Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation

Similar documents
Traceability and labelling of GMOs as a framework for risk management in European Regulation

GMO & Food Safety. Presented By: Dr. Yasser Mostafa Quality & Food Safety Manager MARS KSA

The following are answers to frequently asked questions

Genetically Modified Crops

tractors. Using herbicides avoids that, while herbicide tolerant crops make the use of herbicides simpler.

GM Foods: Possible Risks and Opportunities. Dr. Frank Shotkoski, Cornell University, USA

Keywords: GMOs; biotechnology; labeling policy; trade disputes.

STUDY GUIDE ARE GMOS GOOD OR BAD? KEY TERMS: genes DNA genetically-modified

THE ECONOMICS OF AGROBIOTECHNOLOGY. J. Wesseler Social Science Department, Wageningen University, The Netherlands

Genetically Modified Organisms

PUBLIC PERCEPTION OF GM FOODS: IMPLICATIONS FOR FUTURE TECHNOLOGIES IN AGRICULTURE GIULIANO TOLUSSO CAES CONFERENCE JANUARY 12, 2017 OTTAWA, ON

New techniques in plant biotechnology - old deficiencies in risk assessment

Genetic Engineering in Agriculture

CONSUMER PERCEPTION AND GMOS IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

What Are GMOs? Why Do We Need GMOs?

TRANSGENIC CROPS CONSUMER CONCERNS

BIOSAFETY AND ENVIRONMENTAL ISSUES

Do consumers not care about biotech foods or do they just not read the labels?

Genetic Engineering: Genetically Modified Foods and You!

GMO Answers: Get to Know GMOs

Stewardship and Integrated Pest Management for generic / off patent GM crops

QUESTIONNAIRE about the socio-economic implications of the placing on the market of GMOs for cultivation. Contact Details

PROS AND CONS OF GMO FOODS

briefing false industry claims of increased biotech crop cultivation in europe

Genetics in the New Millennium: From Plants to People

Maize and Biodiversity: The Effects of Transgenic Maize in Mexico. Issues Summary. Prepared by Chantal Line Carpentier and Hans Herrmann

Genetically Modified Organisms

1 A Genetically Modified Solution? Th e u n i t e d n a t i o n s World Food Program has clearly stated, Hunger

GMO Crops, Trade Wars, and a New Site Specific Mutagensis System. A. Lawrence Christy, Ph.D.

EUROPEAN COMMISSION HEALTH AND FOOD SAFETY DIRECTORATE-GENERAL

Can GM crops contribute to food security and sustainable agricultural development?

GENETICALLY MODIFIED (GM) CROPS AND BIOSAFETY** Prof S.Kannaiyan*

CalsMUN 2019 Future Technology. Human Rights Council. Research Report. The morality of genetic modification. Bart van Donselaar and Labib Ehsan

HEALTH. hen was the last time you

IP IN AGRICULTURE PART 1. At van Rooy. 3 April 2017

Unit Plan 5: Bioethics

How much evidence does it take for EFSA to admit they are unsure about safety? The case of genetically modified herbicide resistant rice LL62.

Prospects of GM Crops and Regulatory considerations

Legal analysis: Release of genetically engineered organisms and the precautionary principle

ADOPTION AND IMPACT OF GENETICALLY MODIFIED (GM) CROPS IN AUSTRALIA:

CIEL. Codex, Substantial Equivalence and WTO Threats to National GMO Labeling Schemes. Matthew Stilwell and Brennan Van Dyke

Environmental Commission - Monitoring the use of biotechnology

Position Paper. Regulation of Plant Biotechnology Products Containing Two or More Traits Combined By Conventional Plant Breeding

Socio-economic aspects in the assessment of GMOs

Comparing Roundup Ready and Conventional Soybean Yields 1999

Genetically Engineered Crops in the United States

A GENE REVOLUTION. Can genetically engineered food help end hunger?

Pharmaceutical crops

Bugbears? Maize GE Benefits & Bugbears in the U.S. Benefits & Bugbears. Bugbears? Natural Corn Plant Sex. v , Purdue Univ.

