platform diminishes by δ [0, 1], so that his total membership benefit from the two platforms is (1 + δ)v. If δ = 0, then there is no additional membership benefit from joining the second platform. If δ = 1, then the membership benefit is unaffected by being a member of another platform. We assume the platforms are homogeneous: Definition 1. Platforms A and B are homogeneous if α 1,A ( ) = α 1,B ( ) α 1 ( ) for all τ. This implies that all consumers have the same marginal utilities for the firm side across platforms. Let N 1 (N 2 ) denote the total number of consumers (firms) who participate in at least one platform and let n A 1 (n B 1 ) denote the total number of consumers who participate on platform A (B). Finally, let n m 1 be the number of consumers who multi-home; hence, N 1 = n A 1 + n B 1 n m 1. Similarly, we have n A 2, n B 2, and n m 2 for the firm side. If firm θ single-homes on platform i, its profit is given by π2(θ); i if it multi-homes its profit is given by π2 AB (θ). These functions are given by: 10

11 π i 2(θ) = α 2 n i 1 cθ p i 2, (32) π AB 2 (θ) = α 2 (n A 1 + n B 1 n m 1 ) 2cθ p A 2 p B 2. (33) If consumer τ single-homes on platform i his utility is given by u i 1(τ); if he multi-homes his utility is given by u AB 1 (τ) where, u i 1(τ) = v + α 1,i (τ)n i 2 p i 1, (34) u AB 1 (τ) = (1 + δ)v + α 1 (τ)(n A 2 + n B 2 n m 2 ) p A 1 p B 1. (35) The sequence of play is as follows: first the platforms simultaneously choose consumer and firm prices, p i 1 and p i 2 for i = A, B; then consumers and firms simultaneously choose which platforms to join. This form of differentiation describes many types of two-sided markets better than much of the literature which use the Hotelling line on both sides of the market to differentiate two competing platforms. For example, the synchronization costs app producers incur rarely varies across platforms; this cannot be modelled with the Hotelling line. Furthermore, in the Hotelling model we cannot allow for the rich choice participation sets that agents have. Thus in our model of competition, differentiation occurs through the consumer side of the market; then based on the unrestrictive participation decisions allowed of the consumers and firms, firms must decide whether it is worth joining a platform based on the additional fixed cost and the additional price they would incur. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to introduce platform differentiation in this way. In the following subsection we determine which consumers and firms single-home or multihome in equilibrium. The equilibrium allocations we get closely resemble what is seen in several two-sided markets like smartphones and video game platforms. Thus demonstrating the importance of allowing both sides of the market to determine their homing choice in a static game. 3.2 Equilibrium Configurations We investigate the equilibrium configurations that occur when the two homogeneous platforms, A and B, compete in prices. If platforms charge the same consumer prices, p A 1 = p B 1, 11

12 then consumers will join the platform with more firms. If consumer prices and the number of firms are equal across platforms then consumers are indifferent between the two platforms; in this case, consumers will either not participate, multi-home, or single-home on platform A or B with equal probability. Assuming that consumers and firms cannot coordinate with any other agents, then if prices are equal on both sides of the platform then in expectation the number of consumers will be the same on each platform and the number of firms will be the same on each platform, E(n A 1 ) = E(n B 1 ) and E(n A 2 ) = E(n B 2 ). Once prices are set, consumers and firms simultaneously choose which platforms to join. This can lead to failure to launch issues. Specifically, how will consumers and firms allocate if p i 1 > p j 1 and p i 2 < p j 2? When platforms price both sides equally, then, in expectation, the number of consumers and firms on each platform are equal. However, when prices on each side are not equal and neither platform sets both the low prices then how consumers and firms allocate themselves will depend on the beliefs and the beliefs of beliefs and so on. To resolve this we assume that if p i 1 p j 1 > p j 2 p i 2 then platform i fails to launch and agents who join a platform only join platform j. 3 As we will see, in many cases the homogeneous platforms will set their prices equal to each other for both the consumer and firm prices so that p A 1 = p B 1 = p 1 and p A 2 = p B 2 = p 2. Before investigating how, and for which parameter sets this occurs, we first investigate how firms and consumers allocate on the platforms when they face symmetric prices. Given the timing of the game and the lack of coordination between and within both sides of the platform, if a consumer or firm decides to single-home on a platform then it must be indifferent between which platform it chooses. We assume it then joins platform A or B with equal probability; hence, it must be true that in expectation n A 1 = n B 1 and n A 2 = n B 2. In the following subsections we investigate how firms and consumers allocate by either not participating, single-homing, or multi-homing on the platforms Allocation of Firms with Symmetric Pricing Firms who join the platform can be separated into two disjoint groups. Without loss of generality we compare multi-homing to the case when a firm single-homes on platform A; the group who single-home and those who multi-home are given by: 3 Then analysis in what follows still holds for more belief systems. For example, if instead the inequality is with respect to percent makeup then the results are the same. We also require p A 1, p B 1 > δv, but this is not important at this time. The additional requirement, p A 1, p B 1 > δv, will become clear in the analysis below; but notice that when consumer prices fall below δv then all consumers will join regardless of what the firms do. So this requirement is important. 12

