NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THEORIES OF HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS AND TRADE. Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THEORIES OF HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS AND TRADE. Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper"

Transcription

1 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THEORIES OF HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS AND TRADE Stephen J. Redding Working Paper NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA December 2010 The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research by Stephen J. Redding. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

2 Theories of Heterogeneous Firms and Trade Stephen J. Redding NBER Working Paper No December 2010 JEL No. F1,L80 ABSTRACT This paper reviews the recent theoretical literature on heterogeneous firms and trade, which emphasizes firm selection into international markets and reallocations of resources across firms. We discuss the empirical challenges that motivated this research and its relationship to traditional trade theories. We examine the implications of firm heterogeneity for comparative advantage, market size, aggregate trade, the welfare gains from trade, and the relationship between trade and income distribution. While a number of studies examine the endogenous response of firm productivity to trade liberalization, modeling internal firm organization and the origins of firm heterogeneity remain interesting areas of ongoing research. Stephen J. Redding Department of Economics and Woodrow Wilson School Princeton University Fisher Hall Princeton NJ and CEPR reddings@princeton.edu

3 Contents 1 Introduction 3 2 Empirical Challenges 4 3 The Melitz Model Preferences and Endowments Production Technology Production and Exporting Decisions Steady-state Industry Equilibrium Trade Liberalization and Intra-industry Reallocation Welfare Pareto Distribution Summary Integrated Equilibrium 13 5 Trade and Market Size 15 6 Gravity 18 7 Quantitative Analysis 20 8 Labor Markets 22 9 Endogenous Firm Productivity Multi-Product Firms Technology and Skills International Production Networks Firm and Aggregate Dynamics Conclusion 30 2

4 1 Introduction Theoretical research in international trade increasingly emphasizes the decisions of individual plants and firms in understanding the causes and consequences of aggregate trade. This new theoretical emphasis is a response to empirical studies using micro data, which revealed a number of features of producer behavior that were not well explained by pre-existing theories of international trade. There is substantial heterogeneity in productivity, size and other economic characteristics even within narrowly-defined industries. Participation in international trade is relatively rare and is associated with superior values of productivity and other measures of economic performance. Trade liberalization is accompanied by reallocations of resources within industries, which raise average industry productivity, as low productivity suppliers exit and high productivity suppliers expand to enter international markets. Trade liberalization is also accompanied by endogenous changes in firm productivity, which in turn influence within-industry resource allocation. This paper reviews the recent theoretical literature on heterogeneous firms and trade inspired by these empirical findings. We begin in Section 2 by briefly summarizing the main empirical features of micro data on plants and firms that have influenced the development of theoretical research. Section 3 introduces the Melitz (2003) model, which accounts for these main features of the micro data, and has become a key benchmark framework in international trade for analyzing a whole host of issues. 1 The Melitz model can be embedded within the integrated equilibrium framework of traditional trade theory, as shown in Section 4. The resulting framework explains why countries export more in some industries rather than others ( inter-industry trade ), why nonetheless there is two-way trade within industries ( intra-industry trade ), and why in industries engaged in the two forms of trade some firms participate in international markets while many others do not. Modeling firm heterogeneity leads to a number of new insights concerning the determinants and effects of international trade, including the role of market size (Section 5) and the well-known gravity equation in international trade (Section 6). These theories have also been quantitatively successful in explaining patterns of aggregate and disaggregate trade, as reviewed in Section 7. While theories of firm heterogeneity and trade stress reallocations of resources across firms, the benchmark model of firm heterogeneity features a frictionless labor market. As a result, all workers are employed at a common wage and are affected symmetrically by the opening of trade. More recent research has emphasized labor market imperfections, such as search frictions, and the way in which these can influence the income distributional effects of trade liberalization across workers, as discussed in Section 8. 1 While we focus on the Melitz model and other related approaches in the light of its theoretical influence and empirical success, alternative approaches to modeling firm heterogeneity and trade include Bernard et al. (2003) and Yeaple (2005). 3

