INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Similar documents
Chapter 13. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 13. Chapter Outline. Some Specific Oligopoly Models : Cournot, Bertrand and Stackelberg Competition When There are Increasing Returns to Scale

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

OLIGOPOLY: Characteristics

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Market Structure & Imperfect Competition

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 33 Oligopoly (Contd )

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

Three Rules and Four Models

Three Rules and Four Models

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

Name FIRST HOUR EXAM ECN 4350/6350

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Lecture 2 OLIGOPOLY Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Contents. Concepts of Revenue I-13. About the authors I-5 Preface I-7 Syllabus I-9 Chapter-heads I-11

Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

Overview 11/6/2014. Herfindahl Hirshman index of market concentration ...

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

Chapter 6: Market Structure

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Economics 384 B1. Intermediate Microeconomics II. Assignment 2. S Landon Winter 2007

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

Hotelling s (1929) linear city. Hotelling

Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

Unit 13 AP Economics - Practice

Chapter 10: Monopoly

Lecture 11 Imperfect Competition

Unit 6: Non-Competitive Markets

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series. 1 Introduction to Economics 5 2 Competitive Markets, Demand and Supply Elasticities 37

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Part III: Market Structure 12. Monopoly 13. Game Theory and Strategic Play 14. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Use the following to answer question 4:

Market Structure - Oligopoly

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 6. I. Choose the correct answer (each question carries 1 mark)

Lecture 3 OLIGOPOLY (CONTINUED) 13-1 Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

AP Microeconomics Review Session #3 Key Terms & Concepts

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Monopolistic Competition

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

ECONOMICS CHAPTER 9: FORMS OF MARKET

c) Will the monopolist described in (b) earn positive, negative, or zero economic profits? Explain your answer.

Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Duopoly Monopoly. The further right on the scale, the greater the degree of monopoly power exercised by the firm.

Microeconomics Unit 2 The Nature and Function of Product Markets

2007 Thomson South-Western

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

B.V. Patel Institute of Business Management, Computer & Information Technology, Uka Tarsadia University : Managerial Economics

MICROECONOMICS DIAGRAMS

CH short answer study questions Answer Section

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 6. Competition

Networks, Telecommunications Economics and Strategic Issues in Digital Convergence. Prof. Nicholas Economides. Spring 2006

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

Principles of Microeconomics Assignment 8 (Chapter 10) Answer Sheet. Class Day/Time

Many sellers: There are many firms competing for the same group of customers.

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Managerial Economics

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

Textbook Media Press. CH 12 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

FOR MORE PAPERS LOGON TO

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

MICROECONOMICS 2601 FINAL % 100 Marks 2 Hours FI Concession Assessment 27 February 2017 STUDENT NUMBER IDENTITY NUMBER. Marks Examiners 1 2

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

1. For a monopolist, present the standard diagram showing the following:

REDEEMER S UNIVERSITY

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

Syllabus item: 42 Weight: 3

Perfect competition the competitive firm s supply decision. Microeconomics

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Firm Supply. Market demand. Demand curve facing firm

Sample Multiple-Choice Questions

UNIT 11 COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY

Transcription:

13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries and markets fall under the category of "imperfect competition." However, monopoly and perfect competition are useful benchmarks. There is no clear separation between monopolistic competition and oligopoly, but we will examine industries which fit the description of monopolistic competitors and other industries which fit the description of oligopolies. Both market structures are characterized by firms that possess some degree of market power. Market Power relates to the firm's ability to affect the price of its product. Market power often depends upon the degree of concentration that characterizes a market. Concentration is measured by the concentration ratio, which is defined as the proportion of the output produced by the largest firms in the industry. High concentration ratios suggest the potential for market power, but market power need not develop. The potential for market power can be diminished by the threat of potential entry as well as by the presence of actual competitors. Potential entry may act to restrain an existing firm from exercising market power and raising prices. Monopolistic competition is characterized by product differentiation. The products are unique in some way but are very close substitutes. Product differentiation is very often associated with the brand name owned by the producer. This is responsible for the name "monopolistic competition" because firms are monopolists with regard to their own specific product, hence face down-sloping demand curves. However, the presence of close substitutes impacts on their market power: their demand curves are likely to be very elastic. The question that we wish to answer is: what output level will the profit-maximizing Monopolistic Competitor choose in the short run? Again the answer is: it will choose the output level for which MC = MR. For simplicity we will assume that pricing decisions are independent. Whether the Monopolistic Competitor can sustain economic profits in the long run depends on the ease of entry. If there are effective barriers to entry, then the monopolistic competitor may earn economic profits in the long run. However, many monopolistically competitive industries are characterized by relatively low barriers to entry, and long run equilibrium will occur where MC = MR and where P = AC = LRAC, and economic profits will have been driven to zero. Entry eats into the firm's market share, driving its demand curve to the left.