13 Group 1: The θ such that π AB 2 (θ) > π A 2 (θ) and π AB 2 (θ) > 0 are the multi-homing firms. Group 2: The θ such that π A 2 (θ) > π AB 2 (θ) and π A 2 (θ) > 0 are the single-homing firms. Group 1 is the set firms such that multi-homing is more profitable than single-homing when multi-homing is better than not participating. Equation (33) implies this occurs when 0 < α 2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) cθ p 2 and 0 < α 2 (n A 1 +n B 1 n m 1 ) 2cθ 2p 2. However, for all θ 0 and since in expectation n A 1 = n B 1, we have α 2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) cθ p 2 α 2 (n A 1 +n B 1 n m 1 ) 2cθ 2p 2, i.e. the first inequality implies the second. Thus the firms who multi-home are the θ such that θ α 2 (n B 1 nm 1 ) p 2. Note, if the firm price, p c 2, is large enough, then this set is empty and no firms multi-home. Alternatively, if n m 1, the number of consumers who multi-home, is large enough, then the set is again empty and no firm will multi-home. Thus for multi-homing firms to exist we must have firm price and the number of multi-homing consumers to be sufficiently low. Assuming this is true, i.e. the inequality 0 < α 2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) cθ p 2 holds, then the set of firms who multi-home are: θ [ 0, α ) 2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) p 2 = [0, n m 2 ). (36) c Group 2 is the set of firms such that single-homing is more profitable than multi-homing when single-homing is better than not participating. Equation (32) implies this occurs when 0 > α 2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) cθ p 2 and 0 < α 2 n A 1 cθ p 2. For this set to be nonempty we need α 2 n A 1 cθ p 2 > α 2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) cθ p 2 which is true since n m 1 0. Thus, so long as prices are sufficiently low for the market to exist, the set of firms who single-home is always non-empty when the competing platforms set prices equal. By solving for θ we can determine the total number of firms that single-home on platforms A or B: [ α2 (n B 1 n m 1 ) p 2 θ, α ] 2n A 1 p 2 = [n m 2, N 2 ]. (37) c c When prices are such that both sets are nonempty there are two key points worth making here. First, the number of firms who will join each platform is n A 2 = n B 2 = n m 2 + (1/2)(N 2 n m 2 ) = (1/2)(N 2 + n m 2 ) where (1/2)(N 2 n m 2 ) is the expected number of single-homing firms to join each platform. Second, the firms that choose to multi-home instead of singlehome are the firms with the sufficiently low synchronization costs. For firms with higher synchronization costs it becomes to costly to join more than one platform. Thus, for given prices, a firm is more likely to multi-home if it faces a lower synchronization cost to join a platform. 13

14 3.2.2 Allocation of Consumers with Symmetric Pricing In a similar fashion we can separate the consumers into those who multi-home and those who single-home. Group 1: All τ such that u AB 1 (τ) > u A 1 (τ) and u AB 1 (τ) > 0 multi-home. Group 2: All τ such that u A 1 (τ) > u AB 1 (τ) and u A 1 (τ) > 0 single-home. Group 1 is the set of consumers such that multi-homing provides more utility than singlehoming when multi-homing is better than not participating. Equation (35) implies this occurs when 0 < δv + α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ) p 1 and 0 < v + α 1 (τ)n 2 p 1. However, for all τ 0 we have δv+α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ) p 1 v+α 1 (τ)n 2 p 1. This means that the first equation implies the second. Thus the consumers who multi-home are those with 0 < δv+α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ) p 1. Note, if the consumer price, p 1, is large enough, then this set is empty and no consumer will multi-home. If n m 2, the number of firms who multi-home, is large enough, then the set may again be empty and no consumer will multi-home. For consumers, unlike firms, there always exists an additional membership benefit, δv, to join the additional platform. Thus if δv p 1, then all consumers will multi-home regardless of the firms decisions. Assuming 0 < δv + α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ) p 1 holds, then the set of consumers who multi-home is given by: τ [ ( 0, α1 1 p1 δv n B 2 n m 2 )] = [0, n m 1 ]. (38) Group 2 is the set of consumers such that single-homing provides more utility than multi-homing when single-homing is better than not participating. Equation (34) implies this occurs when 0 > δv + α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ) p 1 and 0 < v + α 1 (τ)n A 2 p 1. For both of these to hold we need v + α 1 (τ)n A 2 p 1 δv + α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ) p 1 to hold for all τ, which it does. Since α 1 ( ) is increasing in τ, this set of single-homing consumers are the consumers with smaller τ relative to those τ who multi-home. Furthermore, the above inequalities imply that if p 1 > δv then for all δ < 1 the set of single-homing consumers is nonempty since v + α 1 (τ)n A 2 > δv + α 1 (τ)(n B 2 n m 2 ). It is reasonable to assume that p 1 > δv will hold in most practical cases. For most products the membership benefit will depreciate almost to zero when a consumer multi-homes. In the video game case, the membership benefit would be the ability to play music and watch movies from the video game console. Once someone has one console they can do this and adding an additional console is of almost no added benefit. This implies a δ close to zero. Thus for p 1 > δv, the set of single-homing consumers 14

15 is given by: τ [ ( α1 1 p1 δv n B 2 n m 2 ), α 1 1 ( )] p1 v = [n m 1, N 1 ]. (39) Assuming the sets of multi-homing and single-homing consumers are nonempty, the consumers who multi-home are those with τ closer to zero, i.e. those with the higher marginal utility for producers. This makes sense. In the case for video games, for example, this implies that consumers who purchase multiple gaming consoles are those with the highest marginal utility for the number of games available on these consoles. The consumers who single-home are those who have lower marginal utilities for the number of games available and those with the lowest marginal utilities, τ large, do not enter the market. Furthermore, we have n A 1 = n B 1 = n m 1 + (1/2)(N 1 n m 1 ) = (1/2)(N 1 + n m 1 ) where (1/2)(N 1 n m 1 ) is the number of single-homing consumers to join each platform. Investigating the allocation decisions of the consumers and firms provides insight into two-sided markets where both sides can either single-home or multi-home if it is optimal to do so. In reality this is how many two-sided markets work. Given the consumer and firm allocation rules for equal prices across platforms, we can determine the Nash Equilibria that occur in this model. n A Equilibria In determining the equilibrium configurations, the main parameter inequality that affects > both how consumers and firms allocate and how platforms choose to price is f 1 δv. For < many products the membership benefit will depreciate almost to zero when a consumer multi-homes. This implies the marginal cost for an additional consumer on the platform is greater than the additional membership benefit from joining an additional homogeneous platform, f 1 δv. In the video game case, the membership benefit would be the ability to play music and watch movies from the video game console. Once someone has one console they can do this, but adding an additional console is of almost no added benefit since they can already watch movies and play music on the first console. This would imply a δ close to zero and the additional benefit would not overcome the cost of producing the additional console. Consider first the case when f 1 δv. In this case, competition between the two homogeneous platforms results in the Bertrand Paradox: Proposition 1. If f 1 δv then p A 1 = p B 1 = f 1 and p A 2 = p B 2 = f 2 are the unique symmetric 15