5 Although models of firm heterogeneity and trade often treat firm productivity as fixed and focus on selection and reallocation across firms, a number of studies have modeled endogenous firm productivity and organization, as discussed in Section 9. This line of research has considered several dimensions of firm decisions, including the vertical integration decision, the choice of product mix, investments in new technologies, and adjustments to the skill composition of the workforce. While the theoretical literature on heterogeneous firms and trade has advanced rapidly in breadth and depth, there remain areas that are relatively unexplored, and Section 11 offers some concluding comments about possible areas for further research. 2 Empirical Challenges As micro data on plants and firms became increasingly available from the late 1980s and early 1990s onwards, a number of empirical challenges for existing theories of international trade began to emerge. 2 One of the most striking features of these micro data is the tremendous heterogeneity in productivity, size and other economic characteristics, even within narrowly-defined industries. In influential work, Bernard & Jensen (1995, 1999) showed that this heterogeneity is systematically related to trade participation. Within an industry, some firms export while many others do not and, even among exporters, the fraction of shipments exported is often small. Exporters are larger, more productive, and pay higher wages than other firms within the same industry. 3 Additionally, exporters are observed in both net exporting and net importing industries, although the fraction of exporting firms and the fraction of exported output vary across industries with correlates of comparative advantage. None of these features of the data are well explained by existing theories of international trade, with their assumption of a representative firm within industries. In comparative-advantage-based models, such as the Heckscher-Ohlin model, the emphasis is on net trade across industries ( inter-industry trade ), and the assumptions of perfect competition and constant returns to scale often imply that firm size is indeterminate. In variety-based models, such as Krugman (1980), firms specialize in distinct horizontally-differentiated varieties and there is two-way trade within industries ( intra-industry trade ), but consumer love of variety typically implies that all firms export. Further evidence relating firm heterogeneity and trade participation comes from empirical studies of trade 2 For a more detailed discussion of this empirical literature, see Bernard, Jensen, Redding & Schott (2007). For complementary theoretical reviews of the literatures on firms, organizations and trade, see Antràs & Rossi-Hansberg (2009) and Helpman (2006). 3 The finding that exporters are more productive than non-exporters within industries raises the question of the direction of causality between exporting and productivity. While there is substantial evidence of selection into exporting, there is less evidence of learning by exporting. This literature is reviewed in Lopez (2005) and, more recently, a number of papers have provided evidence that exporting enhances incentives for technology adoption, as discussed in Section 9. 4

6 liberalization episodes. While traditional trade theories emphasize reallocation across industries, much of the observed reallocation in the aftermath of trade liberalization is found to occur across firms within narrowlydefined industries (e.g. Levinsohn 1999). Trade liberalizations are accompanied by the exit of low productivity plants and firms and increases in aggregate industry productivity through the resulting changes in industry composition. While much of the evidence of these intra-industry reallocations comes from studies of largescale trade liberalizations in developing countries (e.g. Tybout & Westbrook 1991, Pavcnik 2003), similar results hold for developed countries (e.g. Bernard, Jensen & Schott 2006, Trefler 2004). Another related feature of micro data is ongoing reallocation and selection even in the absence of trade liberalization or other large-scale changes. In U.S. Census Data, around one third of plants enter or exit every five years, and there are systematic differences in productivity, size and other economic characteristics between exiters and survivors (see in particular Dunne et al. 1989). Similarly, gross job creation and destruction at the plant level are large relative to net changes in industry employment, and these rates of job creation and destruction are positively correlated across industries (see in particular Davis & Haltiwanger 1992). None of these features are well explained by existing theories of international trade, with their abstraction from firm and industry dynamics. 3 The Melitz Model The Melitz (2003) model addresses the above empirical challenges by combining a model of industry equilibrium featuring heterogeneous firm productivity, as in Jovanovic (1982) and Hopenhayn (1990), with a model of trade based on love of variety preferences and increasing returns to scale, as in Krugman (1980) Preferences and Endowments The world consists of many countries, such that each country trades with n 1 foreign countries. We begin by considering the case of symmetric countries, before discussing in a later section country asymmetries. Labor is the sole factor of production in inelastic supply L for each country and is immobile across countries. Consumer preferences are defined over consumption of a continuum of horizontally-differentiated varieties within an industry. Preferences take the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) or Dixit & Stiglitz (1977) form: [ ] 1 C = q(ω) ρ ρ dω, 0 < ρ < 1, (1) ω Ω 4 Derivations of expressions in this and subsequent sections are contained in a web appendix. 5

7 where ω indexes varieties, Ω is the (endogenous) set of varieties, and the price index dual to (1) is: [ P = p(ω) 1 σ dω ω Ω ] 1 1 σ, σ = 1 1 ρ > 1, where σ corresponds to the elasticity of substitution between varieties. The model can be interpreted as capturing an industry within an economy. The assumption of CES preferences implies a strong love of variety : there is diminishing marginal utility from the consumption of any given variety; utility is increasing in the measure of varieties consumed; and the marginal utility from consumption of any given variety approaches infinity as consumption approaches zero. Given these preferences, the revenue for a variety supplied to the domestic market is: ( ) pd (ω) 1 σ r d (ω) = R, (2) P where p d (ω) is the price of variety ω in the domestic market; R denotes aggregate revenue, which equals aggregate income, which equals aggregate expenditure; the price index P summarizes the prices of competing varieties. 3.2 Production Technology There is a competitive fringe of potential entrants that can enter by paying a sunk entry cost of f e units of labor. Potential entrants face uncertainty about their productivity in the industry. Once the sunk entry cost is paid, a firm draws its productivity ϕ from a fixed distribution, g(ϕ). As firms with the same productivity behave symmetrically, we index firms from now on by ϕ alone. Productivity remains fixed after entry, but firms face a constant exogenous probability of death δ, which induces steady-state entry and exit of firms in the model. The assumption that the probability of firm death is uncorrelated with firm productivity is strong. However, the model still captures empirical findings that exiting firms are on average of lower productivity than surviving firms, because, among the cohort of entering firms each period, those that draw low productivity exit immediately as discussed below. The market structure is monopolistic competition. Production of each variety involves a fixed production cost of f d units of labor and a constant variable cost that depends on firm productivity. The total labor required to produce q(ϕ) units of a variety is therefore: l(ϕ) = f d + q(ϕ) ϕ. 6

