On Macroeconomic Theories and Modeist

Similar documents
Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Spring Macroeconomics, sixth edition, Andrew B. Abel and Ben S. Bernanke, Pearson/Addison- Wesley 2005.

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

TEACHING MICRO AND MACRO AS SEPARATE COURSES

Chapter 3. Introduction to Quantitative Macroeconomics. Measuring Business Cycles. Yann Algan Master EPP M1, 2010

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROGRAMME SPECIFIC OUTCOME

Study Plan Finance Agricultural Marketing Management International Markets and Agricultural 3 3 -

On Robust Monetary Policy with Structural Uncertainty

MONEY, CREDIT, AND FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY: REPLY TO PORTER AND OFFENBACHER

Advanced Macroeconomic Theory I: Syllabus

Introduction [to Recent Developments in the Theory of Involuntary Unemployment]

The Rational Expectations Hypothesis

16. Wrap Up John B. Taylor, May 22, 2013

What Economic Forecasters Really Do

THE CYCLICAL BEHAVIOR OF PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM SEVEN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Fundamentals of Economics. 2 September Exam Paper. Time: 2.5 hours

Curriculum Vitae. Andrew G. Atkeson

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory, 01/07/2003. A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Economic Forecasting in the Private and Public Sectors. Remarks by- Alan Greenspan. Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

College: Department: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID:

Concepts of Equilibrium and Their Role in Economic Simulation Models

The History of Expectations in Macroeconomics

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

EC5101 Microeconomic Theory ECA5101 Microeconomics EC5102 Macroeconomic Theory ECA5102 Macroeconomics

Supply of Money. William A. Barnett University of Kansas. July 14, 2006

Lecture 11: Real Business Cycles

Reconstructing Macroeconomics: A Perspective from Statistical Physics and Combinatorial Stochastic Processes

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Keynes' Labor Market: A Reply. By Allan H. Meitzer

A Planned Course Statement for. Economics, AP. Length of Period (mins.) 41 Total Clock Hours: 123. Periods per Cycle: 6 Length of Course (yrs.) 1.

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Master 2 Economic Analysis

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

II. Activist Views on Monetary Stabilization Policy

Econometric Theory and Methods: Doing Econometrics. Paul Dunne

Introduction to Econometric Methods. J Paul Dunne

Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Supply of Money. William A. Barnett. 14. July 2006

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models

SECTION 5 STUDY GUIDE MODULES 23-33

Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Econ 2004

Session 9 Assessing Welfare Impact of PBL Operations: Concept & Method Guntur Sugiyarto Economics and Research Department

CHAPTER 2. Conceptual Framework Underlying Financial Accounting ASSIGNMENT CLASSIFICATION TABLE (BY TOPIC) Brief. Concepts for Analysis

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

Economics. Synopsis. 1. Economic Concepts, Issues and Tools. 2. An Overview of Economics. Sections. Learning Summary. Sections

A Neoclassical Theory of the Keynesian Multiplier *

Research on Theoretical Analysis of Unemployment Rates Interim Report. Summary

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Methodological issues in the regulation of mobile voice call termination

On the Propagation of Demand Shocks *

Question Paper Code : J1103

CHAPTER 2. Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 9, 10, 11, 30 6, Basic assumptions. 12, 13, 14 5, 7, 10 6, 7

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

THE IMPLICATIONS OF HYPERBOLIC DISCOUNTING FOR PROJECT EVALUATION. Maureen Cropper and David Laibson

These examples suggest that he and I have had professional disputes. It generated a lot of interest. Meltzer and I were dubious but could not

Wallingford Public Schools - HIGH SCHOOL COURSE OUTLINE

Fixed and flexible prices

Productivity and Competitiveness as determinants of Growth: Empirical Evidence from a Small Island Economy Mauritius

Fundamentals of Economics. 3 June Examination Paper. Time: 2.5 hours

The True Cause of Business Cycle

Assessment Report for the Department of Economics. Program: Bachelor of Economics

Price and volume measures in national accounts - Resources

Empirical Evidence on the Demand for Money

On Rational Expectations and Stabilization Policy


Applied Welfare Economics

An Examination of the Quality of a Sample of 60 Selected Issues Papers

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model

LOSS DISTRIBUTION ESTIMATION, EXTERNAL DATA

Price setting problem: Rigidities

Roundtable Discussion Academic Help Wanted: A Policymaker s Perspective. Athanasios Orphanides Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

INTRODUCTION TO WALRASIAN GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODELING. Structural and Behavioral Underpinnings of the Walrasian General Equilibrium Model

Recommendations for Reforming Energy Efficiency Cost-Effectiveness Screening in the United States

4.2 A Model of Production. 4.1 Introduction. A Model of Production. Setting Up the Model. Chapter 4

Agenda. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis, Part 3. Disequilibrium in the AD-AS model

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization

1 Macro Facts. 2 Growth. 3 Flexprice Monetary Approach

M.Sc. Agril. Economics

10 AGGREGATE SUPPLY WITH IMPERFECT INFORMATION

ECONOMICS (ECO) Economics (ECO) 1

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Economics is the social science concerned with how individuals, institutions, and society make optimal (best) choices under conditions of scarcity.