16 prices in equilibrium and Π A = Π B = 0. Given these prices, and using the allocation rules above we can determine the Nash Equilibrium for the case when p 1 = f 1 δv. We first investigate the case when there exists both consumers who single-home and consumers who multi-home. Theorem 1. When f 1 δv we have unique Nash Equilibrium prices charged by the two platforms, p A 1 = p B 1 = f 1 and p A 2 = p B 2 = f 2, and at least one, potentially four, allocations of firms and consumers that can be present in Nash Equilibrium. 1. All consumers single-home and all firms multi-home. This is always a Nash Equilibrium. 2. There exists consumers that multi-home and single-home and firms that multi-home and single-home; here, existence depends on model parameters. 3. All firms single-home and many, potentially all, consumers multi-home. This has strong restrictions when p 2 > 0, and when p 2 = 0 it requires v = 0. Case 1, which always exists, is an important equilibrium because it very closely resembles the two-sided market for smartphones where almost all consumers single-home, they own one phone, and almost all firms multi-home, every app is available on all types of smartphones. In case 2, allocations resemble current allocations we see in many two-sided markets. For video game platforms, there exists consumers who multi-home and single-home and there exists game designers who multi-home and single-home. In case 3, v = 0 is needed for such an equilibria to exist and this equilibria is seen with antique malls. An antique mall is the platform with many firms, antique shops, and consumers. Antique shops are only in one mall and all consumers shop at the many malls to find what they are looking for. There is no membership benefit for being a mall so v = 0, all consumers multi-home and all firms single-home. We now turn to the case when δv > f 1. In this case a platform can charge a consumer price of p i 1 = δv and guarantee itself profit since consumers will either single-home on platform i or if a consumer is already on platform j i then they will be indifferent to multi-homing. Hence, if p i 1 = δv then consumers will join platform i regardless of the firms decisions. Thus for this case with δv > f 1, both platforms are guaranteed profits and all consumers τ [0, N 1 ] are guaranteed to join at least one platform. Furthermore, in this case we do not have failure to launch issues since both platforms are completely able to establish themselves 16

17 on the consumer side of the market. This implies we can investigate and determine the Nash Equilibrium allocations for the cases when p i 1 > p j 1 and p j 2 > p i 2. This also leads to potentially uncountably many Nash Equilibrium. Theorem 2. When δv > f 1, there exists at least one and potentially uncountably many Nash Equilibria. 1. There exists a unique symmetric Nash Equilibrium where p A 1 = p B 1 = δv, p A 2 = p B 2 = f 2, all consumers τ [0, 1] multi-home, and the firms who join a platform do so by singlehoming on platform A or B with equal probability; this Nash Equilibrium always exists. 2. The uncountably many asymmetric Nash Equilibria that can potentially exist are characterized by p i 2 = f 2, p j 2(ɛ) = f 2 ɛ, p i 1 = δv, p j 1 = p j 1(ɛ) δv, and p i 2 = f 2, for ɛ 0 with p j 1(ɛ = 0) = δv. If there exists an ɛ > 0 where certain conditions hold, see proof, then the resulting Nash Equilibrium allocations will have all consumers multi-homing and all firms who decide to participate do so by joining platform j. Furthermore, in all NE platforms receive positive profits: Π A = Π B = N 1 (δv f 1 ) > 0. Thus, if a platform has significantly high retained membership benefit for consumers when they multi-home, then competing homogeneous platforms can avoid the Bertrand Paradox on the consumer side of the market and make positive profits. This result obviously generalizes to n homogeneous platforms who compete in prices. The Nash Equilibrium outcomes provide insight into the decision of an agent to single-home or multi-home. We next investigate the theorems by looking at closed form solutions. 3.3 Closed Form Solutions and Welfare for Static Nash Equilibrium In this subsection we investigate the same closed form solution that we determined above in the case for a monopoly platform. We calculate welfare and compare it with the welfare that occurs with a monopoly platform. Note, there exists two effects on welfare between having a monopoly platform and two competing platforms. Competition will result in lower prices; however, it also can destroy network surplus or create more synchronization costs from firms who choose to multi-home. Depending on which effect dominates, welfare may increase or decrease with increased competition. 17

18 As before we assume α 1 (τ) = a bτ so that the maximum number of consumers that can join a platform is N 1 = a/b. Furthermore, we assume v = f 1 0 and f 2 = 0. This implies f 1 = v δv so Proposition 1 and Theorem 1 hold but Theorem 2 does not. Proposition 1 implies p A 1 = p B 1 = f 1 = v 0 and p A 2 = p B 2 = f 2 = 0. Given this, we investigate allocation 1 in Theorem 1 where all consumers single-home and all firms multi-home. We know this equilibrium exists and is relevant for real world applications such as smartphones and video game consoles. Given that all consumers single-home and all firms multi-home we have n m 1 = 0 and N 2 = n A 2 = n B 2 = n m 2. Furthermore, allocations (36) and (39) imply: n m 2 = (1/c)(α 2 n A 1 p 2 ) = α 2n A 1 c, n A 1 = a 2b. These two equations and two unknowns determine the equilibrium: n A 1 = n B 1 = (1/2)N 1 = (1/2) N 1 and n A 2 = n B 2 = n m 2 = aα 2 with p 2bc 1 = f 1 = v, and p 2 = f 2 = 0. Notice, all consumers join a platform i.e., we have full participation. Given this equilibrium, consider welfare. The superscript 1 represents allocation 1 in Theorem 1. Π 1 A = Π 1 B = 0, (40) CS 1 N1 0 [v + α 1 (τ)n m 2 p 1 ]dτ = F S 1 n m [(a bτ) ( aα 2 2bc )]dτ = a3 α 2 4b 2 c = CSc, (41) [α 2 N 1 2cθ 2p 2 ]dθ = a2 α 2 2 4b 2 c = 2F Sc, (42) W 1 = T S 1 = a2 α 2 4b 2 c [α 2 + a] = a2 α 2 8b 2 c [2α 2 + 2a] < a2 α 2 8b 2 c [3α 2 + 2a] = W c. (43) Recall from the monopoly model at the end of section 2.1 that the corner solution occurs where the monopolist captures all consumers when α 2 a, otherwise the interior solution occurs. Notice how consumer surplus is the same as in the monopoly model when a corner solution occurs. This is because consumer prices are the same in both cases and all consumers are single-homing in this case with two platforms. Firm surplus is greater here than in the monopoly corner solution. 18

