Cartelization of Cross-Holdings

Similar documents
INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

Relative profit maximization and Bertrand equilibrium with quadratic cost functions

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Centre for Development Economics

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Networks, Network Externalities and Market Segmentation

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang *

4 Effects of a change in marginal cost (Extra) α β q * 1. The reason is that this is the first-order condition for the firm's choice of quantity.

Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

OLIGOPOLY: Characteristics

Economics 384 B1. Intermediate Microeconomics II. Assignment 2. S Landon Winter 2007

Big fish eat small fish: On merger in Stackelberg markets

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

UNIT 11 COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY

LECTURE 13 THE NEOCLASSICAL OR WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM INTRODUCTION

Lecture 4: Will profits in reality be higher or lower than under Cournot? Tom Holden

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Network Flows. 7. Multicommodity Flows Problems. Fall 2010 Instructor: Dr. Masoud Yaghini

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

R&D Cooperation and Industry Cartelization

Partial Equity Ownership and Knowledge Transfer. Arghya Ghosh and Hodaka Morita

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

ECON 5113 Microeconomic Theory

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming

Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Yasuhiko Nakamura Graduate School of Economics, Waseda University. Abstract

Module 6: Mergers in a Dynamic World

Volume 31, Issue 4. Free entry and welfare with price discrimination

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Competitor Collaboration and Product Distinctiveness. Arghya Ghosh and Hodaka Morita

New Perspectives on Industrial Organization

1 Double Marginalization & Two Part Tariff

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

The Core Pareto Optimality and Social Welfare Maximizationty

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

Empirical Applications in Transport Economics. Philippe Gagnepain. Office: Tel:

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Pollution from Cournot Duopoly. and the Effect of Ambient Charges

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Hotelling s (1929) linear city. Hotelling

Horizontal Information Sharing in the Cluster Supply Chain

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

Volume 30, Issue 3. Specialization through Cross-licensing in a Multi-product Stackelberg Duopoly

Relative profit maximization and the choice of strategic variables in duopoly

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers

Empirical Models of Pricing in Industries with Differentiated-Products

Mixed Duopoly and Strategic Trade Policy

Lecture 3 OLIGOPOLY (CONTINUED) 13-1 Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

Three Rules and Four Models

Three Rules and Four Models

MERGER INCENTIVES OF COST ASYMMETRIC FIRMS UNDER PRODUCTION DIFFERENTIATION XIA LI B.A., KANSAS STATE UNIVERSITY, 2010 A REPORT

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Algorithmic Collusion For IO Reading Group

- Material influence - Level of shareholding - Plus factors. - Cooperative / concentrative JV - R&D - Extraterritoriality

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Tacit collusion with price matching punishments

FIRST FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF WELFARE ECONOMICS

Chapter 17 Regulation and Antitrust Law

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Merger Analysis and Anti-Trust

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

ECONOMICS. A brief introduction. 1. Economics. What is this?.

PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND DEMAND ELASTICITY

Industrial Organization

CH 17 sample MC. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 13. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 13. Chapter Outline. Some Specific Oligopoly Models : Cournot, Bertrand and Stackelberg Competition When There are Increasing Returns to Scale

3. Cartels and Collusion

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Abstract

Microeconomics (Fall term) Syllabus

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No QUANTIFYING THE COORDINATED EFFECTS OF PARTIAL HORIZONTAL ACQUISITIONS

The Retail Space-Exchange Problem with. Pricing and Space Allocation Decisions 1

Delegation and Firms Ability to Collude: Do Incentive Schemes Matter? Patrick de Lamirande. Cape Breton University, Sydney, Canada. Jean-Daniel Guigou

Volume 29, Issue 4. Mixed oligopoly and spatial agglomeration in quasi-linear city

Oligopoly is a market structure in which Natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms. A small number of firms compete.