An Analysis of McLean County, Illinois Farmers' Perceptions of Genetically Modified Crops

Biotechnology and its Applications

The public sector must promote organic food though public procurement

Asian Journal of Food and Agro-Industry ISSN Available online at

Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety. Dr. Manoranjan Hota Additional Director Ministry of Environment and Forests New Delhi

Brussels, September 2009 EFSA Conference Risk Assessment of GMOs for human health and the environment 1. of GM in Europe

Chapter 6: Plant Biotechnology

The EU Court of Justice extends the GMO Directive to gene-edited organisms Daniela Ruffell

World Trade Organization Activity

The Debates, Impacts, and Implications Surrounding Genetically Modified Crops in Third World Nations. Tamera Dandachi

Genetically engineered (GE) papaya threatens Thailand s farmers, consumers & the environment

Views, Experiences and Best Practices on the Implementation of Farmers Rights Submitted by Contracting Parties and Relevant Organizations

NewLeaf Potatoes: Friend or Foe A study of the GMO potato. By Rick Swenson English 320 Final Paper Dr. Sullivan 5/6/04

Treaties and Conventions Related to Management of Genetic Resources

Case Study One Open farming of genetically modified (GM) corn. Is it ethical?

The European Food Safety Authority and GMO Risk Assessment in the EU:

Introduction of Genetically Modified Wheat into Society: A Lose, Lose Situation

Overview on International Standards for Phytosanitary Measures (ISPMs) and their application to living modified organisms (LMOs)

Biotechnology Biotechnology is the application of a technological process, invention or method to living organisms

EUROPEAN COMMISSION AGRICULTURE DIRECTORATE-GENERAL DIRECTORATE-GENERAL JOINT RESEARCH CENTRE ARGUMENTAIRE ON CO-EXISTENCE OF GM CROPS

Genetically Engineered Crops: What are They? Who s Growing Them? Who s Eating Them? Who Cares?

Regulatory experiences and ideas. Steve Strauss Oregon State University

Draft COMMISSION DECISION

ECOLOGICAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL PROBLEMS RELATED TO HUMAN NEEDS

Genetically Modified (GM) crops are they safe to grow? Are

HIDDEN UNCERTAINTIES. What the European Commission doesn t want us to know about the risks of GMOs

Professor T V Price: Head of Dept. of Agriculture, The University of Vudal, Papua New Guinea

High- tech Food: Science In Your Shopping Cart

Food & Agricultural Biotechnology CPE Questions

What is DNA? Gene (skin colour) Gene (iris colour)

clarify the content and the use of the concepts of nature and naturalness in organic agriculture, to relate this conception to the bio-ethical literat

Farm Perspectives Study, 2014 Main Findings

GM-crops: Unintended effects

At the crossroadswhat future for plant breeding innovation in Europe?

Questions and Answers on the Regulation of GMOs in the European Union

Promises and Problems Associated with Agricultural Biotechnology

Question and Answers on the regulation of GMOs in the EU

QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS ON THE REGULATION OF GMOS IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

FOOD AND BIOTECHNOLOGY:

FINDINGS, ISSUES AND RECOMMENDATION. Introduction

BBC Learning English Talk about English Insight plus Part 17 GM crops

Unapproved genetically modified wheat from Monsanto found in Oregon field

Notes of Speech by Martin Khor (South Centre) at meeting in Oslo on development of Norway s Biosafety Regulations, Sept. 2012

CROP PRODUCTION AND BIOTECHNOLOGY: Successes and Challenges SUMMARY

Policy Discussion Paper

ACRE Consultation. Managing the Footprint of Agriculture: Towards a Comparative Assessment of Risks and Benefits for Novel Agricultural Systems

Green Payments Policy

Biosafety Issues and Risk Assessment in Transgenic Crops

FOOD QUALITY AND SAFETY. Overview of IPM

Muhammad Musa, Ph.D. Senior Program Specialist (Crops) SAARC Agriculture Centre, Dhaka Bangladesh

Genetic Engineering and Other Aspects of Biotechnology

Transcription:

Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation Christophe Charlier 1 and Egizio Valceschini 2 1 Université de Nice Sophia Antipolis and GREDEG/CNRS, France, christophe.charlier@gredeg.cnrs.fr 2 Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique, Paris, France, egizio.valceschini@paris.inra.fr Paper prepared for presentation at the 110 th EAAE Seminar System Dynamics and Innovation in Food Networks Innsbruck-Igls, Austria February 18-22, 2008 Copyright 2008 by [Charlier, Valceschini]. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.

