The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence

Similar documents
Trade in Intermediate Goods, Armington Elasticity and Exchange Rate Pass-through. Fumihide TAKEUCHI Tokai University (Japan)

Jaana Korhonen, 3rd International Congress on Planted Forests Porto, Portugal May 18, 2013

10 ECB HOW HAVE GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS AFFECTED WORLD TRADE PATTERNS?

TUAC Comments on the OECD Employment Outlook Making the case for coordinated and multi-employer collective bargaining systems

GRI Sustainability Reporting Statistics Publication year By Report Services

Detailed Data from the 2010 OECD Survey on Public Procurement

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy

GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY DIRECT AND INDIRECT EXPORTS

A Ten Year Strategic Outlook for the Global Flexible Plastic Packaging Market. Sample pages. Commodity Inside Ltd

Communication Costs and Agro-Food Trade in OECD. Countries. Štefan Bojnec* and Imre Fertő** * Associate Professor, University of Primorska, Faculty of

The Implications of Global Ecological Elasticities for Carbon Control: A STIRPAT Formulation

Developing a Global Workforce January 26, 2012

Economic development and Environmental quality: The environmental Kuznets curve for water pollution

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation

Energy Efficiency Indicators: The Electric Power Sector

In 2013, global production

The Comparative Growth of Goods and Services Prices

A decade of oil demand

The Future of Nuclear Power after Fukushima

ITAM Mexico City, 27 October 2016

A rm s-length transfer prices for the remuneration of

Unionization and Informal Economy

Welcome to the Bank Statement Processing introduction topic. During this training, we use the acronym BSP for Bank Statement Processing.

Modeling of Exports Flows in the Visegrad Sub-Region

WORKFORCE METRICS BENCHMARK REPORT

Carbon Intensity Changes in the Asian Dragons. Lessons for climate policy design.

ATINER's Conference Paper Series CBC

WATER PRICING Seizing a Public Policy Dilemma by the Horns

ASSESSING GOOD PRACTICES IN POLICIES AND MEASURES TO MITIGATE CLIMATE CHANGE IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE. Elena Petkova

Steel, Industrial Policy, and Economic Performance. Bruce Blonigen University of Oregon and NBER

Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02)

Energy Efficiency in Fossil-Fuel Electricity Generation: A Panel Data Empirical Analysis

Industrial Convergence in East Asia. July 1, Akira Kohsaka. Jun-ichi Shinkai

Key results from the survey on organic. Organic Agriculture Worldwide. agriculture worldwide 2012

A note on power comparison of panel tests of cointegration An application on. health expenditure and GDP

Enhancing Productivity Growth. Philippe Aghion

Impact of MRCT after ICH E17 fully implement -Industry perspective-

Siemens Partner Program

Energy Innovation Scoreboard A Pilot Framework with a Focus on Renewables

Non-technical Innovations Definition, Measurement & Policy Implications. The new service economy: growth and implications for service innovation

Global Energy Production & Use 101

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 12 ( 2014 )

The Great Synchronisation: what do high-frequency statistics tell us about the trade collapse?

The US dollar exchange rate and the demand for oil

Press Release. Wind turbines generate more than 1 % of the global electricity. Worldwide Capacity at 93,8 GW 19,7 GW added in 2007

Convergence in consumption habits: what goods and services are more likely to experience growth in Spain in the future?

Energy Subsidies, Economic Growth, and CO 2 emissions

Urban Energy Use and Carbon Emissions. Matthias Ruth WEO Team Member Center for Integrative Environmental Research University of Maryland

OECD WORK ON GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS AND TRADE IN VALUE ADDED

Emissions Trading System (ETS): The UK needs to deliver its share of the total EU ETS emissions reduction of 21% by 2020, compared to 2005;

Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits

Energy security indices

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF IT, SOFTWARE, AND THE MICROSOFT ECOSYSTEM ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

Well-being in regions: Building more coherent policies for a better growth model

An Account of Global Factor Trade

Evolution of Production Network: Measuring Trade in value-added (TiVA)

Highlights. Figure 1. World Marketed Energy Consumption by Region,

Are Fluctations In Energy Consumption Transitory Or Permanent? Evidence From A Fourier Adf Unit Root Test

Assessing country procurement systems and supporting good practice: The contribution of the 2015 OECD Recommendation on Public Procurement