Literature Review: Long-Run Economic Growth

Over the past decade or so,

NEER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEW CLASSICALS AND KEYNESIANS, OR THE GOOD GUYS AND THE BAD GUYS - Robert J. Barro. Paper No. 2982

Economics 120 Phone: FALL 2014 Office: D-413

Stan Ross Department of Accountancy: Learning Goals. The department s general goals are stated in its mission:

Incorporating DSM Uncertainty and Flexibility into Integrated Resource Planning

SAMPLE. Table of Contents Higher Altitudes. in Economics. Unit 1: Introduction Chapter 1: What is Economics?

Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review

Introduction to Economics, ECON 100:11 & 13 Economic Growth, Business Cycles, Unemployment, and Inflation. Macroeconomics

Transcription:

On Macroeconomic Theories and Modeist Preston Miller Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Critique of the Policy-Making Framework We have argued in the best stabilization theory tradition that the search for optimal policy is a technical problem which can be solved given an objective function and a macroeconometric model. Optimal policy derived within this standard policy-making framework, in general, can be expressed as a quantitative feedback rule. By quantitative we mean that the optimal policy can be numerically calculated and depends on the values of the model s parameters. By feedback we mean that the actual values at which the instrument variables should be set in the current period depend on recently observed values of endogenous and exogenous variables. But can a defensible objective function and a defensible model from among existing estimated macroeconomic models be supplied? We think not. Our doubts reflect to a large extent our dissatisfactionwith the current state of macroeconomics and monetary theory. Unlike other fields in economics, these two branches traditionally have not made use of models which contain behavioral relationships grounded explicitly in theories of individual optimization. This situation cannot be regarded as desirable. Macroeconomics developed this way because until very recently optimizing models did not exist which could account for fluctuations in aggregate real economic activity. Monetary theory developed this way because optimizing models still do not exist which explain the way financial institutions and the exchange mechanism evolve and operate under various government rules. Reliance on ad hoc models in these fields has forced welfare analysis of alternative government rules to be based on ad hoc notions of desirable tthe first two sections of this paper Contain arguments which were made previously in Muench-Wallace 171. (Note that numbers in brackets I I correspond to the reference list, p.50) 43

paths of aggregates like unemployment and the price level. Standard welfare economics based on the Pareto criterion cannot be applied to models which are not explicitly grounded in individual optimizing behavior. Thus, the theory of stabilization policy usually involves application of ad hoc welfare functions to ad hoc macroeconomic models to search for optimal policy rules. We are very dubious that implications from this type of analysis are at all useful. Microeconomic Approach To explain in greater detail our doubts about currently used macroeconometric models, it is helpful to begin by briefly describing the microeconomic approach and then to contrast general equilibrium microeconomic models with the current genre of macroeconometric models. We view the microeconornic approach to macroeconomic policy as one that builds models of the economy with the following characteristics: The models are based explicitly on the assumption that individuals optimize. They can explain observable phenomena such as the Phillips curve~unemployment (voluntary and involuntary), and inflation. The models allow for the analysis of a range of policies. The traditional (Pareto-type) welfare criterion can be applied to evaluate policies. In a microeconomic general equilibrium model, individual maximization subject to one or more constraints implies relationships between individual choice variables (often quantities demanded or supplied) and variables that appear in the constraints (prices). The equilibrium prices and quantities are determined from market-clearing conditions (that is, demand equals supply in every market) obtained by summing the individual supply and demand relationships. If this procedure is carried out explicitly, it insures a certain kind of consistency; namely, the pricequantity solutions are consistent with the choice problems which individuals were assumed to face. The imposition of rational expectations or, more simply, rationality in a model is the extension of this kind of consistency to stochastic models. The idea is that the distributions of endogenous variables implied by the model should be the same as those which individuals were assumed to face in deriving their supply and demand relationships. Macroeconometric models are not constructed in this fashion. Instead, they consist of estimated relationships behind each of which, at best, is an implicit partial equilibrium optimizing model of some aspect of the behavior of some sector of the economy. This procedure is very likely to produce inconsistencies. First, these different partial equilibrium fthe Phillips curve is interpreted broadly here as the negative correlation between aggregate demand variables and the unemployment rate. 44