Imperfect Competition

Market Structure - Oligopoly

Transcription:

Cartelization of Cross-Holdings Cheng-Zhong Qin, Shengping Zhang and Dandan Zhu May 25, 2012 Abstract Cross-holdings between firms cause their profits to be mutually dependent. This paper analyzes a model of cross-holdings that calls for the firms to consider financial interests of the competitors in their profits instead of operating earnings. It is shown that cross-holdings induce tacit formation of cartels when they are irreducible. Consequently, the irreducibility of cross-holdings should be regarded as a condition, under which the firms attempt to bring about substantial lessening of competition. Keywords: Antitrust; Cartel; Cross-holding; Financial interest JEL Code: C72, G0, L1 1 Introduction Cross-holding refers to a situation where a firm acquires equity shares in another firm. Cross-holdings are frequently observed in practice. For example, Northwest Airlines acquired a 14% equity position in Continental Airlines in 1998. Microsoft acquired approximately 7% of the non-voting stock of Apple in 1997 and in 1999, it held a 10% stake in Inprise/Borland Corp. The former is a historic rival of Microsoft in PC market and the latter is a major competitor in the software applications market. 1 The We thank Hongbin Cai, Ted Frech, and David Malueg for helpful comments. Contact: Cheng-Zhong Qin, Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA 93106-9210, qin@econ.ucsb.edu; Shengping Zhang, Guanghua School of Management, Peking University; zsp@gsm.pku.edu.cn; Dandan Zhu, Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA 93106-9210, zhu@econ.ucsb.edu. 1 Microsoft Investments Draw Federal Scrutiny, Pittsburg Post-Gazette, August 10, 1997, B-11; Corel Again Buys a Victim of Microsoft Juggernaut, The Ottawa Citizen, February 8, 2000, C1. 1

Japanese and the U.S. automobile industries are two of many that feature complex webs of cross-holdings (see Alley, 1997). We consider cross-holdings which are passive, in the sense that the acquiring firm is entitled to a share of the acquired firm s profit but not decision making. That is, the acquiring firm is entitled to financial interests in the acquired firm s profits only. Partial ownership interests have been often examined in the context of Section 7 of the Clayton Act. According to the statutory language, Section 7 of the Clayton Act shall not apply to persons purchasing such stock [1] solely for the investment and [2] not using the same by voting or otherwise to bring about, or in attempting to bring about, the substantial lessening of competition. (see O Brien and Salop, 2000). Due to the lack of decision right, passive cross-holdings are solely for the purposes of investment, because firms continue to be independent and compete with each other. However, it is not clear whether by engaging in cross-holdings firms attempt to bring about substantial lessening of competition. Reynolds and Snapp (1986) were the first to analyze competitive implications of cross-holdings. They assumed that firms consider competitors financial interests in their operating earnings (profits from ordinary production). Firms profits under this approach are formulated by diving their earnings in proportion to equity shares. As pointed out in Reynolds and Snapp (p. 144), this formulation of firms profits is appropriate if owners are managers, or if managers view equity holdings by competitors as different from those by external equity holders (private investors or firms outside the industry). For an oligopoly with a homogenous product, Reynolds and Snapp showed that the Cournot equilibrium of the output market will become less competitive, with aggregate output level falling toward the monopoly level as cross-holdings increase. Cross-holdings do not imply complete mergers unless they are large enough according to these results. 2 Flath (1991) adopted a different approach under which firms profits are given by their operating earnings plus financial interests in rivals profits. Firms under this approach do not consider competitors financial interests. As a result, total profits of the firms exceed total industry s operating earnings, which implies double counting. Competitive implications of cross-holdings under this approach are qualitatively similar 2 Alley (1997) applied the Reynolds and Snapp s (1986) approach to analyze the effect of crossholdings on the degree of competition in the US and Japanese automobile industries. Malueg (1992) considered the collusive effect of cross-holdings in a repeated Cournot duopoly also using this approach. Cross-holdings weakens output market competition following a breakdown of a collusive scheme. Contrasting to the Reynolds and Sanpp s (1986) results on competitive implications of crossholdings, Malueg showed that cross-holdings have an ambiguous effect on collusion. 2