19 The most striking result is that welfare with perfect competition is strictly less than welfare with a monopoly platform that implements the corner solution and captures all consumers. Comparing welfare between the case here and the case when the monopolist implements an interior solution (which requires α 2 < a) we see that W 1 < W i if and only if 0 < 5a 3 17a 2 α aα α2. 3 This inequality never holds for α 2, a 0. Thus we have the following theorem. Theorem 3. For v = f 1 0, f 2 = 0, α 1 (τ) = a bτ. When α 2 a the monopoly corner solution that occurs has higher welfare than the perfectly competitive equilibrium between two homogeneous platforms when all consumers single-home and all firms multi-home. When α 2 < a the monopoly interior solution that occurs has lower welfare than the equilibrium between two homogeneous platforms when all consumers single-home and all firms multihome. This means that when the two-sided market is driven by the firms, α 2 a, then the monopoly will capture all consumers and this will generate more welfare than the case where we have two homogeneous platforms who compete perfectly competitively with all consumers single-homing and all firms multi-homing. When the monopoly platform is already capturing all consumers then in an sense it is already pricing low enough for competition to not be enough to increase surplus. Otherwise, the tradeoff for lower prices is sufficient to increase welfare. There are three more important points to be made here. First, we are assuming that there do not exist decreasing marginal returns for the other side of the platform. In many instances consumers have decreasing marginal returns from the number of apps available on their smartphone. Overall this decreases surplus for both levels of competition but it would hurt the monopolist more since now its prices would change and destroy more surplus. Second, we assumed v = f 1 0. For v > f 1 similar arguments follow and welfare results will closely resemble what we have here. However, for v < f 1 it will be less likely for the corner solution to occur since in that case it will be costly for the monopoly platform to capture all consumers. This makes competition welfare improving in more cases. Finally, we assumed homogeneous platforms. If platforms are quite different more cases with high price competition but strong network benefits will occur. This would make competition welfare enhancing. Even with these pitfalls, this result is quite interesting and one can imagine a case where a monopoly is welfare improving. For example, when the first iphone came out it was essentially a monopolist in terms of pure smartphones. At this time, if a homogeneous competitor 19

20 was also present, welfare arguably would suffer by destroying and splitting network surpluses between these two platforms even if we assume no coordination issues. 4 Conclusion This paper makes three contributions to the existing platform and two-sided market literature. It establishes a base model for two-sided markets, with consumers, firms, and a monopoly platform, that is intuitive and general while allowing for extensions of competition and well-behaved closed form solutions. Second, it introduces competition between two homogeneous platforms where both sides of the market, consumers and firms, may either single-home or multi-home. Third, the model admits welfare comparisons across levels of competition; a monopoly platform and two competing homogeneous platforms. The framework of this model allows for more extensions. For instance, this model will be extended to allow for entry. The results of the stage game will depend on the amount of differentiation between platforms. For example, given a situation where an incumbent platform has established a presence in the market, a homogeneous potential entrant will have no way of gaining momentum to enter the market. This could lead to many interesting results about entry and exit in two-sided markets which will be left for future research. 5 Appendix 5.1 Proofs Proof of Proposition 1 Proof. Clearly, symmetric prices that are less than their respective marginal costs is worse for each platform and so both platforms deviate. Thus symmetric prices below the respective marginal cost is not feasible. If the symmetric firm price is greater than f 2 then both platforms have the incentive to undercut the price by ɛ and capturing all firms and thus all consumers. Thus we must have p 2 = f 2. If p 1 > f 1 then both platforms have an incentive to undercut the price by ɛ and capture the whole market. This undercutting only captures all consumers when p 1 δv which we assume to be true in Proposition 1. Otherwise all consumers will multi-home because price is less than the additional membership gain from joining a platform. Thus p 1 = f 1. This implies Π i = n i 1(p 1 f 1 )+n i 2(p 2 f 2 ) = n i 1(0)+n i 2(0) = 0 for i = A, B. 20

21 Proof of Theorem 1 Proof. Here we show the equilibrium allocations for general prices p 1 and p 2. Equilibrium prices are then given by Proposition 1, this completes the Nash Equilibrium. Allocation 1: For all firms to multi-home, notice that allocation (37) implies all firms multi-home only when all consumers single-home. Furthermore, since n m 2 = n A 1 = n B 1, allocation (38) implies no consumer multi-homes. Hence, the allocation where all firms multi-home and all consumers single-home is a Nash Equilibrium when prices are equal and p 1 δv. Allocation 2: Since p 1 δv, allocation (38) implies the set of multi-homing consumers is non-empty only when the number of multi-homing firms is not to large. In what proceeds we determine a Nash Equilibria that occurs under certain parameter restrictions. Let x [0, 1] be the percent of consumers who multi-home of those N 1 who join a platform so that in expectation n m 1 = xn A 1 = xn B 1. Note, this implies N 1 = n A 1 + n B 1 n m 1 and since in expectation n A 1 = n B 1 we have N 1 = (2 x)n A 1. Given this, using allocation (36) we can find the cutoff x = x m such that above x m no firm will multi-home. Allocation (36) implies 0 = α 2 (1 x m )n B 1 p 2. Thus, x m = 1 p 2. (44) α 2 n B 1 And for all x > x m no firm multi-homes. Note, we are assuming p 2 < α 2 n B 1 the market collapses, hence x m (0, 1). since otherwise Now if we let 0 < x < x m then some firms will single-home and some firms will multihome. Allocation (36) implies n m 2 = α 2(1 x)n B 1 p 2 c and allocation (37) implies n B 2 = (1/2)(N 2 + n m 2 ) = (1/2c)[α 2 (2 x)n A 1 2p 2 ]. Similarly, allocation (38) defines the number of multihoming consumers: 0 = δv + α 1 (n m 1 )(n B 2 n m 2 ); using this equation and the equations for n m 2, n B 2, and n m 1 = xn A 1 = xn B 1 we can characterize x by: 0 = δv+α 1 (xn A 1 )(1/2c)[α 2 (2 x)n A 1 2p 2 2α 2 (1 x)n B 1 +2p 2 )] = δv+α 1 (xn A 1 )(1/2c)[α 2 xn A 1 ], (45) Furthermore, allocation (39) defines N 1, the number of consumers on platform A: 0 = v + α 1 (N 1 )n A 2 p 1. Thus we have: 21