Global Commerce Review EMEA, Q2 2018

Global Commerce Review. Americas, Q2 2018

Emerging Global Trade Patterns: USDA s Long-term Agricultural Projections

GLOBAL COALITION FOR GOOD WATER GOVERNANCE

COMPENSATION REVIEW AND ANALYSIS SERVICES TAKING THE WORK OUT OF YOUR COMPENSATION REVIEW PROCESS

1 Controlling for non-linearities


The Innovation Union Scoreboard: Monitoring the innovation performance of the 27 EU Member States

Argus Ethylene Annual 2017

International Price Dispersion and the Direction of Trade

Estimating the Indirect Economic Benefits from Research

151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H Fax Andrew Sharpe and John Tsang

The Dynamics of Trade and Competition

The Job Quality Index from PIAAC Singapore and International Comparisons

Rethinking E-Government Services

FACTS ABOUT THE AUSTRALIAN RETAIL FUELS MARKET & PRICES

World KLEMS initiative

R&D in WorldScan. Paul Veenendaal. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis. R&D in WorldScan

PrimePCR Pricing and Bulk Discounts

SITSI Global Datamart

Energy Intensity of GDP as an Index of Energy Conservation

The EU ETS: Over-allocation or Abatement?

Solution Partner Program Global Perspective

Inclusive Growth in Scotland. Gary Gillespie, Chief Economist Scottish Government 12 th February 2016

Decomposing Services Exports Adjustments along the Intensive and Extensive Margin at the Firm-Level

Employment and Productivity: Exploring the Trade-off

GLOBAL VIDEO-ON- DEMAND (VOD)

CompNet approach to competitiveness: Results and policy use

Chapter 22 An Economic and Environmental Assessment of FTA in East Asian Region by CGE Approach


Energy and CO 2 emissions in the OECD

research paper series

Decision taken from September 2010 Four focus areas: megacities, informal sector, global recycling markets & international aid tools Members: Antonis

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence

Why Export? Mitigating Risk by Diversifying Your Market Portfolio

World KLEMS initiative: the future

Analyses of woody biomass supply systems costs in Europe. Fulvio Di Fulvio, Ola Lindroos, Nicklas Forsell

Productivity Key measurement challenges

The Changing Shape of Global Olive Oil Value Chain

The Productivity Effect of Temporary Agency Work

Costs and Benefits of Apprenticeship Training*

Transcription:

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence ECB - BoC Workshop : Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Adjustment 15-16 June 2011 Christiane Baumeister Ehsan U. Choudhri Lawrence Schembri This presentation represents the views of the authors, not the Bank of Canada

Introduction & Motivation: HBS Hypothesis Developed by Harrod (1933), Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964) To explain sustained real exchange rate (RER) appreciations in rapidly growing economies, via productivity increases Strongest evidence in Japan and Eastern Europe Posits that relatively strong productivity growth in the tradables sector raises the relative price of nontradables and the RER Provides an argument against long-run purchasing power parity 2

1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Japan: RER and Real Per Capita Income 275 (1970 = 100) 250 225 200 175 150 125 100 REER index Real GDP per capita index 3

Poland, Czech & Slovakia: RER & Real Per Capita Income 200 (1994 = 100) 175 150 125 100 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Poland - REER index Czech Republic - REER index Slovakia - REER index Poland - Real GDP per capita index Czech Republic - Real GDP per capita index Slovakia - Real GDP per capita index 4

Brazil, Chile and Mexico: RER & Per Capita Income 180 160 (1994 = 100) 140 120 100 80 60 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Brazil - REER index Brazil - Real GDP per capita index Chile - REER index Chile - Real GDP per capita index Mexico - REER index Mexico - Real GDP per capita index 5

RER adjustment in Latin America versus East Asia Chart 2: EME Real Effective Exchange Rate REER 1990 = 100 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Latin America East Asia Source: JP Morgan 6

Purpose: Reconciling the evidence The main purpose of the paper is to attempt to reconcile the mixed evidence surrounding the HBS hypothesis Both theoretically and empirically Derive a theoretically based empirical model Using per-capita income is not a true test of HBS hypothesis Estimate the model using a consistent OECD panel database on labour productivity by sector 7

