Explaining Price Dispersion in the Manhattan Beer Market: Information Acquisition, Geographic Distribution and Searching under the Influence

Similar documents
EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF INTERNET-ENABLED MARKET TRANSPARENCY: IMPACT ON DEMAND, PRICE ELASTICITY, AND FIRM STRATEGY

2TouchPOS Pricing & Dynamic Pricing Administrative Guide

Identifying Peer Influence in Massive Online Social Networks: A Platform for Randomized Experimentation on Facebook

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Eyal Carmi. Google, 76 Ninth Avenue, New York, NY U.S.A. Gal Oestreicher-Singer and Uriel Stettner

Monetizing Information: Competition. in Online Markets

Monetizing Information: Competition. in Online Markets. Alok Gupta Carlson School Professor of IDSc. What s this about

Phase II of the On-Demand Economy What Did We Learn from Phase I?

Evaluating Pricing Strategy Using ecommerce Data: Evidence and Estimation Challenges. October 15, 2005

Can Product Heterogeneity Explain Violations of the Law of One Price?

CUSTOMER LOYALTY AWARD WON BY BRANDS IN 19 CATEGORIES. -- Pepsi, Canon, Baseball and Wendy s Among America s Most Liked Brands

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract

The Three Most Important Variables in Internet Retailing

Impact of Secondary Electronic Markets on Information Good Suppliers

Online Price Dispersion: An International Comparison

Citation for published version (APA): Kopányi, D. (2015). Bounded rationality and learning in market competition Amsterdam: Tinbergen Institute

The Gestalt in Graphs: Prediction Using Economic Networks

Price dispersion is an important indicator of market efficiency. Internet-based electronic markets have the

Discriminating Dispersion in Prices

Title: A bounded-rational procedural consumer: How a human solves the consumer optimization problem

Terry College of Business - ECON 4950

University of California, Davis

This worksheet will help you understand various aspects of the existing marketplace your product will be entering into.

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Visualizing MR results Perceptual Maps

Will the growth of multi-channel retailing diminish the pricing efficiency of the web?

Economics of Information and Communication Technology

Department of Economics Fall Economics 121 SUGGESTED SOLUTIONS FOR MIDTERM EXAM

In this paper, we develop a theoretical model to analyze the pricing strategies of competing retailers with

Clicks vs. Bricks: Toward a Model of Internet- Induced Channel Competition

Spatial Information in Offline Approximate Dynamic Programming for Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Stochastic Requests

The Effect Of Consumer Reviews On Vendor- Related And Market-Related Price Sensitivity

Tools and Processes to Enhance TAM: Resource Allocation

ONLINE RESTRAINTS EFFECTS, ANALYSIS AND ENFORCEMENT

Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices

Introduction to Business Research 3

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

Chapter 21. channels of distribution. Section 21.1 Distribution. Section 21.2 Distribution Planning

Hello Attribution. Goodbye Confusion. A comprehensive guide to the next generation of marketing attribution and optimization

AS THE NEW COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE

The Pricing Behavior of Firms in the Euro Area: New Survey Evidence

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

MARKET PRICE AND DATA ANALYSIS

Local Preference Minorities and the Internet: Why e-retailer Demand Is Greater in Areas Where Target Customers Are in the Minority

TOUCH IOT WITH SAP LEONARDO PROTOTYPE CHALLENGE

Comp-CCD/35/11 Amazon.com, Inc/The Book Depositary International Ltd

Econ 302: Microeconomics II - Strategic Behavior. Problem Set # 3 May 31

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 33 Oligopoly (Contd )

Introduction - Simulation. Simulation of industrial processes and logistical systems - MION40

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion

COMPETITION WITH PRICE-DEPENDENT PREFERENCES MATTHEW G. NAGLER*

The Microfoundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies: Dicussion of Duranton and Puga (DP), 2004

Best Practice. Assessing Lead Source Effectiveness

IO Experiments. Given that the experiment was conducted at a sportscard show, the sequence of events to participate in the experiment are discussed.

Estimating the Effects of Deregulation in the Ontario Wine Retail Market

The value of consumer data in online advertising

The Internet: Changing the Face of Business

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 23 Theory of Cost (Contd )

Chapter 4 Market research

Investment Platforms Market Study Interim Report: Annex 8 Gap Analysis

What is TicketNetwork Private Label?