8 With CES preferences, the fixed production cost is central to matching empirical findings that exiting firms are on average of lower productivity than surviving firms, because firms that draw a sufficiently low productivity cannot generate enough variable profits to cover the fixed production cost. If firms decide to export, they face a fixed exporting cost of f x units of labor and iceberg variable costs of trade, such that τ > 1 units of each variety must be exported in order for one unit to arrive in a foreign country. With CES preferences, the fixed exporting cost is key to matching empirical findings that only the most productive firms export, because only firms that draw a sufficiently high productivity can generate enough variable profits to cover the fixed exporting cost. Otherwise, in the presence of only variable trade costs, all firms would export, since CES preferences imply that the marginal utility of consuming any given variety approaches infinity as consumption of that variety approaches zero. 3.3 Production and Exporting Decisions As each firm supplies one of a continuum of varieties, it is of measure zero relative to the industry as a whole, and hence takes the aggregate price index as given. The first-order condition for profit maximization yields the standard result that equilibrium prices are a mark-up over marginal cost that depends on the elasticity of demand. Given the same constant elasticity of demand in the domestic and export markets, equilibrium prices in the export market are a constant multiple of those in the domestic market due to the variable costs of trade: p x (ϕ) = τp d (ϕ) = τ ( ) σ wd σ 1 ϕ = τ ρϕ, (3) where we choose the wage in one country as the numeraire and use country symmetry. Together these imply w = 1 for all countries. 5 Substituting the pricing rule into firm revenue (2), we obtain the following expression for equilibrium firm revenue in the export market, r x (ϕ), and in the domestic market, r d (ϕ): r x (ϕ) = τ 1 σ r d (ϕ) = τ 1 σ (ρϕ) σ 1 RP σ 1. (4) In deriving this expression for equilibrium revenue, firm varieties were assumed to enter utility symmetrically 5 Horizontal product differentiation and the pricing rule (3) have implications for empirical measures of productivity. The representation of consumer preferences (1), in which varieties enter utility symmetrically, implicitly imposes a choice of units in which to measure the quantity of each variety. There is no necessary relationship between this normalization and the units in which physical quantities of output are measured for each firm in the data. As a result, data on physical quantities of output cannot be directly compared across firms, and revenue rather than quantity-based empirical measures of productivity are appropriate. Additionally, the constant mark-up implied by CES preferences in (3) ensures that firm prices are inversely proportional to firm productivity. Hence revenue-based measures of productivity, p (ϕ) q (ϕ) /l (ϕ), only vary across firms because of the fixed costs. More productive firms have higher variable labor input and higher revenue, with the result that the fixed labor input is spread over more units of revenue. 7

9 in (1). However, it is straightforward to allow for different weights for each firm variety to capture, for example, differences in product quality. With CES preferences and monopolistic competition, product quality enters firm revenue in the same way as firm productivity. 6 From equilibrium revenue (4), the relative revenue of any two firms within the same market depends solely on their relative productivities: r d (ϕ ) r d (ϕ ) = r x(ϕ ) r x (ϕ ) = ( ) ϕ σ 1, (5) ϕ Additionally, from equilibrium revenue (4), the relative revenue of a firm with a given productivity in the domestic and export markets depends solely on variable trade costs. Together these two features of relative revenues greatly simplify the characterization of industry equilibrium. Consumer love of variety and a fixed production cost imply that no firm would ever export without also serving the domestic market. Therefore we can apportion the entire fixed production cost to the domestic market and the fixed exporting cost to the foreign market. 7 Adopting this convenient accounting device, the pricing rule (3) implies that variable profits in each market are proportional to revenue, while firm profits in each market equal variable profits minus the relevant fixed cost: π x (ϕ) = r x(ϕ) σ f x, π d (ϕ) = r d(ϕ) σ f d. (6) The fixed production cost implies that there is a zero-profit cutoff productivity (ϕ d ) below which firms would make negative profits if they entered, and hence they exit immediately: r d (ϕ d ) = (ρϕ d )σ 1 RP σ 1 = σf d. (7) Similarly, the fixed exporting cost implies that there is an exporting cutoff productivity (ϕ x) below which surviving firms would make negative profits if they exported, and hence they serve only the domestic market: r x (ϕ x) = τ 1 σ (ρϕ x) σ 1 RP σ 1 = σf x. (8) 6 An empirical literature has sought to use variation in unit values (revenue divided by physical quantity) to distinguish between models of horizontal product differentiation featuring productivity and quality differences across firms, including Baldwin & Harrigan (2007) and Johnson (2009). As discussed in footnote 5, there is no necessary relationship between the normalization imposed by the symmetric demand representation (1) and the units in which physical quantities of output are measured for each firm in the data. As a result, data on physical quantities of output cannot be directly compared across firms in the presence of horizontal product differentiation, which complicates the interpretation of variation in unit values across firms. 7 This is merely a convenient accounting device. Instead of analyzing the decision to export by comparing export profits to the fixed exporting cost, we could instead equivalently compare the sum of domestic and export profit profits to the sum of the fixed production and exporting costs. 8

