Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Abstract

Similar documents
Capacity Choice in the Mixed duopoly with Product Differentiation. Abstract

Mixed Duopoly and Strategic Trade Policy

Optimal degree of privatization in a mixed oligopoly with multiple public enterprises

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract

Yasuhiko Nakamura Graduate School of Economics, Waseda University. Abstract

Shuichi Ohori Kyoto University. Abstract

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Lifetime Employment and a Sequential Choice in a Mixed Duopoly Market with a Joint-Stock Firm

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Volume 36, Issue 1. Privatization neutrality theorem in a mixed oligopoly with firm asymmetry. Kojun Hamada Faculty of Economics, Niigata University

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

Volume 29, Issue 4. Mixed oligopoly and spatial agglomeration in quasi-linear city

Relative profit maximization and the choice of strategic variables in duopoly

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTRA-INDUSTRY TRADE WITH BERTRAND AND COURNOT OLIGOPOLY: THE ROLE OF ENDOGENOUS HORIZONTAL PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION

Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang *

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

How does state ownership affect optimal export taxes? Abstract

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

Economics 384 B1. Intermediate Microeconomics II. Assignment 2. S Landon Winter 2007

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note

Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria", Games and Economic Behavior, 2, 29-46, 1990.

Key words: Franchise Fees, Competition, Double Marginalization, Collusion

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Imperfect Competition

Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions

Antitrust Policy and Environmental Protection. Abstract

Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. Equilibrium and Optimal R&D Roles in a Mixed Market. Vasileios Zikos WP

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects

A New Approach to Free Entry Markets in Mixed Oligopolies: Welfare Implications

14.54 International Trade Lecture 17: Increasing Returns to Scale

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

Big fish eat small fish: On merger in Stackelberg markets

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

References. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp

Process RDin Monopoly under Demand Uncertainty. Abstract

Volume 38, Issue 3. Why Firms Should Care for All Consumers

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1

Volume 31, Issue 4. Free entry and welfare with price discrimination

Temporary Protection and Technology Choice under the Learning Curve

Relative profit maximization and Bertrand equilibrium with quadratic cost functions

Social responsibility in a bilateral monopoly with R&D

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Optimal Privatization Policy under Private Leadership in Mixed Oligopolies

Government-Leading Welfare-Improving Collusion

Market Distortions and Public Enterprise Strategies in an International Mixed Oligopoly

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 4 pp Introduction

Privatization, Profit and Welfare in a Differentiated Network Duopoly

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

PRIVATIZATION AND CAPITALIST AND LABOR-MANAGED FIRMS: A NUMERICAL EXAMPLE

OLIGOPOLY: Characteristics

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

R&D Cooperation and Industry Cartelization

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik)

Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Abstract

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTER DISCUSSION PAPER

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki

Tariff Policy Towards a Monopolist in the Presence of Persuasive Advertising

Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion

Chapter 11 Perfect Competition

Overview 11/6/2014. Herfindahl Hirshman index of market concentration ...

Competition under Bertrand duopoly: low cost versus differentiation. Paper presented at

Welfare Enhancing Mergers under Product Differentiation

EXAMINATION #4 VERSION C General Equilibrium and Market Power November 24, 2015

Price vs. Quantity in Duopoly with Strategic Delegation: Role of Network Externalities

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note

Vasileios Zikos Department of Economics, Loughborough University. Abstract

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #9

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS. Golovko Sergiy

Does it Pay to be First? Sequential Locational Choice and Foreclosure*

Mixed Duopoly Under Vertical Differentiation

R&D Cooperation in a Three-Firm Cournot Industry*

Econ8500_Game_Theory. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Transcription:

Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Akira Nishimori Aichi University Hikaru Ogawa Nagoya University Abstract We analyze the capacity choice of firms in a long run mixed oligopoly market, in which firms decide not only production quantity but also capacity scale. Our main purpose is to show that while a profit maximizing firm maintains over capacity as a strategic device, a firm pursuing non pure profit chooses under capacity. This research was carried out while Ogawa was on leave at the University of Kentucky. He is very grateful to Martin School of Public Policy and Administration for its support. Citation: Nishimori, Akira and Hikaru Ogawa, (2004) "Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity?." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 12, No. 2 pp. 1 7 Submitted: January 14, 2004. Accepted: January 15, 2004. URL: http://www.economicsbulletin.com/2004/volume12/eb 04L30001A.pdf