An Ethical Reading of the UK Modern Slavery Act and its Implications for Firms

Setting targets is a routine business practice that helps ensure that. an issue is kept on senior management s radar screen and factored

Energy Efficiency Impact Study

2016 FINANCIAL REVIEW

MARKETING AUTOMATION

Creating a Marketing Plan. An American Marketing Association Best Practices Tutorial by Linda Lee and Denise Hayes

AB InBev Investor Seminar September 1st, 2015 Miguel Patricio, CMO AB InBev

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

How Consumer Analysis Affects Business Strategy

David Easley and Jon Kleinberg November 29, 2010

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

DYNAMIC PRICING UPDATE 1.0 APRIL atpco.net

Electronic Markets and Geographic Competition among Small, Local Firms

Is globalization a road to duopoly?

Automated Negotiation on Internet Agent-Based Markets: Discussion

Shared Value Business Case. Approaches and Frameworks for Workforce Development Practitioners

VALUE OF SHARING DATA

Improving Urban Mobility Through Urban Analytics Using Electronic Smart Card Data

Chapter 6: Combining Supply and Demand

CHAPTER 1. PRELIMINARIES

The Other Long Tail. The Value of Infrequent Customers. Congrès des Microbrasseries du Québec November 27, 2018

Marketing Metrics Handbook (Simplified)

Continuous customer dialogues

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

INSIGHTS. Driving Decisions With Data: iquanti s Hybrid Approach to Attribution Modeling. Ajay Rama, Pushpendra Kumar

CO-HOST BOOKING GUIDE

CHAPTER 2. Presented By: Raghda Essam Dina El-Haddad Samar El-Haddad Menna Hatem. E-Marketplaces: Structures, Mechanisms and Impacts

The Chinese professional services platform

Online and Offline Demand and Price Elasticities: Evidence from the Air Travel Industry

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Investigating Intermediaries that Participate in Internet Commerce to Determine the Elements of Online Price Dispersion

ROUTING GAMES IN THE WILD: EFFICIENCY, EQUILIBRATION AND REGRET. Hassan Nikaein Amin Sabbaghian

Our Mission: We create, perform, teach and promote dance as an essential and inspiring element of our community.

Panos Markopoulos [University of Cyprus]

A Typical Multichannel Forensics Project A CEO s Guide To Reducing Expenses And Increasing Profit

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Transcription:

Explaining Price Dispersion in the Manhattan Beer Market: Information Acquisition, Geographic Distribution and Searching under the Influence Vandana Ramachandran University of Utah vandana@business.utah.edu Arun Sundararajan NYU Stern School of Business arun@stern.nyu.edu 1. Overview and Summary The term price dispersion is commonly used to refer to firms in the same market selling identical goods for different prices at the same time. Since the early conjecture by Bakos (1997) that electronic markets are likely to feature lower price dispersion on account of lower search costs, a number of researchers have studied how information technology alters the observed variation of prices across sellers, in both traditional and online marketplaces. We model the role of geographic concentration, online versus offline information acquisition, heterogeneous search costs and repeat purchasing in explaining price dispersion for homogeneous goods, and examine the drivers of measured price dispersion in the market for beer served at New York City bars. We formulate a random bar crawler model of search by bar patrons, a variant on the random surfer model of Brin and Page (1998), and use it to generate hypotheses about the equilibrium price dispersion of different brands of beer across bars dispersed in densely populated urban areas. We use panel data comprising price information in 2009 for over 4,200 beers sold in over 600 bars in New York City across neighborhoods with differing income levels and varying mixes of regular patrons/tourists. We combine this with information about the geographic concentration of bars and proximity to public transportation obtained from Google Maps, product quality information from beeradvocate.com, merchant desirability information based on reviews from Citysearch.com, urbanspoon.com and insiderpages.com, and product cost information from the New York State Liquor Authority. Our preliminary evidence suggests that the significant price dispersion that exists in this market persists even after controlling for differences in a variety of bar characteristics and variation in the intensity of local competition as measured by neighborhood bar concentration. Our analysis has also uncovered patterns of price dispersion across products in different neighborhoods which is consistent with a theory in which in addition to simple random bar crawling, heterogeneous benefits are realized from the acquisition of price information, consistent with an economic model in which a fraction of buyers are one-shot consumers while others are regulars or repeat purchasers