10 Combining the zero-profit and exporting cutoff conditions, (7) and (8), with the relationship between variety revenues within the same market (5), we obtain the following relationship between the two productivity cutoffs: ϕ x = Λϕ d, ( ) 1 Λ τ fx σ 1. (9) f d Therefore, for sufficiently high values of fixed and variable trade costs, the model features selection into export markets: Λ > 1. 8 Only the most productive firms export, while intermediate productivity firms serve only the domestic market, and low productivity firms exit Steady-state Industry Equilibrium The steady-state industry equilibrium is characterized by constant masses of firms entering, producing and exporting, as well as stationary ex post distributions of productivity among producing and exporting firms. With firm productivity fixed at entry and a constant independent probability of firm death, these stationary ex post distributions for productivity take a particularly tractable form. The ex post productivity distributions in the domestic and export markets, µ d (ϕ) and µ x (ϕ) respectively, are truncations of the ex ante productivity distribution, g(ϕ), at the zero-profit and exporting cutoff productivities respectively: µ d (ϕ) = g(ϕ) 1 G(ϕ d ) if ϕ ϕ d 0 otherwise, µ x (ϕ) = g(ϕ) 1 G(ϕ x ) if ϕ ϕ x 0 otherwise. (10) In an equilibrium with positive firm entry, we require that the free entry condition holds, which equates the expected value of entry to the sunk entry cost. The expected value of entry depends on the value of a firm with each productivity ϕ, which equals the maximum of zero (if the firm exits) and the net present value of the stream of future profits (if the firm enters). Assuming, for simplicity, no time discounting, the value of a firm with productivity ϕ is: { v(ϕ) = max 0, π(ϕ) }. δ The free entry condition therefore takes the following form: v e = [1 G(ϕ d )] π δ = [1 G(ϕ d )] [ π d + χn π x ] δ = f e, (11) 8 Empirical estimates of the fixed costs of exporting are typically large: see for example Das et al. (2007) and Roberts & Tybout (1997). Arkolakis (2008) argues that these large values for fixed costs are hard to reconcile with small export shipments and proposes instead a model of endogenous market entry costs, which is discussed further below. 9 While the discussion here concentrates on exporting, Helpman et al. (2004) extend the analysis to consider exporting and horizontal foreign direct investment (FDI) as alternative modes of serving foreign markets. 9

11 where the expected value of entry equals the probability of successful entry, [1 G(ϕ d )], times expected profits conditional on successful entry, π. Expected profits conditional on successful entry equal expected profits in the domestic market conditional on serving that market, π d, plus the probability of exporting, χ = [1 G(ϕ x)]/[1 G(ϕ d )], times the number of export markets, n, times expected profits in each export market conditional on serving that market, π x. Expected profits in the domestic and export markets, π d and π x, themselves depend on the ex post productivity distributions (10). In a steady-state equilibrium with a constant mass of firms producing, we also require that the mass of successful entrants that draw a productivity above the zero-profit cutoff equals the mass of firms that die, which yields the following steady-state stability condition: [1 G(ϕ d )] M e = δm d, (12) where M e denotes the mass of entrants and M d denotes the mass of producing firms. While aggregate variables, such as the price index, depend on integrals over values for firm productivity, the assumption of CES preferences again greatly simplifies the analysis, because all aggregate variables can be written in terms of a weighted average of firm productivity. As a result, aggregate variables in the Melitz model take the same value as in a model in which all firms have a common productivity equal to weighted-average productivity, but weighted-average productivity is itself endogenously determined by firm decisions. Using the equilibrium pricing rule (3), the zero-profit and exporting cutoff productivities, (7) and (8) respectively, the ex post productivity distributions (10), and country symmetry, we obtain the following expression for the price index: P = [ M d p d ( ϕ d ) 1 σ + χnm d τ 1 σ p d ( ϕ x ) 1 σ] 1 1 σ 1 σ = Mt p( ϕ t ) 1 where M t = (1 + χn) M d ; weighted-average productivities in the domestic and export markets, ϕ d and ϕ x, are defined in the web appendix and depend solely on the zero-profit and exporting cutoff productivities, ϕ d and ϕ x; overall weighted average productivity, ϕ t, is itself a weighted average of ϕ d and ϕ x, as also defined in the web appendix. These weighted-average productivities correspond to theoretically-consistent measures of aggregate productivity derived from the CES ideal price index From (4), q d (ϕ)/q( ϕ) = (ϕ/ ϕ d ) σ, which implies that ϕ d can be written as ϕ d = ϕ 1 [q(ϕ/q( ϕ))] [g(ϕ)/ (1 G(ϕ ϕ d ))] dϕ. d Therefore, ϕ d is the weighted harmonic mean of the ϕ s, where the weights (q d (ϕ)/q( ϕ)) are firms relative output shares. The interpretation of ϕ x is directly analogous. 10

12 With symmetric countries, the steady-state industry equilibrium can be referenced by a quadruple {ϕ d, ϕ x, R, P }, in terms of which all other endogenous variables of the model can be written. As the model has a recursive structure, it is straightforward to determine this steady-state equilibrium for a general continuous productivity distribution, as shown in the web appendix. 3.5 Trade Liberalization and Intra-industry Reallocation To examine the comparative statics of opening the closed economy to trade, we compare the steady-state equilibria in the closed and open economy. 11 Using the relationship between variety revenues and the zeroprofit and exporting cutoff conditions, the free entry condition (11) can be written as: v e = f d δ ϕ d [ ( ) ϕ σ 1 1] g(ϕ)dϕ + nf x δ ϕ d ϕ x [ ( ) ϕ σ 1 1] g(ϕ)dϕ = f e. (13) ϕ x Substituting for ϕ x = Λϕ d from the relationship between the productivity cutoffs (9), a unique equilibrium value of the zero-profit cutoff productivity, ϕ d, can be determined independently of the other endogenous variables of the model. Having determined ϕ d, the exporting cutoff productivity, ϕ x, follows immediately from the relationship between the productivity cutoffs (9). The free entry condition (13) defines a downward-sloping relationship between ϕ x and ϕ d, where the closed economy free entry condition corresponds to the limiting case of infinitely large trade costs, where ϕ x. As the closed economy opens to trade and the exporting cutoff productivity, ϕ x, falls to a finite value, the zeroprofit cutoff productivity, ϕ d, must rise in order for the expected value of entry in (13) to remain equal to the unchanged sunk entry cost. Intuitively, the opening of trade increases expected profitability in the industry, π, because of the positive probability of drawing a productivity sufficiently high to export, which implies that the probability of successful entry, [1 G (ϕ d )], must fall to restore equality between the expected value of entry and the sunk entry cost. While we have derived these results for the opening of the closed economy to trade, similar results hold for reductions in variable trade costs in the open economy equilibrium. The rise in the zero-profit cutoff productivity, ϕ d, induced by trade liberalization leads to within-industry reallocations of resources across firms. There is exit by low-productivity firms with productivities above the old but below the new zero-profit cutoff. Additionally, intermediate-productivity firms that serve only the domestic market experience a contraction in revenue as a result of the rise in the zero-profit cutoff, since r d (ϕ) = (ϕ/ϕ d )σ 1 σf d. While high-productivity exporting firms also experience a contraction in revenue in 11 Following the opening of trade, there are transition dynamics from the closed to the open economy steady-state equilibrium (see for example Chaney 2005). In a later section, we follow much of the literature in considering a static version of the Melitz model, with no exogenous firm death and no steady-state entry and exit of firms. 11

13 the domestic market, they enjoy an expansion in revenue in the export market. As shown in the web appendix, the expansion in export market revenue dominates, so that the total revenue of high-productivity exporting firms rises. Each of these firm responses induces reallocations of resources towards more productive firms, which raises aggregate productivity. 12 The mechanism behind these within-industry reallocations of resources is the differential impact of trade liberalization on exporters and non-exporters. In the special case where fixed exporting costs are equal to zero (f x = 0), all firms export and the opening of trade has no effect on the zero-profit cutoff productivity, because the open economy free entry condition (13) takes exactly the same form as in the closed economy. Although the opening of trade leads to entry by foreign varieties into the domestic market, which reduces the domestic price index, this reduction in the price index has a symmetric effect on the domestic revenue of all firms in (4). As a result, there is a change in the mass of firms at each productivity, M d g(ϕ)/[1 G(ϕ d )], but no change in the zero-profit cutoff productivity below which firms exit Welfare Indirect utility in both the closed and open economy can be expressed solely in terms of the zero-profit productivity cutoff below which firms exit: V = 1 P = ρ ( L σf ) 1/(σ 1) ϕ d. As the opening of trade raises the zero-profit productivity cutoff below which firms exit, ϕ d, there are necessarily welfare gains from trade in the Melitz model. While theories of international trade have typically emphasized comparative advantage and product variety as sources of welfare gains from trade, theories of heterogeneous firms and trade point to within-industry reallocations of resources as a new channel through which trade can affect welfare. We discuss in Section 6 below the implications of the introduction of this new welfare channel for the overall magnitude of the welfare gains from trade. 12 One caveat is that ϕ t takes into account output lost in transit (from τ), which implies that it is possible for ϕ t to be lower than the closed economy value of ϕ d when τ is high and f x is low. However, any productivity average based on output at the factory gate is necessarily higher in the open economy equilibrium with selection into export markets than in the closed economy equilibrium, as shown in Melitz (2003) and the web appendix. 13 From the relationship between the productivity cutoffs (9), there is a range of parameter values with positive fixed exporting costs for which all firms export. For this range of parameter values, the opening of trade does affect the zero-profit cutoff productivity in the free entry condition (13), but only because it increases fixed costs for all firms. As a result, some previously viable low productivity firms can no longer generate enough revenue to cover fixed costs and exit. 12