to those in Reynolds and Snapp (1986). In this paper, we analyze an alternative profit formulation that calls for firms to consider competitors financial interests as in Reynolds and Snapp (1986), but with financial interests in profits instead of operating earnings. Thus, firms under our approach divide profits in proportion to equity shares. Aside from the difference between financial interests in operating earnings and financial interests in profits, the appropriateness of this formulation can be justified by similar characteristics of the firms or behavioral conditions on managers as Reynolds and Snapp considered for their profit formulation. As with Flath s (1991) approach, having financial interests in profits implies that firms consider indirect as well as direct financial interests. Total profits of the firms equal to total industry s operating earnings under our approach. Furthermore, competitive implications of cross-holdings significantly differ from those found in the literature. We show that, under the condition of irreducibility of cross-holdings, firms are each induced to guide their individual choices by the maximization of total operating earnings. That is, a cartel between the firms is tacitly induced. More generally, when cross-holdings can be grouped into irreducible blocks, firms are tacitly induced to partition themselves into disjoint cartels. These results do not depend on whether firms use price or quantity to compete in output market. An implication of these results is that the irreducibility of cross-holdings between firms within a group should be taken as a condition, under which member firms attempt to bring about substantial lessening of competition. The irreducibility of cross-holdings means that each firm has either direct or indirect equity holding in the profits of each of the other firms. On the other hand, an irreducible block is a group of firms such that cross-holdings between them are irreducible and separable from the rest of the firms. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the model. Section 3 presents the results and Section 4 concludes. 2 Model We consider an industry with n firms. Firm i s choice set is denoted by X i (e.g., the set of prices or quantities). Set X = X 1 X 2 X n. The profits of firm i resulting from a choice profile x = (x 1, x 2,, x n ) X are called the operating earnings of firm i and are denoted by πi (x). Set π (x) = (π1(x),, πn(x)). By normalization, we can take the total number of equity shares within each firm 3

to be one. Denote by a i = (a i1, a i2,, a in ) the row vector of equity shares a ij held by firm i in firm j for i j and a ii = 1 a ji. (1) j i Let A denote the cross-holding matrix with a i as the i-th row. As a non-harmful assumption, we assume a ii > 0 for all i. With (1), the transpose of A is a stochastic matrix or A is column stochastic. We say that cross-holdings between member firms of a group S are separable if a ij = a ji = 0, i S, j / S. (2) We use π(x) = (π 1 (x),, π n (x)) to denote profit allocation resulting from the operating earnings allocation π (x) and cross-holding matrix A. Let A S denote the sub-matrix obtained from A by removing the rows and columns that correspond to firms not in S, and let π S (x) = (π i (x)) denote the sub-vector of π(x). If crossholdings between firms in group S are separable, we require A S π S(x) = π S(x). (3) The right-hand-side of equation (3) is the column vector of profits that firms in group S end up getting at choice profile x and cross-holding matrix A. In comparison, the left-hand-side is the column vector of profits which these firms will get when crossholdings between them are characterized by matrix A, and their profits are divided in proportion to equity shares. If follows that formulating profits according to (3) requires that firms consider financial interests of the competitors in their profits. Next, as a natural condition, we also require that the resulting profit allocation be feasible, in the sense that the allocation cannot involve profit sharing by member firms of a separable group in non-member firms nor conversely. This means that the allocation of profits must also satisfy: if cross-holdings between firms in S are separable. 3 π i (x) = πi (x) (4) 3 Firm i maximizes n j=1 a ijπj (x) in Reynolds and Snapp (1986) while it maximizes π i(x) = πi (x)+ j i a ijπ j (x) in Flath (1991). The former restricts financial interests to be in operating earnings only while the latter covers financial interests in profits, but it implies n i=1 π i(x) > n i=1 π i (x). 4