2. Background and Motivation Our study is motivated in part by the fact that information technologies affect price dispersion and its analysis in a number of different ways 1. The model of Bakos (1997) predicts that the intermediation facilitated by electronic markets lowers the cost of buyers in acquiring information about both seller prices and product offerings, which in turn will lower price dispersion. There is a wide variety of evidence that supports this theory to differing degrees for different homogenous products. In the market for airline tickets in well-defined markets, for example, price dispersion, while substantial in the mid-1990 s (Clemons, Hann and Hitt, 2002) has dropped since, and there is evidence that IT has led to more transparent electronic markets in this industry (Granados, Gupta and Kauffman, 2007). On the other hand, price dispersion for books, CDs and software, initially measured as substantial in the 1990 s (Brynjolfsson and Smith, 2000) has persisted ten years later (Ghose, Ipeirotis and Sundararajan, 2009) in part because of observable and measurable heterogeneity in the reliability of the sellers of these products and of the quality of the trade processes (fulfillment, delivery, packaging, customer support) associated with the purchase. The latter findings are relevant to our study because they suggest that price dispersion for a seeming homogeneous product (such as beer) may be mitigated by controlling for seller fixed effects, a finding supported partially in the past for the gasoline market as well (Lewis, 2008). A different impact of IT on price dispersion that has received less attention in the literature and that we aim to contribute towards is the effect that online providers price and product quality information may have on price dispersion in offline markets. In our offline market, there is currently a wealth of web-based information about the quality of different merchants (bars and other drinking establishments) which is bound to affect the variation of prices for homogeneous products sold by heterogeneous merchants. A third impact that IT has had on the analysis of price dispersion is in the wealth of data that it has made available to the educated econometrician. Our study is made possible by the Internet-based availability of beer prices 2 as well as our ability to quantify the intensity of competition and the local concentration of sellers using the Google Maps API. 3. Data and Model We gather data about beer prices in New York City from beermenus.com, a web site that lists the menus, prices and ABV ratings of beers sold in bars, pubs and other drinking establishments 1 It is also motivated in part by a deep personal interest by one of the authors in this local industry coupled with extensive prior consumption of its products and services. 2 Thus eliminating the need for expensive (although possibly fulfilling) hand-collection of pricing data.

Figure 1: Illustrates the beermenus.com web site. The screenshot on the left lists a subset of the bars in a particular Manhattan neighborhood, while the screenshot on the right illustrates how the price and product information are displayed to a user. (henceforth referred to as bars for brevity). We use a Perl spider and custom-built parser to traverse the site on a weekly basis. Our data collection began in March 2009 and is ongoing. The site also provides information about the street address (geographic location) of each bar. We use the Google Maps API to determine the latitude and longitude of each bar, and to compute the walking distances between bars in the same neighborhood. We use the Google Local Search API to get aggregate rating information for bars, as well as custom Perl scripts to spider insiderpages.com, Citysearch.com and urbanspoon.com for further bar rating information. We supplement this with product information gathered from beeradvocate.com. Our empirical analysis is based on two models. The first builds on Sorenson (2001) and bases the eventual price dispersion on a consumer utility specification for consumption that has beerspecific, bar-specific and idiosyncratic components. Specifically, the indirect utility for consumer i from consuming beer k at bar j is given by u = θ αp + ε, where ijk j jk θ j is a bar fixed effect which captures the average ambience of the establishment or other bar-specific characteristics that may make it able to charge a higher price, p jk is the price of beer k at bar j and ε represents preference aspects relating to bar j and beer k that are idiosyncratic 3 to individual i. ijk ijk 3 For example, an explicit preference for 16oz. Stella Artois draft beer at the V-Bar.