models are very likely inconsistent with one another. The money demand function in the MPS niodei~for example, is reportedly derived from a partial equilibrium model in which an individual s asset alternatives are assumed to be money and an interest-bearing security. In other sectors of the model, however, it is assumed that individuals also hold inventories of a produced good. If holdings of this physical good had been allowed at the outset in addition to the money and securities, a very different money demand function would have resulted~ A second type of inconsistency occurs when the estimated relationships are put together and the resulting distributions of endogenous variables prices, incomes, etc. implied by the macroeconometric model are found to be different from those implicitly assumed in the various underlying partial equilibrium models. If the stochastic environment in which individuals are assumed to make decisions were constrained at the outset to be the same as the one implied by the model, then, once again, very different types of aggregate relationships would result. These inconsistencies are usually implicit rather than explicit because macroeconometric models tend to leave behind the detail of the underlying partial equilibrium models. The inconsistencies get revealed when in the face of some structural change for example, a change in policy regime the old estimated relationships no longer fit the data. But is such a critique of macroeconometric models of practical importance? Perhaps the critique is theoretical nit-picking and an arbitrary commitment to a particular way of modeling. If this were the case, then, at a minimum it would have to be argued that the estimated models pass tests for invariance over subperiods during which different policy rules seemed to be in effect. As a matter of fact, no empirical argument has been nor, we think, can be presented for those models that today form the basis for consensus forecasting and policy prescription. As far as we know, this Bank sponsored the only systematic testing of large macroeconometric models.~the models examined did not pass versions of standard statistical tests. Figure 4 from the Bank s study [81, reproduced here as Figure 1, gives a flavor of the results. The bar distributions are forecast distributions of the GNP deflator made conditional on actual values of all variables for the third quarter of 1968 and earlier and on actual values of future paths of a set of exogenous variables which include Ml, a set of fiscal variables, and some other variables taken to be exogenous by those who constructed the model, tthe MPS (MIT-Penn-SSRC) model is maintained by Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates, Inc., in Philadelphia. Pennsylvania. *See Miller 161. 5ee Muench eta!. I8I. 45

I Figure 1 FRB-MIT: Forecast Distributions of the GNP Deflator 9th quarter) 1970-4) 4th quarter (1969-3) 165 C 1st quarter (1968-4) 15-75- Mean 45~ Actual 60-30- () N N N Index (1958 100) 46

an old version of the FRB-MIT model. These distributions were obtained taking into account both residual and parameter estimation uncertainty. For all three forecast dates illustrated, the actual value of the deflator ended upoutside the estimated distribution of possible outcomes forecast by the model; nine quarters out, the mean forecast is 126.7 while the actual value was 137.4. This and other evidence are consistent with the view that the estimated relationships which appear in macroeconometric models shift around in systematic but unspecified ways in the face of alternative policy regimes. The deficiencies of macreconomics and monetary theory place a great burden on the policy authority. They force the authority to supply considerable judgment in choosing the most reasonable model among alternative representations of the economy, and then they force the authority to limit the choice of an objective function to one consistent with that particular view of the worldt While the current state of objective knowledge is woefully incomplete, what does exist should not be ignored. The policy authority s judgment in choosing among economic models should be informed and should reflect the weight of accumulated theoretical and empirical evidence. It is thejob of economists to construct and present that evidence. We now turn to that task. Clarification of Issues and a Role for Judgment In the next sequence ~of papers we will be presenting theoretical and empirical arguments addressing the question, Which model of the economy should the FOMC use as a basis for current policy-making decisions? To sharpen this question let us suppress our misgivings about ad hoc macro welfare functions and suppose that the policy-maker s objective function can be written w U~_~rt(Xt_X~)2 w where X~and ~ are real GNP and the GNP deflator in period t, N is the number of periods in the policy-maker s horizon, and the r s and d s are time discount factors. The targets for real GNP and the GNP deflator in period t, X~,and ~ respectively, are chosen to indicate peak efficiency in the economy over time. We suppose also that the economic model can be written in the form ta distinction is being made here between a welfare function stated abstractly in terms of individual utilities and an objective function stated in terms of reported economic time series. The policy maker~view of the world determines which reported economic variables can serve as proxies for welfare. If all unemployment were viewed as being voluntary, for example, the unemployment rate would be a poor proxy for welfare and would not be included in the objective function. 47