Methodology / Outline 1. Derive the conventional empirical model for the HBS hypothesis 2. Derive an extended version of the empirical model of the HBS hypothesis using a monopolistically competitive model 3. Estimate the empirical model using time series/panel data techniques 4. Interpret and reconcile the results 8

Theoretical Framework Derive the empirical relations to represent the HBS hypothesis Two countries (home and foreign), one factor (labour), and two composite goods (tradable and nontradable goods) Focus on long-run effects: Assume flexible prices, financial autarky, mobile labour and balanced trade To facilitate comparison across two models, assume CES aggregators and a continuum of goods in tradable and nontradable bundles 9

The Conventional Model Consumption: Aggregate, Nontradable and Tradable C C (1 ) C 1/ ( 1)/ 1/ ( 1)/ N T ( 1/ CN CN() i di i N ( 1/ CT CT( j) dj j T /( 1) /( 1) /( 1) Production: Nontradable and Tradable Y ( i) A L ( i) N N N Y ( j) A L ( j) T T T 10

The Conventional Model Real Exchange Rate Relation: Each country s tradable/nontradable productivity ratio affects the RER via the relative price of nontradables Assume that the share of nontradables is same across countries, the RER is related to home/foreign productivity ratio in each sector Letting a hat over a variable denote the log deviation from its initial value, obtain a typical form of the HBS relation: ˆ ˆ * ˆ ˆ * ˆ T * T N * N Q ( A A ) ( A A ) 11

Monopolistic Competition Model Monopolistic competition in each sector with symmetrical firms and free entry Nontradable good is still an aggregate of (nontradable) varieties Tradable good now is of a continuum of home & foreign varieties: /( 1) 1/ ( 1)/ 1/ ( 1)/ CT CH (1 ) C F, /( 1) /( 1) ( 1)/ * ( 1)/ * CH CH ( j) dj, CF C ( ) * j F j dj H j F 12

Monopolistic Competition Model 1/ AN and 1/ AH units of labor to produce a unit of a domestic nontradable and a tradable variety / A and / A fixed amounts for non-production activities N H In the monopolistic competition model, home-foreign productivity differentials affect the RER through two additional channels: 1. the terms of trade 2. the number of home and foreign varieties 13

Monopolistic Competition Model Real Exchange Rate Relation: Solve the model to derive: represents the conventional effect via the nontraded/traded price ratios T, Tare the terms of trade channel effects 1 2 N, N are the number of number of varieties channel effects 1 2 Qˆ ( )( Aˆ Aˆ * ) ( )( Aˆ Aˆ * ) * * 1 1 F H 2 2 N N 14

The Terms of Trade Channel The effects through the terms of trade channel depend on: 1. ε - elasticity of substitution between tradables & nontradables 2. η - elasticity of substitution between home & foreign tradables 3. θ θ* - home bias in the consumption of tradable goods The effects via the number of varieties channel also depends on the same parameters 15

Data Annual data from 1977 to 2006 30 observations per country 16 OECD countries: Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Korea, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Sweden, U.K. and U.S. RER and productivity differential data are calculated relative to the average of the rest of the sample RER is obtained using NER and CPI from the IMF s IFS database Labour productivity is output per employee in four tradable goods industries and five nontradable goods industries from the OECD s STAN database 16

Regression model and estimation Dynamic OLS specification (to incorporate co-integration) ln Qi = δi +βit(lnait - lnawt) + βin (lnain - lnawn) + one lead and one lag of the first differences HBS Hypothesis: βit > 0 and βin < 0 Three different panel DOLS techniques: 1. Fixed -Effect Panel: Homogeneous LR & SR coefficients 2. Pooled Mean-Group Panel: Homogeneous LR coefficients 3. Group Mean Panel: Panel average of heterogeneous LR coefficients 17

Estimation results: World Base DOLS Estimation Technique Tradable Productivity Differential Nontradable Productivity Differential Fixed-Effect Panel -0.31** (0.13) 0.43 (0.32) Pooled-Mean Group Panel -0.19*** (0.04) 0.04 (0.12) Group-Mean Panel -0.48*** (0.10) 0.29*** (0.13) Dependent Variable: lnrer Sample: 1977-2006 18

Estimation Results: Other Notable Findings Using the U.S. or Germany as the basis for comparison does not change the qualitative nature of the results Values/significance of the coefficients change somewhat The results using aggregate productivity as the explanatory variable, as a proxy for per capita income, are more mixed Estimates by country are very heterogeneous with no obvious pattern 19