1 Introduction It is commonly recognized that maintaining excess capacity plays an essential role as a strategic device in the oligopoly market. Excess capacity results often hold not only in the pure oligopoly market where profit-maximizing firms compete with each other, but also in the market where they compete with so-called labor-managed firms. In this paper, we reexamine the excess capacity result using a model of mixed duopoly market, where a profit-maximizing (private) firm competes with a welfare-maximizing (public) firm 1. Our result shows that while the private firm ops to maintain over capacity, the public firm chooses under capacity. In various contexts, it has been found that firms maintain excess capacity to make their rivals reduce output levels or to deter market entry. Dixit (1980), Brander and Spencer (1983) and Horiba and Tsutsui (2000) show that the investment needed to expand production capacity tends to be excessive in the pure oligopoly model. Stewart (1991), Zhang (1993), and Haruna (1996) extend the model into a non-pure oligopoly situation where profit-maximizing firms compete with labor-managed firms. One of the interesting conclusions they reach is that labor-managed firms have a greater incentive to choose excess capacity than profit-maximizing firms. The study most relevant to ours is provided by Wen and Sasaki (2001). They examine the capacity choice in the framework of a repeated mixed duopoly and conclude that the excess capacity held by the public firm sustains the subgame perfect equilibrium. In this paper, a different result from that of Wen and Sasaki willbeobtainedsincewemakeadifferent assumption about cost function and the structure of a game. In our model, the objective of a non-profit maximizing firm provides the key factor. The mechanism is related to the results of Harris and Wiens (1980) and Pal (1998), in which they find that being a welfare-maximizing public firm Stackelberg follower increases social welfare. We show in this paper that the public firm chooses to play the role of market follower by choosing under capacity in the Cournot mixed market. In order to highlight the possible difference in the firms incentives for choosing capacity levels, we shall present a model of a mixed duopoly situation. 1 See De Fraja and Delbono (1990) and Nett (1993) for general reviews of the mixed oligopoly model. 1

2 Model To describe the essence as simply as possible, we consider a mixed duopoly market. There are two firms operating in a homogeneous good market with inverse demand given by p = a Q = a (q a + q b ), a > 0 (1) where p is market price and Q is total output. q i denotes the output of firm i(= a, b). While firm a is a profit-maximizing private firm, firm b has an objective that is different from simple profit maximization. In this paper, we assume that firm b is a public firm maximizing the social surplus which is a summation between the consumer surplus and the firms profit. The firms have different technologies, represented by the cost function, C i (q i,x i ), where q i and x i are the production quantity and capacity of firm i, respectively. We assume that firms first choose the production capacity (plant size, etc.). After observing the plant size in the first stage, firms then determine the desired production quantity. For simplicity, following Vives (1986) and Horiba and Tsutsui (2000), we specify the cost function as C i (q i,x i )=m i q i +(q i x i ) 2. (2) Under this U-shaped cost function, the long-run average cost is minimized when quantity equals production capacity, q i = x i.inthispaperweassumem a <m b ; the private firm can produce more efficiently than the public firm at the efficient production-capacity level 2. The objective function of firm a is the profit givenby π a = pq a m a q a (q a x a ) 2. (3) The public firm b maximizes the social surplus described by SS = Q2 2 + π a + π b, (4) where Q 2 /2 is the consumer surplus and π b (= pq b m b q b (q b x b ) 2 )istheprofit of firm b. 2 We see no reason to assume m a m b because it would yield zero output for the private firm. 2