14 3.7 Pareto Distribution While the above analysis was undertaken for any continuous productivity distribution, the case of a Pareto productivity distribution has received particular attention in the literature and will be considered in a later section. In this case: g(ϕ) = kϕ k minϕ (k+1), G(ϕ) = 1 ( ϕmin ϕ ) k, (14) where ϕ min > 0 is the lower bound of the support of the productivity distribution; lower values of the shape parameter k correspond to greater dispersion in productivity; and we require k > (σ 1) for the distribution of firm revenue to have a finite mean. The Pareto distribution has two key attractive features for the Melitz model. First a random variable with this distribution remains Pareto distributed when it is truncated from below. Second the CES demand system implies that firm variables, such as revenue, are power functions of productivity, and a power function of a Pareto-distributed random variable is itself Pareto distributed. For these reasons, the model becomes particularly tractable for the case of a Pareto distribution, which has been found to provide a reasonable approximation to the observed distribution of firm size (e.g. Axtell 2001). 3.8 Summary Taken together, the Melitz model addresses each of the empirical challenges discussed above. The model features producer heterogeneity, steady-state entry and exit of firms, and the accompanying steady-state job creation and destruction. With positive fixed exporting costs, and for sufficiently large values of fixed and variable trade costs, only some firms export. These exporting firms are larger and more productive than firms that only serve the domestic market. And for values of trade costs for which there is selection into export markets, trade liberalization induces reallocations of resources across firms within industries, as low-productivity firms exit and high-productivity firms expand to enter export markets. 4 Integrated Equilibrium While the Melitz model emphasizes reallocations of resources within industries, traditional theories of international trade, such as the Heckscher-Ohlin model, stress comparative advantage and reallocation across industries. In this section, we review Bernard, Redding & Schott (2007), which embeds the Melitz model within the standard framework of general equilibrium trade theory using the concept of integrated equilibrium, as used in Dixit & Norman (1980) and Helpman & Krugman (1985). 13

15 Consider a world of two countries (home and foreign), two industries (good one and good two) and two factors of production (skilled and unskilled labor). Home is assumed to be skill-abundant relative to foreign. Consumer preferences are identical and homothetic and for simplicity the upper-tier of utility across the two sectors is assumed to take the Cobb-Douglas form. Within each sector, preferences are defined over consumption of a continuum of horizontally differentiated varieties as in the previous section: ( U = q 1 (ω) ρ dω ω Ω 1 ) α ρ ( ω Ω2 ) 1 α q 2 (ω) ρ dω ρ, 0 < α < 1. As in the standard Heckscher-Ohlin model, production technologies are the same across countries but differ in factor intensity across industries. Good one is assumed to be skill-intensive relative to good 2. In each sector, there is a fixed production cost and a constant variable cost that depends on firm productivity. The production technology is assumed to be homothetic, so that the fixed and variable cost use the two factors of production with the same intensity. Therefore the total cost of producing q(ϕ) units of a variety in sector i is: Γ i = [ f i + q ] i(ϕ) (w S ) β i (w L ) 1 β i, 1 > β ϕ 1 > β 2 > 0 where w S is the skilled wage and w L is the unskilled wage. When fixed and variable trade costs are equal to zero, the concept of integrated equilibrium can be used to determine the set of factor allocations to the two countries for which trade in goods alone can equalize factor prices. Within this factor price equalization set, the four theorems of the Heckscher-Ohlin model the Factor Price Equalization, Stolper-Samuelson, Rybczynski and Heckscher-Ohlin Theorems continue to hold in the presence of firm heterogeneity. When fixed and variable trade costs are not equal to zero, factor price equalization breaks down and, for parameter values for which there is selection into export markets, the opening of trade results in intra-industry reallocations across firms. As these intra-industry reallocations are driven by the differential impact of the opening of trade on exporters and non-exporters, they are stronger in the comparative advantage industry, where export opportunities are relatively more attractive. Although there is a decline in the relative mass of firms in the comparative disadvantage industry, as factors of production are reallocated in accordance with comparative advantage, exit by low productivity firms is strongest in the comparative advantage industry. Thus the opening of trade leads to a larger increase in the zero-profit cutoff and in average productivity in the comparative advantage industry than in the comparative disadvantage industry. This differential impact of the opening of trade across sectors according to Heckscher-Ohlin-based comparative advantage influences both the welfare 14

16 gains from trade and the income distributional consequences of trade liberalization. 5 Trade and Market Size While the Melitz model captures reallocations of resources across firms within industries, the property of constant mark-ups imposed by CES preferences stands at odds with empirical studies of trade liberalization episodes, which typically find pro-competitive effects (see for example Tybout 2003). Relatedly, the CES demand structure implies that the within-industry productivity distribution is invariant to market size, which only affects the mass of firms. In contrast to these predictions, Campbell & Hopenhayn (2005) present empirical evidence that retail establishments in larger markets have higher sales and employment. Similarly, Syverson (2004) examines the concrete industry as an example of a good with high transport costs, and finds that larger markets have both higher average plant size and higher average productivity. In this section, we consider the Melitz & Ottaviano (2008) model of firm heterogeneity, which features quasi-linear preferences between a homogeneous and differentiated sector and quadratic preferences across varieties within the differentiated sector. As a result, mark-ups in the differentiated sector vary endogenously with firm productivity, market size and trade integration. 14 Labor is the sole factor of production and each country i is endowed with L i workers. The representative consumer s preferences in each country are defined over consumption of a continuum of differentiated varieties, q c ω, and consumption of a homogeneous good, q c 0 : U = q0 c + α qωdω c 1 ω Ω 2 γ (qω) c 2 dω 1 ( 2 ω Ω 2 η qωdω) c, ω Ω where higher α and lower η increase demand for differentiated varieties relative to the numeraire, while higher γ implies greater love of variety, with γ = 0 corresponding to the special case of perfect substitutes. Each country s labor endowment is assumed to be sufficiently large that it both consumes and produces the homogeneous good, which is chosen as the numeraire, so that p c 0 = 1. Using the first-order conditions for utility maximization, the inverse demand curve for a differentiated variety is: p ω = α γqω c ηq c, Q c = ω Ω q c ωdω, where demand for a variety is positive if p ω α ηq c, which defines a choke price above which demand 14 Other possible frameworks for modeling firm heterogeneity with endogenous mark-ups include Bertrand competition in Bernard et al. (2003), translog preferences and monopolistic competition following Feenstra (2003), and Constant Absolute Risk Aversion preferences and monopolistic competition following Behrens & Murata (2006). 15