13-2 Profit Loss Long-Run Equilibrium Comparison with PC wps.prenhall.com Even with the economic profits driven to zero, however, the long run in monopolistic competition fails to achieve efficiency because P /= MC (the socially optimal output level is not produced) and because capacity is under-utilized, so we do not produce at minimum LRAC. The Role of Advertising: Since non-price competition (product differentiation) is very important in this type of market, we find that advertising plays an important role. Advertising aims to shift demand curves to the right (increase market share) and to make them less elastic (establish brand loyalty). However, advertising is expensive and increases the AC of the firm.

13-3 Chamberlain Model Short-Run Long-run Perfect Competition Versus Chamberlinian Monopolistic Competition Competition meets the test of allocative efficiency, while monopolistic competition does not. Monopolistic competition is less efficient than perfect competition because in the former case firms do not produce at the minimum points of their long-run average cost (LAC) curves. In terms of long-run profitability the equilibrium positions of both the perfect competitor and the Chamberlinian monopolistic competitor are precisely the same. Oligopoly Oligopoly -- A market dominated by a few sellers, in which at least some are large enough relative to the total market to influence the market price. Goods can be either heterogeneous (e.g. autos) or homogeneous (e.g. oil). Barriers to entry make profits possible in the long run. This may be due to Scale economies Patents Reputation Strategic barriers Because you need to account for your rival s behavior, finding equilibrium in an oligopoly market is more complicated then that of other model. We assume that each firm wants to do the best that it can, given what its competitors are doing. In addition, we assume that your competitors will do the best that they can given what you are doing. Thus, we have a Nash equilibrium.

13-4 Nash equilibrium -- Each firm is doing the best that it can given what its competitors are doing. There is no one dominant model of oligopoly and we will look at several. For simplicity, let's take an industry with two firms (Duopoly). A Cournot Duopoly Model The models of duopoly (two firms make up the industry) considered in microeconomics typically include the Cournot duopoly model. The simplest approach to the Cournot duopoly model assumes the following: (1) demand curves are linear, (2) the good is homogeneous, (3) marginal cost is zero, and (4) each firm makes its output decision assuming the other firm s output is fixed at its current level. Typically the Cournot model begins with one firm operating as a monopolist and then allowing the other firm to enter the market. Suppose we have the linear market demand curve: P = 120 Q where P is the price of mineral water and the total quantity offered (Q) is the sum of the outputs of the two firms in the market. Let q 1 and q 2 represent the individual outputs of firms one and two, respectively. The demand function may therefore be written: P = 120 (q 1 + q 2) The marginal revenue curve (MR) has the same vertical intercept as the demand curve and twice the slope or MR = 120-2 (q 1 + q 2) Reaction Functions Since there are no costs, the profit function for Firm 1 is the same as the total revenue function (P x q 1) for Firm 1: 1 = 120q 1 q 2 1 q 1q 2 For maximum profit for Firm 1, differentiate the profit equation with respect to q 1 and set the result equal to zero: d 1/dq 1 = 120 2q 1 q 2 = 0 Solving this for q 1: q1 60 0.5q2 The equation is known as the reaction function for Firm 1, since it determines how much output Firm 1 will produce (q 1) as a function of the output of Firm 2 (q 2). Similarly, the profit function for Firm 2 is: 2 = 120q 2 q 2 2 q 1q 2

13-5 and the first-order condition is: d 2/dq 1 = 120 2q 2 q 1= 0 Solving the equation for q 2: q2 60 0.5q1 The reaction functions for each firm are based on the output for the other firm. Therefore we can substitute the equation for q 1 into the equation for q 2: q 60 0.5(60 0.5 q ) 2 2 Solving for q 2 yields: q2 30 0.25q2 or 0.75q 2 30 q 2 = 40 Substitute the solution for q 2 into firm s 1 reaction function and we find q 1 equals q 1 = 60-0.5(40) = 40 Inserting q 1 and q 2 into the demand function we get an equilibrium price of P = $40. From before: q2 60 0.5q1 q1 60 0.5q2 The figure below shows the two reaction functions, where the vertical axis is the output of Firm 2, q 2, and the horizontal axis measures the output of Firm 1, q 1. Output from Firm 2 60 120 R1 R2 60 120 Output from Firm 1 R1 is the reaction function for Firm 1 and R2 is the reaction function for Firm 2. The equilibrium is found at the intersection of the two reaction functions, where q 1 = 40, along the horizontal axis and q 2 = 40, along the vertical axis. We can see that P = 40 1 * = 2 * = 40(40) = 1600