Miller Lite 12 oz. Bottle La Chouffe 12 oz. Bottle Hoegaarden 16 oz. Draft Coors Light 12 oz. Bottle Bud Light 12 oz. Bottle Red Stripe 12 oz. Bottle Orval 12 oz. Bottle Guinness 16 oz. Draft Stella Artois 16 oz. Draft Lindeman's Framboise 12 oz. Bottle Duvel 12 oz. Bottle Chimay Rouge 12 oz. Bottle Budweiser 12 oz. Bottle Brooklyn Lager 16 oz. Draft Heineken 12 oz. Bottle Amstel Light 12 oz. Bottle Corona 12 oz. Bottle Stella Artois 12 oz. Bottle Red Stripe 12 oz. Bottle Duvel 12 oz. Bottle Brooklyn Lager 16 oz. Draft Becks 12 oz. Bottle Chimay Rouge 12 oz. Bottle Negra Modelo 12 oz. Bottle Budweiser 12 oz. Bottle Corona 12 oz. Bottle Heineken 12 oz. Bottle Amstel Light 12 oz. Bottle 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% Figure 2: Illustrates the most popular beers (measured as a percentage of bars that they are available at) in two zip codes (10012, blue on the left, and 10014, red on the right). We also assume that search is all or nothing. Consumers either price-search exhaustively or select the bar that best matches their non-price preferences, expecting to pay the average price for the beer of their choice. The latter consumers, who we term one-shot consumers 4, will maximize the expected utility obtained absent a price search. The former consumers compute the maximum expected indirect utility from price-shopping, and are those whose indirect utility (amplified by an inflation factor alc ik which represents the number of times the consumer expects to use the information they have acquired via this exhaustive search) exceeds their cost of exhaustive search τ ik. The second model, which is still under development, is a dynamic model of search by uninformed consumers, a model we call the random bar crawler model. A consumer starts by choosing a bar at random, where the probability of starting at any given bar is proportionate to the bar s exogenously specified quality (determined, for example, from some composite of its user-generated and expert ratings). Upon arriving at the bar, the consumer determines its price menu and true ambience by direct examination. The consumer then chooses whether to consume a beer at this bar or explore a second bar. If the choice is the latter, the probability that the consumer chooses a specific next bar in the neighborhood of the current bar is inversely proportionate to the distance of the former bar from the latter. When reaching the next bar, the consumer repeats this process. This process describes a Markov chain in which each bar location 4 Or one pint consumers, perhaps.

Figure 3: Illustrates (a, on the left) price dispersion in a specific zip code for Corona 12oz. bottles, and (b, on the right for zip code 10016) how the price dispersion for different beers at a sample of 14 locations, 10 of which sell both beers (blue labels are for Amstel Light 12oz. bottle, green labels are for Budweiser 12oz. bottle) is not completely explained by seller-specific characteristics. is a state, and the transition probabilities are based on inter-bar distances 5. We can then compute the steady-state probabilities of being at the states (bars) in this Markov chain. These steadystate probabilities, analogous to PageRank values, represent a measure of the pricing power of the bar in question as a function of both its geographic location and inherent quality. 4. Preliminary Results and Research Agenda Our salient preliminary results are summarized below. Heterogeneous preferences across neighborhoods: This is a pattern that emerges from our data, that there is considerable variation in the popular beers across different areas of Manhattan, indicative of heterogeneity in consumer tastes. The bar charts in Figure 2 illustrate this by charting the distribution of availability of specific beers in two candidate zip codes in our data set. As is evident from the figures, the different zip codes have fairly different distributions of popular beers. This could depend in part by the mix of tourists and regulars. 5 A more complete and realistic model would recognize the fact that transition probabilities from bar to bar are a function of the number of beers consumed at the point of transition (and after a particular consumption level some states may become sinks), but we have not yet been able to formulate an analytically tractable version of this model.

Price dispersion is persistent even after accounting for bar quality: Figure 3a illustrates the price distribution 6 for a sample beer in a subset of bars in a candidate zip code (10012) from our data set. As is evident from the map on the left, there is considerable price dispersion across bars even for a very popular homogenous beer. Figure 3b illustrates the price dispersion for two popular beers in a different zip code, illustrating that bar (seller) fixed effects do not wash out all the variation in prices across bars. This is another pattern that emerges very clearly from our data. Concentration and price dispersion: We have defined a measure of competition at both the bar level and the individual beer level based on our Google Maps data about geographic concentration. The simple measure of concentration counts the number of bars that are within a reasonable walking distance of each bar (for example, a bar with 85 other bars within walking distance is termed an 85-proof bar). The measure of product concentration counts, for each beer sold at a bar, the number of other bars within walking distance that also sell that beer. Neither measure of concentration fully accounts for the observed price dispersion. This analysis is quite preliminary and we are working on refining these estimates. Our further research agenda between now and December 2009 will focus on completing the development of our analytical model of random crawling, computing the relative market power of each of the bars in our sample using this model, and assessing whether this more refined measure of concentration can account for the price dispersion we observe in our data. We are also working on completing a more robust estimation of our model with one-shot and regular customers using our entire weekly panel, perhaps extending it to include a more sophisticated analytical model of consumer search. We hope to be able to report on our findings at the 20 th anniversary WISE in Arizona. (References available on request) 6 A different kind of bar chart.