of two somewhat general reduced-form equations X~= a + a 1X~_1+ a,(p~p1) + a,p~+ ~(t) b + bx~_ + b,(p~-p~)+ b3p~+ ~(t) where a s and b s are known constants, P~is the value of the Fed s portfolio in period t, Pt is the public s expectation of P~as of the beginning of period t, and E~and e,~are random disturbance terms. The economic model we have posed should be interpreted as the true model; no estimation is involved yet. The question we are addressing in this next sequence of papers is, Can monetary policy have a systematic effect on real output or, more specifically, is a1 > 0? Note, the issue isoverthe model of the economy. It is not over optimal policy. That follows from the model which is chosen. The issue can alternatively be stated, Is there an exploitable Phillips curve? In other words, do observed correlations between unemployment and prices constitute the policy maker s attainable set? To stylize the argument, suppose Pcan be defined so that a,, + b3 1, and suppose that a3 = 1 indicates policy has maximal effect on the real economic variable X. Rational expectations theorists hypothesize that a., is zero. In this case it follows that policy cannot have a systematic (or predictable) effect on real output and should, therefore, be directed at stabilizing the price level. Policy activists, however, hypothesize that a3 is greater than zero, and some have been known to argue that it is close to one. Activists prescriptions for policy follow because the closer a3 is to one, the more policy should be directed at closing the gap between actual and desired real GNP and the less attention should be given to price stabilization. Why not simply estimate our economic model and determine whether a,, = 0? This turns out to be a difficult task. Thomas Sargent s paper in this volume shows that if P were set according to some rule over the historical period, then a number of models would fit the data equally well. In this case the data could not distinguish between a model with = 0 and others with a, > 0. Which model is the right one? The decisive experiment has not yet been performed. It is important to note a significant property of these seemingly equivalent models: only one will remain invariant to a change in the policy rule. This property suggests a strategy for testing the correctness of particular models. First identify differences in policy rules either for a given country over time or across different countries. Then test whether the hypothesized models are invariant under the different policies. Sargent reports some results from these types of tests that, while suggestive, are not likely to settle the policy-making debate. Where does this leave the policy maker? Based on theoretical arguments and empirical evidence, the policy maker must form judgment on 48

the true value of a,. Judgment might then be equated with specifying a probability distribution over the set of feasible models. Presumably the more informed that judgment is, the more concentrated the distribution becomes. Our objective in the next set of papers, therefore, is to hammer away at policy makers probability distributions to make them more concentrated around the value of a 3 we believe is correct. 49

References 1. Kareken, John H., Thomas J. Muench, Thomas M. Supel, and Neil Wallace. Determining the Optimum Monetary Instrument Variable: In Open Market Policies and Operating Procedures: StaffStudies. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July 1971: 85-96. 2. Kareken, John H., Thomas J. Muench, and Neil Wallace. Optimal Open Market Strategy: The Use of Information Variables: American Economic Revieit Vol. 63, No. 1 (March 1973): 156-72. 3. Lucas, Robert E., Jr. Expectations and the Neutrality of Money. Journal of Economic Theory Vol. 4, No. 2 (April 1972): 103-24. 4.. Some International Evidence on Output Inflation Tradeoffs. American Economic Review Vol. 63, No. 3 (June 1973): 326-34. 5.. Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In The Phillips Curie and Labor Markets, ed. by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer. Rochester, N.Y.: North Holland, Vol. 1(1976): 19-46. 6. Miller, Preston J. The Transactions Demand for Money in a Three-Asset Economy. International Economic Review forthcoming. 7. Muench, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. On Stabilization Policy: Goals and Models A,nerican Economic Review Vol. 64, No.2 (May 1974):330-37. 8. Muench, Thomas J., Arthur 1. Rolnick, Neil Wallace, and William Weiler. Tests for Structural Change and Prediction Intervals for the Reduced Forms of Two Structural Models of the U.S.: The FRB-MIT and Michigan Quarterly Models: Annals of Economic and Social Measurement Vol. 3, No. 3 (July 1974): 491-519. 9. Rolnick, Arthur J. Evaluating the Effectiveness of Monetary Reforms: Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 2, No. 3 (July 1976): 271-96. 10. Sargent, Thomas J. Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemployment: In Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, ed. by Arthur M. Okun and George L. Perry. Washington: The Brookings Institution, 2:1973: 429-80. 11... A Classical Macroeconomic Model for the United States Journal of Political Economy Vol. 84, No. 2 (April 1976): 207-37. 12. Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. Rational Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule: Journal of PoliticalEconomj Vol. 83, No.2 (April 1975): 241-54. 13.. Rational Expectations and the Theory of Economic Policy~ Studies in Monetary Economics 2. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, June 1975. 50