17 for a variety is zero. The homogeneous good is produced under conditions of perfect competition and constant returns to scale with a unit labor requirement. Differentiated varieties are produced under conditions of monopolistic competition and constant returns to scale. To enter the differentiated sector, a firm must incur a sunk entry cost of f e units of labor, after which its unit labor requirement or cost, c, is drawn from a cumulative distribution function G (c) with support on [0, c M ], where this cost draw is the inverse of the productivity draw considered in Section 3 above. As firms with the same cost, c, behave symmetrically, firms are indexed from now on by c alone. If a firm decides to export, it faces iceberg variable costs of trade, such that τ j > 1 units of a variety must be exported to country j in order for one unit to arrive. With quadratic preferences in the differentiated sector, the marginal utility of consuming a differentiated variety is finite at zero consumption. Therefore fixed production costs and fixed exporting costs are not needed to generate firm exit and selection into export markets respectively. Firms drawing a marginal cost above the choke price in the domestic market exit in equilibrium, because they cannot generate positive profits from production. Additionally, a firm s marginal costs may lie below the choke price in the domestic market, but may be above the choke price in the foreign market once variable trade costs have been taken into account. Thus sufficiently high variable trade costs are enough to induce selection into export markets. The consideration of equilibria where each country both consumes and produces the homogeneous good greatly simplifies the analysis. As long as the homogeneous good is produced, productivity in this sector pins down the wage in each country as equal to one. Additionally, as long as the homogeneous good is consumed, quasi-linear preferences imply that the demand for differentiated varieties can be determined independently of income. A key advantage of these features is the resulting tractability of the model, which means that it can be used to consider multiple countries with arbitrary differences in country size and physical geography (variable trade costs). A disadvantage is that changes in income are accommodated solely through changes in consumption of the homogeneous good and have no general equilibrium effects in the differentiated sector. As markets are assumed to be segmented and the production technology exhibits constant returns to scale, the supplier of each differentiated variety maximizes independently the profits earned from domestic and export sales. 15 Using the first-order conditions for utility and profit maximization, firm variables such as the price in the domestic and export market can be determined solely as a function of a firm s own cost and the cost cutoff 15 Using the equilibrium pricing rules derived below, it can be shown that equilibrium variety prices are such that there exist no profitable arbitrage opportunities across markets. 16

18 above which it is not profitable to serve a market: p i d (c) = 1 ( c i 2 d + c ), p i x (c) = τ j ( c i 2 x + c ), where countries are indexed by i and j; c i d is the cost cutoff in the domestic market for country i; ci x is the cost cutoff for firms exporting from country i to j; and c i x = c j d /τ j. From the above equilibrium pricing rule, more productive firms again charge lower prices, but linear demand implies that firms charging lower prices face more inelastic demand, and hence they choose optimally to set a higher mark-up of price over marginal cost. As a result, the lower costs of more productive firms are not fully passed on to consumers in the form of lower prices. 16 To characterize the model s comparative statics, we follow Melitz & Ottaviano (2008) in assuming that firm productivity 1/c follows a Pareto distribution, as discussed in Section 3 above, with lower productivity bound 1/c M and shape parameter k > 1. In this case, the cumulative distribution function of firm costs is given by G(c) = (c/c M ) k for c [0, c M ]. We begin by considering the closed economy, which again corresponds to the limiting case of infinitely large trade costs, where c i x 0. With quasi-linear preferences, market size (the measure of consumers L) affects the closed economy cost cutoff. Larger markets are characterized by greater product market competition, with lower cost cutoffs (c D ), lower average costs ( c), lower average prices ( p), and a larger mass of product varieties (N). Comparing a large to a small market, some low productivity firms have marginal costs above the choke price in the larger market and exit, while surviving firms price on a more elastic segment of their demand curve, and hence charge lower mark-ups than in the smaller market. Therefore consumers in larger markets face lower average prices and enjoy higher welfare, because of both higher average productivity and lower average mark-ups. Opening the closed economy to trade has similar effects on the domestic market cost cutoff as an increase in closed economy market size. Consumers experience welfare gains from trade through lower average prices, because of both higher average productivity and lower average mark-ups. Once the economy is open to trade, unilateral, multilateral and preferential trade liberalization have distinct effects on welfare, because they have different effects on the entry and production decisions of differentiated-sector firms. 16 As firm prices now fall less than proportionately with firm productivity, revenue-based measures of productivity, p (ϕ) q (ϕ) /l (ϕ), vary across firms even in the absence of fixed costs. 17