Christophe Charlier and Egizio Valceschini 373 Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation Introduction Christophe Charlier 1 and Egizio Valceschini 2 1 Université de Nice Sophia Antipolis and GREDEG/CNRS, France, christophe.charlier@gredeg.cnrs.fr 2 Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique, Paris, France, egizio.valceschini@paris.inra.fr New technologies and innovations suspected to affect environment or public health need to be regulated. Scientific risk assessment is considered as a key element for the regulation. Its role is reinforced when the regulation has the potential of constraining the international trade. The Sanitary and Phytosanitary Agreement of the WTO dealing with this kind of issues gives primacy to scientific risk assessment. Interesting situations arise with small risks that is to say situations where the probability of damage is tiny and/or expected damages are very small. If risk assessment is the only scientific element considered, the mere presence of risk even smallshould give reason for regulation. Does it rationalize the public decision for all that? If the social benefits associated with the blocked activity are consequent accepting the risk could be worthwhile. Recent works from the economic literature have shown that in order to get a good risk governance cost-benefit analysis should be considered together with risk assessment (Bureau et al. 1998, Turvey and Mojduszka 2005). The aim of cost-benefit analysis is indeed to help public decision making. It consists in a set of methods that enables to evaluate the relevance of a regulation, comparing it with other possible options (from other types of regulation to the absence of any regulation). For that purpose cost-benefit analysis aims at estimating a monetary valuation, on the one hand, for environmental (or public health) degradation and, on the other hand, for the expected benefits implied by environmental conservation and technologies development. A particular relevant case of regulation of an innovation for the agro food sector is the regulation of biotechnologies. Genetically modified organisms (GMOs) indeed can be considered as a particular innovation that poses in both areas of environment and public health specific and new problems as well as valuable perspectives. On the risk aspects, threat on biodiversity and safety for human consumption are the two main risks usually associated with GMOs. On the benefit aspects, the first generation of GMOs were engineered in order to improve farmers productivity whereas the second generation present enhanced nutritional contents. Biotechnologies however are the textbook case of the complexity of evaluating cost and benefit of innovation because of the specific characteristic this case presents: The novelty of biotechnologies, the ethical concerns that genetic modification techniques raise, the threat of potentially irreversible effects on biodiversity, the absence of scientific unanimity on the risk assessment, the importance of the economic perspective biotechnologies offer, the consumers fear, etc. However, cost-benefit analysis can be defended in order to develop a risk governance for biotechnologies in which, together with scientific assessment, economic stakes would be considered. This point is of particular importance at the international level where divergent GMOs perceptions of different States coexist and where the World Trade Organization (WTO) governance scheme favours a scientific-based approach leaving little space for the economic aspects.