13-6 Cournot, Monopoly, and Competition Although the Cournot model is often criticized as being naive, especially in its assumptions, it is intuitively appealing when compared to the models of monopoly and perfect competition. The monopoly output can be found by setting marginal cost (which is zero) equal to marginal revenue (derived from the total revenue function P x Q, where P is the demand function). We look at monopolist with demand curve: P=120 Q and MC = 0. TR 120Q Q 2 You can show that profit-maximizing condition is satisfied when firm produces where MR 120 2Q 0 Q = 60, P=60 The monopolist would produce an output of 60, and the corresponding price would be 60. Notice from either reaction functions, if the output of the other firm is zero, the equilibrium output is indeed equal to the monopoly output, which is the expected result with only one firm in the industry. Output for the duopoly equilibrium is 80, more than the monopoly output, and price $40 is also lower than the monopoly price. The competitive output is found where marginal cost equals price (MC = P), or an output of 120, where P = 0. The Cournot duopoly output and price equilibrium values fit nicely between the monopoly and competitive extremes. Bertrand Duopoly Some assumptions of the model: If the two firms charge the same price each will get half of the market demand at that price. If one firm charges more than the other, even just a little bit, then the one with the higher price will sell nothing and the one with the lower price will have all the demand at that price. Each firm wants to maximize its profit. Let s say the demand in a market is P = 120 Q Suppose the marginal cost for each firm is 20

13-7 TR = 120Q Q 2 Solving for MR = 120-2Q Setting MR = MC 120-2Q = 20 so Q = 50. Each firm will produce 50 units of output. Now suppose this is a perfectly competitive industry. Set P = MC 120 Q = 20 so Q = 100 Thus Betrand Model give same result as Perfect Compettion. Now let s look at a firm that sees at a situation where its optimal production depends on what some other firm does. Stackelberg Leadership Model Assume: two firms (leader, follower) homogeneous product quantity is strategic variable leader chooses a quantity; follower observes this and chooses its quantity. Behavior: 1) Follower takes leader's output as given and maximizes profits 2) Leader takes follower's best response function as given and maximizes profits Residual demand of follower: q 2 = Q - q 1 Residual demand of leader: q 1 =Q - R(q 2) Where: q 1 is observed by firm 2, but firm 1 simply anticipates firm 2's best response. Example: Go back to the Cournot model in which we had the following demand function P =120 Q. But now Q is not just want you produce but it's what both of you produce, so Q = q 1 + q 2. And, assuming you're firm 1, you do not control what the other firm produces. Therefore, P 120 q q 1 2 We assume that MC = 0. but we (Firm 1) have to take into consideration what the other firm does.

13-8 So how does this affect our decision? Profit maximization still requires that we produce until MR = MC. To get MR, we must first know Total Revenue (TR). It is as follows: 2 1 1 2 1 TR 120q q q q We can solve for MR=MC to get MR 1201 2q1 q2 0 Now we have a problem as we have no definitive answer to our production decision unless we know what the other firm is producing. (And, as you can imagine, the other firm has the same problem.) Firm 1's profit maximizing decision is a function of what Firm 2 is producing. Remember we derived Firm 2 s reaction function = q2 60 0.5q1 We can now look once again at TR function: 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 TR 120 q q (60 0.5 q ) q 60q 0.5q From that we can get MR: MR 60 q 1 We now set MR = MC and solve for q 1 as follows: MR 60 q 0 so q 1 = 60 If q 1 = 60 then q 2 = 60-0.5(60) = 30 1 The outcome in terms of Price and Profits is: P * = 120 Q = 120 60-30 = 30 1 * = 30(60) - 0 = 1800 2 * = 30(30) =900 From above we can see that 1) The profit of the leader is higher than in Cournot. 2) Profit of the follower is less than Cournot, but higher than perfect competition. Why? Because the leader can commit to a level of output before the other, uses this commitment to grab the bulk of the market. The follower reacts nonaggressively to this because of the lack of business-stealing effects in this model. 3) Price above marginal cost

13-9 Why? Because both firms act as monopolists on their residual demand curve (as in Cournot) 4) Profit of the leader (and industry) lower than monopoly profit.

13-10 Collusion Now if you think about what the firms should do, you may realize that there is an incentive to collude. There are only two of them so why compete and drive our profits to zero when we could co-operate with each other and earn economic profits. This would reduce our industry analysis back to a monopoly situation. The two firms would collectively want to produce 60 and then they can divide up the profits what every way they like (no matter how they divide both sides are better off than competing (collectively producing 80). What are the problems with collusion (or cartels)? First, it presumes that they can prevent entry. All of the benefits of the monopoly situation arose because no one else could the industry and acquire those economic profits. In perfect competition, that entry brought profits to zero. So now that they collude and make profits they have to have some way to prevent others from coming in. And that's a tough problem -- just ask OPEC. Second, once the collusion begins, everyone has an incentive to cheat. They have an incentive to cheat because MR > MC therefore if they produce more a firm can increase its profits. Given that is true for one firm, it's true for all firms -- so if all firms cheat, then all profits are dissipated away and we're back to a competitive outcome. So what you really want is for everyone else to keep their word and you cheat. There are also other problems like how do you actually divide up the profits but we'll come back to all this. But, cartels are inherently unstable.