3 Equilibrium Following the standard equilibrium concept, we solve the model from the second stage. Given their production capacities, the maximization problem of each firm yields q a = a m a +2x a q b, 4 (5) q b = a m b +2x b q a. 3 (6) By solving (5) and (6), we obtain the output levels as q a = 2a + m b 3m a 2x b +6x a, (7) 11 q b = 3a 4m b + m a +8x b 2x a. (8) 11 In the first stage, firms know that their decision regarding the capacity level affects their output decision in the second stage. Hence, we can formulate the maximization problem of the private firm as follows: max qa π a =(a q a q b )q a m a q a (q a x a ) 2, s.t. (7) and (8). Solving the problem, we have x a = 12 49 (2a + m b 3m a 2x b ). (9) Similarly, the maximization problem for the public firm can be formulated as max qb SS = (q a + q b ) 2 +(a q a q b )q a m a q a (q a x a ) 2 2 +(a q a q b )q b m b q b (q b x b ) 2, s.t. (7) and (8), which yields x b = a m b 14 31 (m b m a +2x a ). (10) From (7)-(10), production quantity and capacity level are given by 3

x a = 12 7 (m b m a ) (11) x b = a 3m b 2m a (12) q a = 11 7 (m b m a ) (13) q b = (a 3m b 2m a )+ m b m a 7 (14) If we compare x i and q i, the following result can be obtained. Result. In the mixed duopoly market, neither firm chooses the most efficient capacity level associated with the equilibrium output. While the private firm chooses over capacity, x a >q a, the public firm chooses under capacity, x b <q b. Since the output-capacity difference imposes additional costs on the social surplus, it seems unreasonable for a public firm to maintain under capacity. However, there is a simple mechanism that justifies such behavior. To maximize the social surplus, it is desirable for a public firm to have total outputs provided by the private firm so that the price is set at private firm s long-run marginal cost; p = m a. This implies that the public firm tries to make the private firm produce more while the public firm produces less 3. Since there is a negative relationship between the capacity level of public firm and the output level of private firm, the public firm can improve the social surplus by reducing its own capacity. On the other hand, enlarging the production share in the market is desirable for the private firm. Hence, the private firm chooses over capacity while the public firm chooses under capacity as a strategic device. 4 Concluding Remarks It iscommonlybelievedthat maintainingexcess capacity benefits profit-maximizing firms. Furthermore, the excess capacity result has often been applied to non-profit maximizing firms, i.e., labor-managed and public firms. Conversely, in this paper, 3 This tendency has been pointed out by Pal (1998) when examining the endogenous order of moves in a mixed oligopoly market. In Pal s model, both public and private firms first announce when (what period) they will choose their quantity levels. After the announcement, they select the output levels. The results show that one of the equilibrium outcomes is that the private firm produces in the first period, implying that it acts as a Stackelberg leader and provides total output, whereas the public firm announces it will produce in the second period and chooses zero output in the first period. 4

we have shown that the public firm might choose under capacity so as to maximize the social surplus. This happens primarily because a welfare-maximizing firm prefers to act as a Stackelberg follower in the mixed duopoly market. It wants to induce the more efficient private firm to expand its output level. Since there is a negative relationship between the capacity level of public firm and the output level of private firm, a public firm can improve the social surplus by reducing its own capacity from the efficient level, inducing the private firm to produce more. References Brander J.A. and B.J. Spencer (1983) Strategic commitment with R&D: the symmetric case Bell Journal of Economics 14, 225-235. Dixit A. (1980) The role of investment in entry deterrence Economic Journal 90, 95-106. De Fraja G. and F. Delbono (1990) Alternatinve strategies of a public enterprise in oligopoly Journal of Economic Surveys 4, 1-17. HarrisR.G.andE.G.Wiens(1980) Government enterprise: an instrument for the internal regulation of industry Canadian Journal of Economics 13, 125-132. Haruna S. (1996) A note on holding excess capacity to deter entry in a labourmanaged industry Canadian Journal of Economics 29, 493-499. Horiba Y. and S. Tsutsui (2000) International duopoly, tariff policies and the case of free trade Japanese Economic Review 51, 207-220. Nett L. (1993) Mixed oligopoly with homogeneous goods Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 64, 367-393. Pal D. (1998) Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly Economics Letters 61, 181-185. Stewart G. (1991) Strategic entry interactions involving profit maximising and labour-managed firms Oxford Economic Papers 43, 570-583. Vives X. (1986) Commitment, flexibility, and market outcomes International Journal of Industrial Organization 4, 217-229. 5

Wen M. and D. Sasaki (2001) Would excess capacity in public firm be socially optimal? Economic Record 77, 283-290. Zhang J. (1993) Holding excess capacity to deter entry in a labour-managed industry Canadian Journal of Economics 26, 222-234. 6