Interpreting and Reconciling the Results The mixed results are consistent with other findings E.g., Peltonen and Sager (ECB, 2009) Theoretical reconciliation Numerically simulating the theoretical monopolistic competition model with different estimates for key substitution elasticities Empirical reconciliation Investigate robustness of the results 20

Home-Foreign Goods Substitution Elasticity The effect of the tradable productivity differential depends on η Below a critical value, the effects (via the terms of trade and number of varieties channels) can cause a real depreciation The increase in home productivity causes an increase in supply and a decline in the terms of trade Thus, the conventional HBS effect can be offset and even reversed for a small enough value of η 21

Tradable-Nontradable Substitution Elasticity If ε > 1 the nontradable productivity differential causes a RER appreciation via the terms of trade E.g., a productivity increase in home nontradables would raise the share of nontradables and reduce the supply of tradables, thereby increasing the terms of trade The nontradable productivity differential could also cause a real appreciation via the number of varieties Thus, the sign of the coefficient of non-tradable productivity differential in the conventional model could also be reversed 22

Reconciling the Results: Numerical Simulation We use data for OECD countries (averaged over periods & countries) to set the nontradable share equal to 0.73 and the home bias equal to 0.3. We let the elasticity of substitution between varieties ( ζ ) equal to 6 based on the evidence on mark-ups ~ 20% Estimates of the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign tradable goods (η) range from <1 to >>1 Estimates of elasticity of substitution between tradable and non-tradable goods (ε) has received less attention, but worth exploring Typically assumed to be close to one 23

Numerical simulation: Effects on lnq (RER) ε η ln Α T ln Α* T ln Α N ln Α* N 1.0 3.0 0.594-0.801 1.0 1.0-0.091-0.802 1.0 0.5-1.659-0.803 2.0 3.0 0.532-0.756 2.0 1.0-0.227-0375 2.0 0.5-0925 0.009 3.0 3.0 0.476-0.705 3.0 1.0-0.300-0.130 3.0 0.5-0.733 0.219 24

Empirical robustness Consider different samples periods Signs of estimated LR coefficients on the productivity differentials are sensitive to the sample period Lee and Tang (2007) also find that the results are sensitive to the definition of productivity (TFP versus labour) 25

Recursive Regression Results: U.S. Base 26

Recursive Regression Results: World Base 27

Concluding remarks Made progress in understanding mixed empirical results for HBS hypothesis by extending theoretical model Empirical results are unstable over time and across countries Sample may be too short to obtain low-frequency estimates Time series/panel techniques unable to remove cyclical effects and other macro factors Future work: Investigate the empirical results further (e.g., RER & China) Build a dynamic version of model to replicate mixed empirical results 28

Extra slides 29

The Terms of Trade Channel The effects through the terms of trade adjustment are [ (1 ) ](1 ) 1 ( 1) [ (1 ) ]( 1) 2 ( 1) 1 (1 )(1 ) (1 ) * ( 1) / ( ), The effects depend on: the elasticity of substitution between tradables & nontradables the elasticity of substitution between home & foreign tradables the home bias in the consumption of tradable goods 30

The Number of Varieties Channel The effects through the adjustment of number of varieties are (1 ) 1 1 1 ( 1) 2 1 1 These effects also depend on the two elasticities and home bias 31

Implications for the Productivity Effects Adjustment in terms of trade can weaken or even reverse the effect of the tradable productivity differential on RER via supply effects (Benigno and Thoenissen, 2003) The effect through the number of varieties channel has not been fully explored The role of the two channels for the effect of the nontradable productivity differential also needs to be examined 32

Home-Foreign Substitution Elasticity: Estimates Controversy about the value of the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign tradable goods Estimates based on macro models indicate that the value of this elasticity is low and below 1.0 (Bergin, 2006; Lubik and Schorfheide, 2005) Studies based on the disaggregated trade data suggest the average value of the elasticity to be much larger (Imbs and Mejean, 2009) 33

Tradable-Nontradable Substitution Elasticity: Estimates Elasticity of substitution between tradable and non-tradable goods has received less attention Typically assumed to be close to one But this assumption is not based on empirical estimation, and this elasticity could be greater than one Given the uncertainty about the values of the two elasticities, we consider a wide range of values for these elasticities 34