19 6 Gravity One of the most successful empirical relationships in economics is the gravity equation, which relates the value of trade between countries to their size and the economic distance between them. Models of firm heterogeneity and trade have yielded new insights for the gravity equation by highlighting a distinction between the extensive margin (the measure of exporting firms) and the intensive margin (average exports conditional on exporting). To highlight this distinction, Chaney (2008) considers a version of the Melitz model with a Pareto productivity distribution and a fixed measure of potential firms rather than free entry. Subsequently, Arkolakis et al. (2008) have shown that the same results hold with free entry, and hence we follow their exposition. The specification of entry and production is similar to that in Section 3. A static version of the Melitz model is considered with a single differentiated sector; the world consists of many (potentially asymmetric) countries; 17 productivity follows the Pareto distribution (14); and fixed exporting costs are incurred in the consuming rather than the producing country. 18 Total exports from country i to destination market j can be written in terms of the extensive and intensive margins of exports: ( 1 G(ϕ ij ) X ij = 1 G(ϕ ii ) ) M i } {{ } extensive (ρϕ) σ 1 (τ ij w i ) 1 σ P σ 1 g (ϕ) ϕ j w j L j ( )dϕ, ij 1 G ϕ ij }{{} intensive where M i is the mass of producing firms in country i and w j L j is total income, which equals total expenditure on differentiated varieties, in destination market j; ϕ ij is the productivity cutoff for firms located in country i and serving destination market j; τ ii = 1 and τ ij > 1 for j i. Using the Pareto productivity distribution, we obtain: X ij = ( ϕ ii ϕ ij ) k σk M i w j f ij. (15) } k {{ σ + 1 } intensive } {{ } extensive Perhaps surprisingly, the intensive margin of trade is independent of variable trade costs with a Pareto productivity distribution. On the one hand, higher variable trade costs reduce exports of a given firm to a given country, which reduces average exports per firm. On the other hand, higher variable trade costs induce low productivity firms to exit the export market, which raises average exports per firm. With a Pareto productivity distribution these two effects exactly offset one another, so as to leave the intensive margin independent of variable trade costs. 17 For an analysis of asymmetries between a home and foreign country in a model with a differentiated and homogeneous sector, see Demidova (2008). 18 While we follow the specification in Arkolakis et al. (2008), whether fixed exporting costs are incurred in the consuming or producing country makes little difference. 18

20 Using total exports (15) and the equilibrium mass of producing firms in country i, the share of country j s expenditure on goods produced in country i, ϑ ij, can be evaluated as: ϑ ij = L iϕ k i min (τ ijw i ) k f 1 k/(σ 1) ij s L sϕ k s min (τ sjw s ) k f 1 k/(σ 1). (16) sj This expression for the trade share takes a familiar gravity equation form, where trade between countries i and j depends on both bilateral resistance (trade costs between i and j) and multilateral resistance (which summarizes trade costs between all countries s and j), as in Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003). The elasticity of the trade share with respect to variable trade costs depends not on the elasticity of substitution, σ, but on the parameter determining the dispersion of productivity, k. This feature is closely related to the property of the Pareto productivity distribution noted above, namely that changes in variable trade costs only affect trade flows through the extensive margin, where the extensive margin response depends on the dispersion of productivity. Notably, the trade share (16) takes a directly analogous form to that in Eaton & Kortum (2002), despite the stark differences between the two models: monopolistic competition and increasing returns to scale versus perfect competition and constant returns to scale. This similarity of the trade shares reflects the fact that, under the distributional assumptions of both models, variable trade costs only influence trade flows through the extensive margin. As shown in Arkolakis et al. (2008), further insight into the welfare gains from trade can be garnered by using the cutoff productivity conditions and the trade share (16) to write indirect utility as follows: V j = w j = ϑ 1/k jj P j L 1/(σ 1) j ϕk j min f 1 k/(σ 1) jj σ 1 ( ) k f σ e σ 1 σ k/(σ 1) k σ + 1 Since in the closed economy ϑ jj = 1, while in the open economy 0 < ϑ jj < 1, we again obtain the result that there are necessarily welfare gains from trade. Furthermore, a country s trade share with itself, ϑ jj, is a sufficient statistic for welfare in the sense that estimating the welfare gains from trade relative to autarky requires only a measure of a country s trade share with itself, ϑ jj, and an estimate of the elasticity of trade flows with respect to variable trade costs, k, which can be obtained from bilateral trade data. Notably, the property that the trade share is a sufficient statistic for welfare is shared with Eaton & Kortum (2002) and a wider class of models See Arkolakis et al. (2009) for an analysis of the class of models for which the trade share is such a sufficient statistic for welfare. Given the same trade share and the same elasticity of trade with respect to trade costs, this class of models implies the same welfare gains from trade. Of course, the trade share is an endogenous variable, which varies with the parameters of each model and in general can differ across models within this class. Though Atkeson & Burstein (2010) show that the free entry condition constrains the overall 1/k. 19