3 Cartelization As noted before, (1) implies that each cross-holding matrix A is column stochastic. If condition (2) holds for group S, then the sub-matrix A S of cross-holdings between member firms of group S is also column stochastic. 3.1 Cartel Formation We say that cross-holdings between firms in group S is irreducible if for any two firms in S, a family of intermediate member firms of group S can be found such that when they are properly ordered, each firm holds equity share in the next firm according to the order. That is, each firm in group S has either direct or indirect equity holding in each of the other firms within group S. Formally, cross-holdings between firms of group S, represented by A S, are irreducible if A S is irreducible or equivalently, if any two member firms i j of S, there is a family i 0, i 1,, i m of m + 1 member firms for some finite integer m such that i = i 0, j = i m, and a ik 1 i k > 0 for k = 1, 2,, m (see Seneta, 1981, p. 18). Proposition 1 Assume cross-holdings between firms in group S are irreducible and separable. (I) If πi (x) 0 for all x X and all i S, then there exists a unique vector γ S = (γ i ) such that γ i > 0, i S, γ i = 1 (5) and π i (x) = γ i πi (x), x X, i S (6) is the unique non-negative solution for (3) and (4). (II) If π i ( ) is continuous and X i is compact for all i S, then there exists a vector γ S = (γ i ) such that (5) holds and π S (x) as determined by (6) is a solution for (3) and (4). Proof. See Appendix. Observe that only non-negative solutions for (3) and (4) are sensible when firms operating earnings are non-negative. Observe also that the Bertrand model satisfies the non-negativity assumption when firms marginal costs are constant and fixed costs are zero. The reason is that the choice set X i can be restricted, without loss of generality, 5

to contain prices not below firm i s marginal cost. In contrast, the Cournot model satisfies the continuity and compactness assumption if demand is continuous and there is either a finite capacity for each firm or a finite total quantity resulting in price equal to 0. By (5) and (6), γ can be regarded as a distribution of relative shares in total operating earnings among firms within group S. Since γ is independent of the choice profile x, (6) implies that the choices of the member firms of group S are each guided by the maximization of the group s total profits. Consequently, a cartel among them with γ as the distribution of their relative shares of operating earnings is induced. The difference between part (I) and part (II) is that the relative share distribution is unique in the former, while this uniqueness is not guaranteed in the latter. A more general result can be established when it is possible to partition the crossholding matrix into irreducible blocks. The proof is similar to the proof of Proposition 1. For this reason, the proof is omitted. Proposition 2 Assume firms can be partitioned into disjoint groups S 1, S 2,, S l such that cross-holdings between firms in group S h are irreducible and separable for all h = 1, 2,, l. (I) If π i (x) 0 for all x X and all i, then there exists a unique vector γ R n such that for all h, (i) γ i > 0 for i S h, (ii) h γ i = 1, and (iii) π i (x) = γ i j S h π j (x) for x X and i S h is the unique non-negative solution for (3) and (4) with S = S h. (II) If π i ( ) is continuous and X i is compact for all i, then there exists a vector γ R n such that γ satisfies (i) and (ii) and π Sh (x) as in (iii) is a solution for (3) and (4) with S = S h for all h. A sufficient condition for the irreducibility of cross-holdings is for each firm to hold a positive amount of equity share in each of the other firms. However, such complete direct holdings are not necessary for the irreducibility of cross-holdings. As an example, suppose that each firm i holds 1% of equity share in firm m + 1 and zero percent in any other firm s. 4 That is, suppose that the cross-holding matrix is A = 99 100 0 99 100 4 We take i + k to be i + k n when i + k > n.. 1 0 0 100. 1 0 100. 1 99 0 0 100 100.. 6