374 Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation The aim of this contribution is therefore to underlines the importance of cost-benefit analysis when considering GMOs regulation and to highlight the difficulties this analysis is confronted with in that specific field. It argues that these difficulties should not be considered as a reason to put apart economic assessment. For that purpose, the contribution presents in a first section the aim and scope of the cost-benefit analysis in the field of GMOs. In the second section the main economic analyses are presented and the meaning of their results explored. 1. Aim and scope of the cost-benefit analysis on GMOs The aim of the cost-benefit analysis is to rationalize the public decision. In evaluating costs and benefits this demarche enables to tell if the benefits of a given public decision exceed the cost implied. This analysis should therefore be undertaken in situation where the private decisions cannot give a suitable orientation. These situations arise in presence of market failures because of external effects or public goods or public bads. In these situations, we cannot expect from the private agents to take into account in their decisions the social aspects (both social benefits and social costs) of their choices. For example, if only private consequences were attached to GMOs introduction a cost benefit analysis would be useless. When social benefits and social costs are at stake a public decision is needed and cost-benefit analysis can be a useful tool to orientate it. In order to apply cost-benefit analysis to the regulation of GMOs the ways GMOs affect environment and human health have to be established first. In a second step, the evaluation whether social benefits cover social costs has to be conducted. The demarche suggested in the case of GMOs is therefore to operate a sort of listing of GMOs consequences for farmers and society and for each consequence to evaluate if the good/bad is private or public (Weaver 2005), in order to estimate if a cost-benefit analysis is needed or if private decisions suffice. Two kinds of social consequences can be distinguished in the case of GMOs. The first ones are the direct social consequences, that is to say consequences that totally escape to the farmers decision process. The second ones are private consequences for farmers that however present public aspects that have to be evaluated. The main direct social consequence in the first class is public health. Food-safety concerns over the potential long-run unknown consequences of ingesting GM-food are frequently pointed out. More precisely these matters relate to allergens and the use of antibiotic-resistant maker genes. These points totally escape from the sphere of farmers once a GMO has been approved for marketing. These risks have therefore to be evaluated before the premarket approval. Should they be translated into economic costs and confronted with the potential social benefits is an opened debate. The first group of consequences contains also public goods such a potential decrease in water use or public bads such as the reduction in genetic diversity in cropping system or adverse effects on organisms that are not pest, such as beneficial or neutral insects. GMOs very often present private and public characteristics. The first generation of GM crops, Ht and Bt, were engineered in order to improve farmers productivity. Ht crops are herbicide resistant and allow for a better control of weeds. Bt crops are insect resistant and allow for less insecticide use and reduced crops damage. The potential to reduce the application of chemical pesticides and herbicides directly concerns farmers. We could therefore estimate that a cost-benefit analysis is useless since no public dimension is present. This assertion however would ignore important social benefits and costs. To illustrate this idea, the case of Ht crops is considered (see Ervin et al. 2000). Ht crops imply a change in tillage practices since compared to conventional crops, less tillage is necessary. Conservation tillage methods are adopted consequently and offers reduction in fuel use/labour and machine time. Together with a better control of weeds, these form private benefits associated with GM crops that can be compared with the cost of the seed. No public decision is a priori needed here. Scientific studies however

Christophe Charlier and Egizio Valceschini 375 point that Ht crops and wild relatives could interbreed, making the latter more resistant to herbicide ( super weeds ). Once again, while with less certainty, this effect on the long-term efficacy of pesticide used could be taken into account by farmers and wouldn t need any public decision as a consequence. However, to control these stronger hybrid plants, farmers might respond by increasing the amount or toxicity of herbicides they apply. This can create an externality that farmers don t consider when choosing to turn to GM crops. In the same vein is the development of herbicide in wild relatives. The cost of this phenomenon has to be evaluated to have a complete cost of GM crops adoption. Furthermore, ecological studies pointed out that conservation tillage methods reduces incorporation of plant residue or animal waste to amend the soil. They would also create a negative environmental effect on the soil structure making possible groundwater to surface effluent. Together with these negative effects, a positive one is presented with a reduced wind and water erosion allowed by conservation tillage methods. All these negative and positive effects are external effects and need a cost-benefit analysis if they were to be taken into account by authorities when deciding Ht GMOs approval. 2. The main economic analysis undertaken and their meaning In front of the many concerns, both positive and negatives, raised by the use of biotechnologies in agriculture, the cost-benefit analyses are not numerous and broadly tackle the problem in the same way. Many studies actually propose evaluations of the consumers willingness to pay (WTP) for GM foods (Marks et al. 2003). The intuitive idea of these studies is that people reveal their preferences for GM foods by showing their WTP for them. If GM foods are considered as an environmental and/or sanitary gain, the consumers WTP should be positive. Alternatively, if GM foods are considered as an environmental and/or sanitary loss, consumers are willing to pay to prevent the loss or are willing to accept (WTA) to face the loss. Marks et al. (2003) provide an overview of the different approaches use to evaluate WTP in the case of GMOs and explain their diverging predictions, as well as their technical advantages and limits. They distinguished opinion surveys from choice experiment and experimental auction market methods. They focused on the latter as the most reliable one. Interestingly, studies that use experimental economics approach generally reveal positive WTP for both US and European respondants. These results contradict the generally accepted idea, especially in the European case, that consumers would shun biotech products if they were introduced (and labelled) on the markets. But what is the exact meaning in term of cost benefit analysis of these WTP expressed in experimental laboratory setting? What do the evaluated WTPs mean in environmental or sanitary terms? Hobbs and Kerr note that consumers are concerned in two ways by transgenic crops: direct (tangible) consumption effect and indirect (intangible) existence-value effects. From a theoretical point of view, the WTP can therefore cover many things (Pearce and Turner 1990): existence value, option value, actual use value In the empirical studies the announced WTP will depend, as a consequence, on the knowledge that respondants have before the experiment, on the way they are previously informed by the experimenters and on the way questions are asked. Different protocols will bring different results and may make comparisons difficult. 1 As an example, Noussair et al. (2004), using experimental economics, confirm that the experimented consumers do not refuse to buy GM food, but note that an opinion survey would accord greater weight to public dimensions such as negative externalities that result from widespread use of the product, than a bid in auction market, and can result in divergent results on the WTP 1. Development of parallel methodologies in ecological sciences may make comparisons difficult too.