22 0 = v + α 1 (N 1 )n A 2 p 1 = v + α 1 ((2 x)n A 1 )(1/2c)(α 2 (2 x)n A 1 2p 2 ) p 1. (46) Thus, we have two equations (45) and (46) and two unknowns, x and n A 1. 4 If the resulting value of x is such that x (0, x m ) then we have a Nash Equilibrium for the whole static game where there is a complete mix of single-homing and multi-homing consumers and firms. Note this equilibrium may not exist for sets of parameters. If the x characterized in equations (45) and (46) is not in [0, x m ) then this equilibrium does not exist. Allocation 3: For all firms to single-home, allocation (37) implies all firms single-home only if the number of multi-homing consumers is large relative to the number of single-homing consumers, n B 1 n m 1 + p 2 /α 2. If p 2 = 0, then this holds only when all consumers multi-home. By allocation (39), this will only be an equilibrium when v = 0. If p 2 > 0, then allocation (39) implies there exists an equilibrium where all firms single-home and a large portion of consumers multi-home given prices such that N 1 n m 1 = α 1 ) α 1 ) 2p n A 2 n A 2 2 α 2. This potential equilibrium requires relatively restrictive assumption. In reality we do not see equilibrium 1 ( p 1 v 1 ( p 1 δv of this form where all firms single-home and many or all consumers multi-home. Proof of Theorem 2 Proof. We first prove the case for ɛ = 0. We must show there does not exist a non-epsilon deviation that makes the platform worse off and the allocation stated above is indeed Nash. Given prices are p A 1 = p B 1 = δv and p A 2 = p B 2 = f 2, consumers are indifferent between single-homing on either platform and multi-homing so we assume they multi-home. If p 1 lowered by ɛ then this would occur. Thus every consumer available in the market joins both platforms A and B. Given all consumers multi-home and firms face equal prices between platforms A and B, for all firms θ we have π A 2 (θ) = π B 2 (θ) > π AB 2 (θ). Thus the firms who join a platform will single-home to platform A or B with equal probability and the number of single-homing firms who join a platform is given by π A 2 (θ = N 2 ) = 0. Using equation (32) this implies N 2 = (1/c)[α 2 f 2 ]. To see why the prices are NE we investigate deviations. If a platform were to increase its consumer price from δv, then it will lose consumers and thus lose all firms and thus lose all consumers driving profits to zero. If a platform lowers consumer price below δv, then the allocation is unchanged and they receive less payment; 4 These equations and prices equal to marginal costs completely determine the Nash Equilibrium. 22

Platform Competition with Endogenous Homing

Platform Competition with Endogenous Homing Platform Competition with Endogenous Homing Thomas D. Jeitschko Department of Economics Michigan State University E-mail: jeitschk@msu.edu Mark J. Tremblay Department of Economics Michigan State University

More information

Exclusive dealing with network effects

Exclusive dealing with network effects Exclusive dealing with network effects Toker Doganoglu Julian Wright Abstract This paper explores the ability of an incumbent to use exclusive deals or introductory offers to dominate a market in the face

More information

Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing

Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing Mark Armstrong and Julian Wright July, 004 Abstract We analyze some models of price competition in two-sided markets, allowing for the possibility

More information

Expectations, Network Effects and Platform Pricing

Expectations, Network Effects and Platform Pricing Expectations, Network Effects and Platform Pricing Andrei Hagiu and Hanna Halaburda December 18, 2011 Abstract In markets with network effects, users must form expectations about the total number of users

More information

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory Econ 500 - Microeconomic Analysis and Policy Monopoly Monopoly A monopoly is a single firm that serves an entire market and faces the market demand curve for its output. Unlike

More information

Competing Payment Schemes

Competing Payment Schemes Competing Payment Schemes Graeme Guthrie and Julian Wright Victoria University of Wellington and National University of Singapore September 9, 2003 Abstract This paper presents a model of competing payment

More information

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist Economics 335 March 3, 999 Notes 8: Models of Spatial Competition I. Product differentiation A. Definition Products are said to be differentiated if consumers consider them to be imperfect substitutes.

More information

Part II. Market power

Part II. Market power Part II. Market power Chapter 3. Static imperfect competition Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2009 Introduction to Part

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Multihoming and compatibility

Multihoming and compatibility Multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright November 3, 2004 Abstract This paper analyzes the consequences of multihoming on private and social incentives for compatibility. Multihoming

More information

Exclusive dealing with network effects

Exclusive dealing with network effects Exclusive dealing with network effects Toker Doganoglu Julian Wright Abstract This paper explores the ability of an incumbent to use introductory offers to dominate a market in the face of a more efficient

More information

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Problem 1. Shorter problems. (35 points) Solve the following shorter problems. 1. Consider the following (simultaneous) game of chicken. This is a game in

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers Economics of Industrial Organization Lecture 12: Mergers Mergers Thus far we have talked about industry dynamics in terms of firms entering and exiting the industry, and have assumed that all these firms

More information

Titolo. Corso di Laurea magistrale in Economia. Tesi di Laurea

Titolo. Corso di Laurea magistrale in Economia. Tesi di Laurea Corso di Laurea magistrale in Economia Tesi di Laurea Titolo Competition, Mergers and Exclusive Dealing in Two-Sided Markets with Zero-Price Constraints: The Case of Search Engines Relatore Prof. Federico

More information

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016 Game Theory & Firms Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016 What is Game Theory? Game Theory Intuitive Definition: Theory of strategic interaction Technical Definition: Account

More information

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Hongru Tan and Julian Wright March, 2018 Abstract We show that in the context of pricing by a multi-sided platform, in addition to the classical market-power

More information

Exclusive dealing with network effects

Exclusive dealing with network effects Exclusive dealing with network effects Toker Doganoglu Julian Wright Abstract This paper explores the ability of an incumbent to use introductory offers to dominate a market in the face of a more efficient

More information

Bundling and Quality Disclosure in a Bayesian Game

Bundling and Quality Disclosure in a Bayesian Game Journal of Game Theory 2015, 4(1): 13-17 DO: 10.5923/j.jgt.20150401.03 undling and Quality Disclosure in a ayesian Game Qing Hu Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University, Kobe, Japan Abstract We analyze

More information

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Producer Theory - Monopoly Producer Theory - Monopoly Mark Dean Lecture Notes for Fall 2009 Introductory Microeconomics - Brown University 1 Introduction Up until now, we have assumed that all the agents in our economies are price

More information

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Econ 11b: Intermediate Microeconomics Dirk Bergemann, Spring 01 Week of 3/6-4/3 1 Lecture 16: Imperfectly Competitive Market 1.1 Price Discrimination In the previous section we saw that the monopolist

More information

Why Tie a Product Consumers do not Use?

Why Tie a Product Consumers do not Use? University of Toronto From the SelectedWorks of Joshua S Gans August, 2007 Why Tie a Product Consumers do not Use? Dennis W Carlton Joshua S Gans Michael Waldman Available at: https://works.bepress.com/joshuagans/10/

More information

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition by Joshua S. Gans and Stephen P. King University of Melbourne 0 th March, 000 This paper demonstrates that low (below marginal

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

Research Article Quality Assurance Competition Strategy under B2C Platform

Research Article Quality Assurance Competition Strategy under B2C Platform Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Volume 2016, Article ID 6587872, 5 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2016/6587872 Research Article Quality Assurance Competition Strategy under B2C Platform Yunmiao

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

Two-Sided markets? Welfare Effects of Process Innovation in Two-Sided Markets: The Role of Compatibility Decisions

Two-Sided markets? Welfare Effects of Process Innovation in Two-Sided Markets: The Role of Compatibility Decisions Welfare Effects of Process Innovation in Two-Sided Markets: The Role of Compatibility Decisions Masayoshi Maruyama and Yusuke Zennyo Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe University Two-Sided

More information

Search markets: Introduction

Search markets: Introduction Search markets: Introduction Caltech Ec106 (Caltech) Search Feb 2010 1 / 16 Why are prices for the same item so different across stores? (see evidence) A puzzle considering basic economic theory: review

More information

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22 Monopoly. Principles of Microeconomics, Fall Chia-Hui Chen November, Lecture Monopoly Outline. Chap : Monopoly. Chap : Shift in Demand and Effect of Tax Monopoly The monopolist is the single supply-side

More information

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power May 19, 2012 Eric B. Rasmusen Dan R. and Catherine M. Dalton Professor, Department of Business Economics and Public Policy, Kelley

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Solutions to Final Exam

Solutions to Final Exam Solutions to Final Exam AEC 504 - Summer 2007 Fundamentals of Economics c 2007 Alexander Barinov 1 Veni, vidi, vici (30 points) Two firms with constant marginal costs serve two markets for two different

More information

Do Credit Cards Increase (Effective) Retail Prices?

Do Credit Cards Increase (Effective) Retail Prices? Do Credit Cards Increase (Effective) Retail Prices? Takanori Adachi School of Economics Nagoya University adachi.t@soec.nagoya-u.ac.jp Mark J. Tremblay Farmer School of Business Miami University tremblmj@miamioh.edu

More information

Industrial Organization 04

Industrial Organization 04 Industrial Organization 04 Product differentiation Marc Bourreau Telecom ParisTech Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 04: Product differentiation 1 / 43 Outline 1 Introduction: forms of product differentiation

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly Outline Barriers to Entry Profit Maximization under Monopoly Welfare Loss of Monopoly Multiplant Monopolist Price Discrimination Advertising in Monopoly

More information

Robust Exclusion Through Loyalty Discounts. Einer Elhauge and Abraham L. Wickelgren Harvard University and University of Texas at Austin

Robust Exclusion Through Loyalty Discounts. Einer Elhauge and Abraham L. Wickelgren Harvard University and University of Texas at Austin Robust Exclusion Through Loyalty Discounts Einer Elhauge and Abraham L. Wickelgren Harvard University and University of Texas at Austin January 2010 Abstract We consider loyalty discounts whereby the seller

More information

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. October 13, 2011 Abstract In a durable good market where sellers have private

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review 14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14 Lecture 2 - Review Prof. Sara Ellison MIT OpenCourseWare 4 basic things I want to get across in this review: Monopoly pricing function of demand, elasticity, & marginal

More information

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION 5. Game Theory Mr. Sydney Armstrong Lecturer 1 The University of Guyana 1 Semester 1, 2016 OUR PLAN Analyze Strategic price and Quantity Competition (Noncooperative Oligopolies)

More information

Market Concentration and Power

Market Concentration and Power Market Concentration and Power What can the data tell us about θ? If we had data on marginal costs, we should be able to estimated θ easily. Because then we could get L, and having estimated H (easy),

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly and oligopoly (PR 11.1-11.4 and 12.2-12.5) Advanced pricing with market power and equilibrium oligopolistic

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 Pricing with market power and oligopolistic markets (PR 11.1-11.4 and 12.2-12.5) Module 4 Sep. 28, 2013

More information

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction 1 Intermediate Microeconomics W3211 Lecture 25: Recap 2 Introduction Columbia University, Spring 2016 Mark Dean: mark.dean@columbia.edu 2 The Story So Far. 3 The Story So Far. 4 Topic Topic 1 The Consumer

More information

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Chapter 8. Group pricing and personalized pricing Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge

More information

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria Slide Slide 3 Recall from last time A Nash Equilibrium occurs when: Econ 40: Micro Theory Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria Monday, December 3 rd, 007 Each firm s action is a best

More information

Platform Competition with Endogenous Multihoming

Platform Competition with Endogenous Multihoming Platform Competition with Endogenous Multihoming Roberto Roson 7th January 2005 Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari di Venezia, Cannaregio S. Giobbe 873, 30121 Venezia. E-mail: roson@unive.it.

More information

Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Abstract

Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Abstract Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Stephan Marette UMR Economie Publique INRA Abstract This paper explores the role of a minimum quality standard when the quality choice is discrete. A minimum

More information

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006 FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006 QUESTION NO: 1 (MARKS: 1) - PLEASE CHOOSE ONE Compared to the equilibrium price and quantity sold in a competitive market, a monopolist Will charge a price and sell a quantity.

More information

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO 20015 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II Candidates should attempt TWO questions. marks. Each question carries equal When presenting numerical results, please give a complete

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2018 Module II Competitive markets Profit maximization and the firm s supply (PR 8.1-8.6) The analysis of

More information

An economic analysis of internet privacy regulation 1

An economic analysis of internet privacy regulation 1 An economic analysis of internet privacy regulation 1 Abraham L. Wickelgren University of Texas at Austin August 2015 1 I thank the George Mason Law and Economics Center for financial support and helpful

More information

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 27, 2006 Answer four of the six

More information

Industrial Organization- micro : Price discrimination in oligopoly

Industrial Organization- micro : Price discrimination in oligopoly Industrial Organization- micro 3 2018: Price discrimination in oligopoly Price discrimination is a mechanism whereby a monopolist can effectively shift surplus from the consumer sector. With perfect price

More information

Competition Policy Monopoly Competition Other. Bundling. Patrick Legros

Competition Policy Monopoly Competition Other. Bundling. Patrick Legros Bundling Patrick Legros / 33 Introduction Sale of two or more products in fixed (or variable) combination Related to tie-in-sales (can buy 2 only if already bought ) hardware-software, printer-ink, tv-channels,

More information

Hard to Get, Easy to Lose Endogenous Reputation and Underinvestment

Hard to Get, Easy to Lose Endogenous Reputation and Underinvestment Hard to Get, Easy to Lose Endogenous Reputation and Underinvestment Guillermo L. Ordoñez July, 2007 Abstract Reputation concerns may help to achieve efficiency in cases where imperfect information impedes

More information

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity Countervailing Power and Product Diversity by Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Work in Progress December 6, 2003 Abstract To analyse the effects of countervailing power on product variety, I construct a

More information

Imperfect Competition

Imperfect Competition Imperfect Competition Lecture 5, ECON 4240 Spring 2018 Snyder et al. (2015), chapter 15 University of Oslo 2.14.2018 iacquadio & Traeger: Equilibrium, Welfare, & Information. UiO Spring 2018. 1/23 Outline

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power Session VI Sep 25, 2010 In a competitive market there are

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SPATIAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS. Jonathan Vogel. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SPATIAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS. Jonathan Vogel. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SPATIAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS Jonathan Vogel Working Paper 14978 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14978 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition Course Evaluations on Thursday: Be sure to bring laptop, smartphone, or tablet with browser, so that you can complete your evaluation in class. Oligopoly

More information

Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities

Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities Daniel CERQUERA March 15, 2005 Abstract We present a model of R&D competition between an incumbent and a potential entrant with network externalities

More information

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets Hend Ghazzai Assistant Professor College of Business and Economics Qatar University P.O. Box 2713 Doha, Qatar. Abstract Consumers' choice

More information

MERGER INCENTIVES OF COST ASYMMETRIC FIRMS UNDER PRODUCTION DIFFERENTIATION XIA LI B.A., KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY, 2010 A REPORT

MERGER INCENTIVES OF COST ASYMMETRIC FIRMS UNDER PRODUCTION DIFFERENTIATION XIA LI B.A., KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY, 2010 A REPORT MERGER INCENTIVES OF COST ASYMMETRIC FIRMS UNDER PRODUCTION DIFFERENTIATION By XIA LI B.A., KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY, 00 A REPORT submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree MASTER

More information

The Model of Perfect Competition

The Model of Perfect Competition The Model of Perfect Competition Key issues The meaning of perfect competition Characteristics of perfect competition and output under competition Competition and economic efficiency Wider benefits of

More information

Dynamic innovation in a two-sided platform

Dynamic innovation in a two-sided platform Title Dynamic innovation in a two-sided platform Author(s) Lin, M; Li, S; Whinston, A Citation The 44th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences (HICSS-44) Koloa, Kauai, HI., 4-7 January 20.

More information

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly ECON 21 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 216) Monopoly Relevant readings from the textbook: Mankiw, Ch. 15 Monopoly Suggested problems from the textbook: Chapter 15 Questions for Review (Page 323):

More information

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes CHAPTER 15 Monopoly Goals in this chapter you will Learn why some markets have only one seller Analyze how a monopoly determines the quantity to produce and the price to charge See how the monopoly s decisions

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2016 Module II Competitive markets Profit maximization and the firm s supply (PR 8.1-8.6) The analysis of

More information

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Julian Wright Abstract In a recent paper, Chiara Fumagalli and Massimo Motta (2006) challenge the idea that an incumbent can foreclose efficient

More information

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Department of Applied Economics Faculty of Economics University of

More information

Finance 510 Midterm #2 Practice Questions

Finance 510 Midterm #2 Practice Questions Finance 50 Midterm # Practice Questions ) ) Consider the following pricing game between Dell and Gateway. There are two types of demanders in the market, High and Low. High demanders value a computer at

More information

4 Effects of a change in marginal cost (Extra) α β q * 1. The reason is that this is the first-order condition for the firm's choice of quantity.

4 Effects of a change in marginal cost (Extra) α β q * 1. The reason is that this is the first-order condition for the firm's choice of quantity. 4 Effects of a change in marginal cost (Extra) Consider the same market as in the previous question. Notice that firm 1 s equilibrium profit can be written as: ( ) = π 1 q 1 * c 1 π 1 * c 1 ( ( ),q * 2

More information

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Pricing Under Homogeneous Oligopoly We will assume that the

More information

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Yasuhiro Arai Hitotsubashi University August 2009 Abstract We capture the differences between patent and copyright by considering the optimal

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct. UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures 13-14 Oct. 1, 2011 Pricing While there is some involved analysis required,

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* Abstract Many software and video game firms offer a free demo with limited content to help buyers better assess the likely value

More information

Lecture 2: Market Structure Part I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

Lecture 2: Market Structure Part I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly) Lecture 2: Market Structure Part I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly) EC 105. Industrial Organization Matt Shum HSS, California Institute of Technology EC 105. Industrial Organization ( Matt ShumLecture

More information

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro Eco 300 Intermediate Micro Instructor: Amalia Jerison Office Hours: T 12:00-1:00, Th 12:00-1:00, and by appointment BA 127A, aj4575@albany.edu A. Jerison (BA 127A) Eco 300 Spring 2010 1 / 61 Monopoly Market

More information

Quality Choice, Fixed Costs and Equilibrium in Models of Vertical Differentiation 1

Quality Choice, Fixed Costs and Equilibrium in Models of Vertical Differentiation 1 Quality Choice, Fixed Costs and Equilibrium in Models of Vertical Differentiation 1 Matteo Alvisi April 000 University of Bologna Department of Economics Abstract: I provide a full characterization of

More information

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets S O L U T I O N S 26 Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets Solutions for Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach with Calculus (International Ed.) Apart from end-of-chapter exercises provided

More information

Operating system adoption decisions in the presence of indirect network externalities

Operating system adoption decisions in the presence of indirect network externalities Operating system adoption decisions in the presence of indirect network externalities Jeanine Miklós-Thal and Markus Reisinger March 2010 Abstract The paper studies operating system adoption decisions

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* University of Florida Department of Economics, P.O.Box 117140 Gainesville, FL 32611-7140 Email: lifan51@ufl.edu Tel:1-352-846-5475

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman Working Paper 11407 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11407 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

The Agency and Wholesale Models in Electronic Content Markets

The Agency and Wholesale Models in Electronic Content Markets The Agency and Wholesale Models in Electronic Content Markets Justin P. Johnson July 11, 2018 Abstract. I analyze a model of dynamic competition between retail platforms which exhibit consumer lock-in.

More information

Volume 29, Issue 4. Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition

Volume 29, Issue 4. Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition Volume 29, Issue 4 Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition Oksana Loginova University of Missouri-Columbia X. Henry Wang University of Missouri-Columbia Abstract We study

More information

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of 137 Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of BMW 1,3,5,7. Hyperlink Harald Schmidt Show: rtsp://streamer2.streaming.szm.de/sat1/schmidt/media//03/03/20/procter_56.rm

More information

The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure

The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure Forthcoming in W. Lehr (ed.), Quality and Reliability of Telecommunications Infrastructure. Lawrence Erlbaum. Hillsdale, NJ: 1995. The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure by Nicholas Economides

More information

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009 Outline Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization Session 2 K. Graddy The Coase Conjecture and Price Skimming Sales Non linear pricing Two part tariffs and the Disneyland monopolist Geographical

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 19, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 31 November 19, 2015 1 / 32 Introduction We are now

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO.

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. 2008-14 ASYMMETRIC MARKET SHARES, ADVERTISING, AND PRICING: EQUILIBRIUM

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Kopányi, D. (2015). Bounded rationality and learning in market competition Amsterdam: Tinbergen Institute

Citation for published version (APA): Kopányi, D. (2015). Bounded rationality and learning in market competition Amsterdam: Tinbergen Institute UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) Bounded rationality and learning in market competition Kopányi, D. Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Kopányi, D. (2015). Bounded rationality

More information

Monopoly. Firm s equilibrium. Muhammad Rafi Khan

Monopoly. Firm s equilibrium. Muhammad Rafi Khan 1 Monopoly It is a type of market structure where there is only one producer and many buyers. The monopolist produces an industry s entire output. In contrast to perfectly competitive firms, which are

More information

A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing

A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing Jean J. Gabszewicz and Filomena Garcia CORE Discussion Paper 2005/95 Abstract We obtain explicitly the optimal path of prices for a monopolist operating

More information

PRICE SETTING IN A DIFFERENTIATED-PRODUCT DUOPOLY WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION ABOUT DEMAND BY MIGUEL ÁNGEL ROPERO 1

PRICE SETTING IN A DIFFERENTIATED-PRODUCT DUOPOLY WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION ABOUT DEMAND BY MIGUEL ÁNGEL ROPERO 1 PRICE SETTING IN A DIFFERENTIATED-PRODUCT DUOPOLY WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION ABOUT DEMAND BY MIGUEL ÁNGEL ROPERO 1 Department of Applied Economics, University of Malaga, Spain. ABSTRACT This paper explores

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 Monopolistic markets and pricing with market power (PR 10.1-10.4 and 11.1-11.4) Module 4 Sep. 20, 2014

More information

EconS Bertrand Competition

EconS Bertrand Competition EconS 425 - Bertrand Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 38 Introduction Today, we

More information

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 14: Intellectual Property Rights and Patent Policy

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 14: Intellectual Property Rights and Patent Policy Economics of Industrial Organization Lecture 14: Intellectual Property Rights and Patent Policy Patents; government-granted monopoly We have spent much of this course consider the problems of monopoly

More information