Simple analysis shows that cross-holdings between the n firms as described by the preceding matrix A are irreducible. 4 Conclusion Behavioral implications of cross-holdings depend on the formulation of firms profits. Two approaches to profit formulation have been proposed and analyzed in the literature. One approach assumes that firms consider competitors financial interests in operating earnings, while the other approach assumes that firms do not consider competitors financial interests. Under both approach, cross-holdings do not imply formation of cartels unless they are large enough. We analyzed a different approach to the formulation of firms profits, under which firms divide profits instead of operating earnings in proportion to equity shares. Thus, firms under our approach consider competitors financial interests in their profits instead of operating earnings. Competitive implications under this approach significantly differ from those found in the literature. We showed that firms will be tacitly induced to form a cartel if cross-holdings between them are irreducible, even though they continue to be independent in their decision making and compete with one another. Accordingly, firms attempt to bring about substantial lessening of competition when crossholdings are irreducible. Consequently, our results suggest that the irreducibility of cross-holdings should be regarded as a condition to raise antitrust concerns. Appendix Proof of Proposition 1: Since A S is irreducible and a ii > 0 for all i S, A S is also primitive (Seneta, 1981, Theorem 1.4). Consider first the case where πi (x) 0 for all x X and all i S. In this case, part (I) holds automatically when π i (x) = 0. Thus, assume π i (x) > 0. Since A S is stochastic, the Perron-Frobenius eigenvalue of A S is 1 (Seneta, 1981, Corollary 1 on p. 8). By results for primitive non-negative matrices (Seneta, 1981, Theorems 1.1 and 1.6), there exists a unique vector γ S = (γ i ) such that 5 A S γ S = γ S, γ i = 1, and γ i > 0, i S, (A1) 5 The positive vector γ S is the normalized Perron-Frobenius eigenvector of matrix A S. 7

and A S η S = η S, η i = 1, and η i 0 η S = γ S. (A2) Since π i (x) > 0, (4) implies π i(x) > 0. Thus, if π i (s) 0 for all i S, then it follows from (3), (A1) and (A2) that ( ) πi (x) j S π = γ S. j(x) By (4), the preceding equation is equivalent to π i (x) = γ i πi (x), i S. Since γ is unique, π S (x) given in the preceding equation is the unique non-negative solution for (3) and (4). This completes the proof of part (I). Consider now the case where π i (x) is continuous and X i is compact for all i S. In this case, let π i be the minimum of π i (x) over X and let π i (x) = π i (x) π i. (A3) Then, π i (x) 0 for all x X and all i S. Fixing x X, by replacing π (x) with π (x) as the operating earnings, it follows from the preceding proof of part (I) that there exists a positive vector γ S = (γ i ) such that it satisfies (A1), (A2), and satisfies and Next, set π i (x) = γ i π i (x), i S A S π S(x) = π S(x) π i (x) = π i (x). π i (x) = π i (x) + γ i π i, i S. (A4) (A5) (A6) (A7) 8

Then, by (A1) and (A3) (A7), and ( A S π S(x) = A S π S(x) + π i ) ( A S γ S = π S(x) + π i (x) = ( )( π i (x) + γ i π i (x) = γ i πi (x). This shows that π S (x) given in (A7) solves (3) and (4). π i π i ) = πi (x) ) γ S = π S(x) References [1] Alley, W. A. (1997): Partial Ownership Arrangements and Collusion in the Automobile Industry, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 45, 191-205. [2] O Brien, D. P. and S. C. Salop (2000): Competitive Effects of Partial Ownership: Financial Interests and Corporate Control, Antitrust Law Journal, 67, 559-614. [3] Flath, D. (1991): When is it Rational for Firms to Acquire Silent Interests in Rivals? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, 573-583. [4] Malueg, D. (1992): Collusive Behavior and Partial Ownership of Rivals, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 27-34. [5] Reynolds, R. and B. Snapp (1986): The Competitive Effects of Partial Equity Interests and Joint Ventures, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 4, 141-153. [6] Seneta, E. Non-Negative Matrices and Markov Chains, Second Edition, Springer- Verlag, 1981. 9