376 Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation as a consequence. In other terms we could advance that if the tested consumers do not know the environmental stakes of their consumption of GM products, the situation of external effect is basically artificially remade with the experimental protocol. In the experimental protocol of Noussair et al. (2004) general information about GMOs is given to consumers. But this information concerns only the definition of a GMOs, the criteria used for classifying a product as containing GMOs, the list of GMOs authorised in France, the food products sold in France that contain GMOs and finally, the French law regarding GMOs. No information on the scientific debate over GMOs safety is provided and the situation of potential external effect cannot be appreciated by the tested consumers as a consequence. The WTP evaluated in this kind of studies (or the change in the WTP in response to new information about GMO content of products) better reflects the consumers preferences over GMOs rather than the social benefit/cost of GMOs. This kind of approach should not be rejected for all that since it forms a useful and precise tool for evaluating WTP in a context where the monetary evaluation of the GMOs environmental impact is needed. Kleter and Kuiper (2005) for instance, studying the environmental impact of change in pesticide use on transgenic crops, underlines the advantage that a monetary evaluation forms in front of the plurality of physical evaluation of impact indicators that cannot easily be compared. References Bureau, J-C., Marette, S. and Schiavina, A. (1998), "Non-tariff trade barriers and consumers' information: The case of the EU-US dispute over beef", European Review of Agricultural Economics, 25, pp. 437-462. Ervin, D. E., Batie, S. S., Carpentier, C. L., Fern, J. I., Richman N. and Schulz, M. A. (2000), Transgenic Crops: An Environmental Assessment, Henry A. Wallace Center for Agricultural and Environmental Policy at Winrock International, November 2000. Hobbs, J. E. and Kerr, W. A. (2005), Will Consumers Lose or Gain from the Environmental Impacts of Transgenic Crops?, in J. H. Wesseler (ed.), Environmental Costs and Benefits of Transgenic Crops, Springer, pp. 249-265. Kleter, G. A. and Kuiper, H. A. (2005), Assessing the Environmental Impact of Change in Pesticide Use on Transgenic Crops, in J. H. Wesseler (ed.), Environmental Costs and Benefits of Transgenic Crops, Springer, pp. 33-43. Marks, L. A., Kalaitzandonakes, N., and Vickner, S. S. (2003), Evaluating Consumer Response to GM Foods: Some Methodological Considerations, Current Agriculture, Food & Resource Issues, 2003, n 4, pp. 80-94. Noussair, C., Robin, S., and Ruffieux, B. (2004), Do Consumers Really Refuse to Buy Genetically Modified Food?, Economic Journal, 114(January), pp. 102-120. Pearce D. W., Turner, R. K. (1990), Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment, Johns Hopkins University Press. Turvey C. G. and Mojduszka E. M. (2005), The Precautionary principle and the Law of Unintended Consequences, Food Policy, 30, pp. 145-161. Weaver, R. D. (2005), Ex post Evidence on Adoption of Transgenic Crops: US Soybeans, in J. H. Wesseler (ed.), Environmental Costs and Benefits of Transgenic Crops, Springer,pp. 125-140.

Christophe Charlier and Egizio Valceschini 377

378 Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation