An Economic Analysis of Generic Fluid Milk Advertising in Ontario, Quebec, the Maritime Provinces

Similar documents
Impact of Generic Milk Advertising on New York State Markets,

An Economic Analysis of Generic Milk Advertising Impacts on Markets in New York State

Impact of Generic Milk Advertising on New York State Markets. Harry M. Kaiser and Chanjin Chung*

An Economic Analysis of the Cattlemen s Beef Promotion and Research Board Demand-Enhancing Programs

Economic Evaluation Models of Generic Fluid Milk and Cheese Marketing Investment in Canada for the Period

National Check-off Study

UPDATE ON THE ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF THE CANADIAN DAIRY INDUSTRY IN 2015

Economic Returns from the Beef Checkoff

Oral Capps, Jr. Gary W. Williams* TAMRC Commodity Market Research Report No. CM November 2007

silled Pricillg:._A Conceptual D odel of C lass Assignment Outcomes

An Economic Analysis of Generic Milk Advertising Impacts on Markets in New York State. John Lenz Harry M. Kaiser and Challjin Chung

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. This research addresses two important questions regarding the Cattlemen's Beef Promotion and Research Board (CBB):

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

Dairy Replacement Programs: Costs & Analysis 3 rd Quarter 2012

Abstract. Acknowledgments

Implications for Producer s Risk Management Strategies

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

November 1999 NICPRE R.B Impact of Generic Fluid Milk and Cheese Advertising on Dairy Markets (Revised) by Harry M.

CANADIAN DAIRY COMMISSION

The law of supply states that higher prices raise the quantity supplied. The price elasticity of supply measures how much the quantity supplied

Dynamic market impacts of generic dairy advertising

Learning Note 11.1: Economic Theory of Pricing

Econ 303. Weeks 3-4 Consumer Theory

An Empirical Analysis of Demand for U.S. Soybeans in the Philippines

Chapter-5 Conclusions and Suggestions

Working Paper. The Impact of Generic Fluid Milk and Cheese Advertising on Regulated Dairy Product Markets: A System Dynamics Analysis

How Dairy Price Changes Influence the Consumers' Welfare

Chapter 3. Table of Contents. Introduction. Empirical Methods for Demand Analysis

Monopoly. The single seller or firm referred to as a monopolist or monopolistic firm. Characteristics of a monopolistic industry

An Analysis of Farm-Retail Price Spread for Jamaican Fresh Fruits. Abdullahi O. Abdulkadri

HOG INDUSTRY NEEDS MORE DOWNSIZING IN 2004

As of January 2000, Pennsylvania

AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS

The University of Zambia School of Humanities and Social Sciences The Department of Economics

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

Estimates of the Return on Marketing Investment for Australian Inbound Tourism

THE ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF THE CANADIAN DAIRY INDUSTRY IN Annual Dairy Policy Conference Dairy Farmers of Canada

Executive Summary. A literature review focusing on the potential issues associated with the exploration and extraction of petroleum;

NB: STUDENTS ARE REQUESTED IN THEIR OWN INTEREST TO WRITE LEGIBLY AND IN INK.

Agriculture Import Liberalization and Household Welfare in Sri Lanka

INTRODUCTION. Professional Accounting Supplementary School (PASS) Page 1

Egg Demand and the Impact of the American Egg Board: Executive Summary

Economic Benefits and Risks for Harvest Platform Adoption for NY Fruit Farms

Pork Industry Makes Turn for the Better

Milking Center Cost Study New York State

Chapter 4 DEMAND. Essential Question: How do we decide what to buy?

Canada s Integrated Energy & Macro Economic Modeling of Energy Efficiency Gains

Manure Application Cost Study New York State Spring 2012

THIS PAPER is concerned primarily with

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector

The Iowa Pork Industry 2008: Patterns and Economic Importance by Daniel Otto and John Lawrence 1

LECTURE NOTES ON MICROECONOMICS

The Economic Contributions of Agriculture in New York State (2014)

A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

2010 JOURNAL OF THE ASFMRA

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory, 01/07/2003. A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF IMPROVED ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN CANADA

Lecture 7 - Food Stamps: The Whitmore Study

Advertising in the U.S. Non-Alcoholic Beverage Industry: Are Spillover Effects Negative or Positive? Revisited using a Dynamic Approach

1. If the per unit cost of production falls, then... A.) the supply curve shifts right (or down)

Agriculture-Based Economic Development in New York State: Assessing the Inter-industry Linkages in the Agricultural and Food System

Organic Market Research Study

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

Japanese Demand for Wheat Characteristics: A Market Share Approach. By: Joe Parcell. and. Kyle Stiegert*

Outlook of the World Rice Industry Under Alternative Trade Liberalization Policies in Japan and Korea

ECON 203. Homework #1 Solutions

The Role of Small and Medium Farms in Modern Agriculture. Arden Esqueda Research and Analysis Directorate Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada June 2012

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

The Management of Marketing Profit: An Investment Perspective

Department of Applied Economics and Management Cornell University, Ithaca, New York USA

Agricultural Business on Price & Quantity of Hog and Economics Perspective on Tendency in Future

Analyzing the Impact of Chinese Wheat Support Policies on U.S. and Global Wheat Production, Trade and Prices

April An Analysis of New Brunswick s Productivity Performance, : Labour Productivity Driven by Capital Intensity Growth CENTRE FOR

3 RD BI-ANNUAL SOUTHWEST DAIRY MARKETING SYMPOSIUM

An Economic Analysis of U.S. Wheat Export Promotion

Overview of livestock farm operating expenses

Chapter 1. An Introduction to Econometrics. 1.1 Why Study Econometrics?

TRANSITION TO SIXTH FORM TASK FOLLOW US ON WEBSITE:

PRICES. Corn constitutes about 60 % of the normal poultry diet, and the remaining ingredients

CHAPTER 3: DATA AND RESULTS

Evaluating the Economic Benefits From the Canadian Beef Check Off

MML Lecture. Globalization and Smallholder Farmers

Farm Credit Canada Annual Report

Effects of discolouration losses in meat chain

Introduction Three disease outbreaks in potatoes have shut down the Canada/US border for Canadian seed potatoes in the last 20 years: Potato Virus Y n

ENGINEERING ECONOMICS AND FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING 2 MARKS

FOR MORE PAPERS LOGON TO

Chapter 2: Market Forces: Demand and Supply Answers to Questions and Problems

Analysis of Regulatory Compliance Costs: Part II

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Faculty of Arts and Science APRIL/MAY EXAMINATIONS 2006 ECO 100Y1 Y. Duration: 3 hours

Hotel Industry Demand Curves

Supply-Managed Supply Chains: An Assessment. Bruno Larue Professor, CREATE, U. Laval

07. Engel s Law of family expenditure and significance. - Consumer's surplus estimation and applications.

The Application and Extension of Jiangsu Agricultural Policy Analysis Model ( JAPA )

Location-Based ISONE Pollutant Intensity Analysis

SURVEY OF SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH AND EXPERIMENTAL DEVELOPMENT CLAIMANTS

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

CHAPTER 4: PERFECT COMPETITION

Food Marketing Policy. Issue Paper. Drafting of Connecticut Fair Milk Pricing Law: Further Thoughts on the Retail Price Collar. Ronald W.

Economics E201 (Professor Self) Sample Questions for Exam Two, Fall 2013

Transcription:

National Institute for Commodity Promotion & Research Evaluation January 2006 NICPRE 06-01 R.B. 2006-01 An Economic Analysis of Generic Fluid Milk Advertising in Ontario, Quebec, the Maritime Provinces by: Harry M. Kaiser John Cranfield Maurice Doyon Department of Applied Economics and Management College of Agriculture and Life Sciences Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853

The National Institute For Commodity Promotion Research and Evaluation The National Institute for Commodity Promotion Research and Evaluation was initially funded by a CSRS Special Grant in April 1994. The Institute is an offshoot of The Committee on Commodity Promotion Research (NEC-63). A component of the Land Grant committee structure to coordinate research in agriculture and related fields, NEC-63 was established in 1985 to foster quality research and dialogue on the economics of commodity promotion. The Institute s mission is to enhance the overall understanding of economic and policy issues associated with commodity promotion programs. An understanding of these issues is crucial to ensuring continued authorization for domestic checkoff programs and to fund export promotion programs. The Institute supports specific research projects and facilitates collaboration among administrators and researchers in government, universities, and commodity promotion organizations. Through its sponsored research and compilations of related research reports, the Institute serves as a centralized source of knowledge and information about commodity promotion economics. The Institute is housed in the Department of Applied Economics and Management at Cornell University in Ithaca, New York as a component of the Cornell Commodity Promotion Research Program. Institute Objectives Support, coordinate, and conduct studies to identify key economic relationships and assess the impact of domestic and export commodity promotion programs on farmers, consumers, and the food industry. Develop and maintain comprehensive databases relating to commodity promotion research and evaluation. Facilitate the coordination of multi-commodity and multi-country research and evaluation efforts. Enhance both public and private policy maker s understanding of the economics of commodity promotion programs. Facilitate the development of new theory and research methodology. It is the Policy of Cornell University actively to support equality of educational and employment opportunity. No person shall be denied admission to any educational program or activity or be denied employment on the basis of any legally prohibited discrimination involving, but not limited to, such factors as race, color, creed, religion, national or ethnic origin, sex, age or handicap. The University is committed to the maintenance of affirmative action programs which will assure the continuation of such equality of opportunity.

An Economic Analysis of Generic Fluid Milk Advertising in Ontario, Quebec, and the Maritime Provinces Harry M. Kaiser John Cranfield Maurice Doyon The authors are respectively, professor at Cornell University, associate professor at the University of Guelph and associate professor at Laval University

An Economic Analysis of Generic Fluid Milk Advertising in Ontario, Quebec, and the Maritime Provinces KEY RESULTS Generic fluid milk advertising in the Maritime provinces, Quebec and Ontario had a positive and statistically significant impact on fluid milk demand in these regions over the period 1990 to 2004. Taken together, non-advertising marketing elements (such as promotion, sponsorship, nutrition communication and public relations) had a positive and statistically significant impact on fluid milk demand in Quebec and the Maritime region, but a less certain impact in Ontario in the same time period. The average producer rate of return to actual generic fluid milk advertising over the period 2000 to 2004 are as follows: o Maritime: $2.2 for every dollar invested o Quebec: $7.4 for every dollar invested o Ontario: $3.4 for every dollar invested Further analysis suggests that over the period 2000 to 2004, the Maritime region overinvested in generic advertising, Quebec under-invested during the same time period, while Ontario s advertising expenditures were slightly below optimal. During the same time period, investment in non-advertising marketing activities in all three regions was below optimal (i.e. all provinces under-invested in these activities). Results suggest there is room to further increase producer benefits by increasing real expenditures on generic advertising in Quebec and Ontario, and real expenditures on non-advertising activities in all three regions. At the least, the status quo level of expenditure should compensate high media cost inflation in order to maintain real expenditure. In Quebec, future budget increases should focus on advertising rather than on nonadvertising marketing elements. ii

An Economic Analysis of Generic Fluid Milk Advertising in Ontario, Quebec, and the Maritime Provinces Executive Summary Over the last several decades, provincial milk boards in Canada have invested heavily in generic advertising of milk and dairy products. Such investment is undertaken with the intent of increasing consumption of milk and, given the supply management nature of milk production in Canada, raising producer revenues. Given the large amount of investment in advertising and promotion, it is important to conduct periodic economic evaluations to determine the profitability of these activities. While previous economic studies suggest that investment in generic fluid milk advertising does, indeed, generate a positive net return, there has not been an updated analysis of these activities for some time. Accordingly, the objectives of this study are twofold. First, to provide an economic assessment of the responsiveness of fluid milk consumption to milk advertising and promotion in Ontario, Quebec, and the Maritime provinces over the last several years. Second, to broadly evaluate a possible reallocation of advertising and promotion budgets between provinces. This analysis is conducted using econometric models of provincial or regional fluid milk demand in eastern Canada. The econometric results are used to simulate the impacts of various provincial advertising and non-advertising marketing (i.e. promotion, sponsorship, nutrition communication, public relations) scenarios for these three milk markets. First, two generic advertising scenarios are simulated: (1) a baseline scenario with generic advertising expenditures equal to historical levels, and (2) a no-advertising scenario, where generic advertising expenditures are set to zero. Based on the difference between these two scenarios, an average rate of return to advertising is calculated for each of the three regions. The average rate of return is a useful figure since it measures the overall profitability of the investment. Next, we

simulate the impact of increasing advertising or non-advertising marketing expenditure by $10,000 per quarter on consumption and producer revenues to ascertain the extent to which the resulting benefits exceed the costs in each region. Based on this simulation, a marginal rate of return to advertising and non-advertising marketing elements is calculated for each region. These marginal rates of return to advertising and promotion are useful for evaluating the optimality of existing marketing campaigns. In each market, per capita fluid milk sales are assumed to be affected not only by generic advertising and non-advertising demand enhancement expenditures (e.g., promotion, nutrition education, and sponsorships), but also by the retail price of milk, prices of substitutes for milk, consumer income, and seasonal indicator variables. While this was the initial specification used for each region, the final specification differs for each market in terms of which variables were included in the model. In addition, the dynamic effects of advertising and non-advertising marketing elements were modeled differently for each province. For example, for the Maritime region, only current advertising was included in the final specification. For Quebec, current and lagged advertising was included in the final specification. Lagged advertising captures any carry-over effect that advertising might have. Finally, in Ontario, lagged, but not current advertising was included in the model. These differences imply that the dynamic effects of advertising in each market are different, which may be related to the advertising campaign in each market and/or to differences in culture and demographics in each region. The econometric results reveal that generic fluid milk advertising in all three markets had a positive and statistically significant impact on per capita consumption. Quebec had the highest advertising elasticity equal to 0.060, i.e., a one percent increase in advertising results in a 0.060 percent increase in per capita demand. The Maritime region had the lowest advertising elasticity of 0.014, while Ontario s equaled 0.027. A statistical test was conducted to determine whether 2

these advertising elasticities were statistically different from each other. The results indicated that they were statistically different in each market. Non-advertising marketing element elasticities were also measured. In Ontario, expenditures on these non-advertising demand enhancing elements (i.e. ingredient/calendar, nutrition communication, promotion and public relations/sponsorship) were not found to have a statistically significant effect on demand for fluid milk. It should be noted, however, that the impact of these non-advertising marketing elements appears to be persistent; the dynamics for the non-advertising marketing activities are long, ranging between three and six quarters back. Moreover, it must be noted that the absence of a statistically significant relationship does not imply that no relationship exists, but that there is more uncertainty with respect to the precise size of this effect. In the Maritime region, the combination of promotion, nutritional communication, and sponsorship had a positive and marginally statistically significant impact on per capita milk demand. A one percent increase in expenditures on these activities was found to increase per capita milk demand by 0.008 percent holding all other demand factors constant. In Quebec, the combination of these activities had an elasticity value of 0.041, which was statistically significant. A simulation model is developed for each province to simulate market conditions with and without generic milk advertising. These scenarios are used to calculate an average rate of return on investment to advertising. The average rate of return is greater than one in each region and is the highest in Quebec at 7.4, followed by Ontario at 3.4 and the Maritime region at 2.2. The average rate of return means that each dollar invested in generic advertising has generated $7.40, $3.40 and $2.20 in net returns to dairy farmers in Quebec, Ontario and the Maritime region, respectively. These results suggest that dairy farmers are benefiting from generic milk advertising in each region of eastern Canada. 3

We also simulate market conditions based on several scenarios involving adding $10,000 per quarter to advertising or promotion in each region in order to compute marginal rates of return. Marginal rates of return are used to determine whether more or less money should be allocated to the market. A marginal rate of return above 1.0 implies that extra money in advertising or non-advertising marketing activities would generate a return for the incremental investment that is higher than its costs, and therefore is interpreted as under-spending. On the other hand, a marginal rate of return below 1.0 implies the opposite, i.e., too much money is being spent on the activity since the incremental costs are higher than its returns. The impact of increasing advertising spending (by $10,000 per quarter) is the greatest in Quebec, with a marginal producer rate of return of 5.04, followed by Ontario and the Maritime region with marginal producer rate of returns of 1.05 and 0.67, respectively. This implies that increasing advertising by $10,000 per quarter would result in an average increase in farm revenues of $50,400, $10,500, and $6,700 per quarter in Quebec, Ontario, and the Maritime region, respectively over this period. (Note that these calculations net out the marginal cost of production associated with producing more milk, as well as take into account a butterfat adjustment.) As for the impact of increasing expenditures on non-advertising demand enhancing activities, the impact is the greatest in Quebec, with a producer marginal rate of return of 3.95, followed by the Maritime region and Ontario with producer marginal rate of returns of 1.05 and 1.02, respectively. The latter number should be interpreted with caution because Ontario s elasticity coefficient for non-advertising activities is not statistically significant. It is interesting to note that Ontario s marginal rate of return for advertising is close to 1.0, meaning that advertising spending in real terms in that region seems nearly optimal (slightly under-investing). In Quebec, increasing advertising would generate benefits that are significantly larger than the costs of the additional spending. Regarding the Maritime region, increasing 4

generic promotion would generate less net revenues than the cost of the investment. In all regions, but the Maritime region, an incremental increase in advertising spending of $10,000 per quarter generates a better return than in the other non-advertising activities. Therefore, from an optimal point of view, Quebec should devote important parts of future budget increases to advertising. Among the three regions, Quebec would clearly benefit the most from an increase in advertising and promotion. Considering that the the three regions have pooled their advertising and promotion budget, these results suggest that advertising and non-advertising spending should be increased in Quebec, maintained in real terms in Ontario, while advertising marketing expenditures spending should be reduced in real terms in the Maritime region. 5

An Economic Analysis of Generic Fluid Milk Advertising in Ontario, Quebec, and the Maritime Provinces Introduction Over the last several decades, provincial milk boards in Canada have invested heavily in generic advertising of milk and dairy products. Such investment is undertaken with the intent of increasing consumption of milk and, given the supply management nature of milk production in Canada, raising producer revenues. Previous studies (primarily conducted by Ellen Goddard, see for example Goddard and McCutcheon 1993) suggest that investment in generic fluid milk advertising does generate a positive net return for producers. Within eastern Canada, Ontario, Quebec and the Maritime provinces have all used different advertising campaigns. Not only do the themes of these advertising programs differ, but so too does the mode of delivery (i.e., television, print media, etc). Following a greater integration of milk revenues in eastern Canada through milk pooling, it seems important to be able to access the marginal revenue of generic advertising, and other non-advertising elements of the marketing mix, for each of the concerned region. Moreover, the three regions have recently pooled their resources dedicated to advertising and non-advertising marketing activities, increasing the need for data that can help to improve budget reallocation in these activities among the regions. The objectives of this study are twofold. First, to provide an economic assessment of the responsiveness of fluid milk consumption to milk advertising in Ontario, Quebec, and the Maritime provinces over the last several years. Second, to broadly evaluate a possible reallocation of advertising and non-advertising marketing budget between Quebec Ontario and the Maritime region. 6

This analysis is conducted using econometric models of provincial or regional fluid milk demand in eastern Canada. The econometric results are used to simulate the impacts of provincial advertising and non-advertising marketing programs on these three milk markets. Specifically, we simulate the market impacts for a scenario where there is no generic milk advertising and one based on historical levels of advertising. Based on this simulation, an average rate of return to advertising is calculated for each region. We also simulate the impact of increasing advertising or non-advertising marketing budgets by $10,000 per quarter on consumption and producer revenues to ascertain the extent to which the resulting benefits exceed the costs in each region. Based on this simulation, a marginal rate of return to each marketing activity is calculated for each region. The following sections describe the conceptual fluid milk demand model used to evaluate advertising in the markets being analyzed, document the data collected for this analysis, discuss specific issues related to model estimation, as well as report and interpret the econometric results. Finally, the last section reports the simulation results of the provincial advertising program impacts on these three milk markets. The Model In each market, per capita fluid milk sales are assumed to be affected not only by generic advertising and non-advertising demand enhancement expenditures (e.g., promotion, nutrition education, sponsorship, public relations etc.), but also by the retail price of milk, prices of substitutes for milk, consumer income, and seasonal indicator variables. The general form for the demand equation for each market can be expressed as: Quantity = f(fluid milk price, substitute price, income, generic fluid milk advertising expenditures, generic fluid milk non-advertising demand enhancement expenditures, seasonality). Regardless of the functional form chosen for estimation, economic theory provides a 7

basis for expectations as to the signs of the price and income variables. With fluid milk quantity as the dependent variable, the estimated coefficient for fluid milk price should have a negative sign. In other words, the expected consumer response to an increase in the price of milk is lower consumption. When the price of a substitute for milk rises, making milk a relatively better buy, the effect should be to increase milk consumption. Thus, the estimated coefficient for any substitute price is expected to be positive. The estimated coefficient for income is expected to have a positive sign. When income rises, consumers can be expected to purchase more milk, as well as more of most goods. If milk advertising is effective, an increase in milk advertising should be associated with greater milk consumption; thus estimated generic milk advertising coefficients should have positive signs when advertising is working as intended. Likewise, expenditures on non-advertising demand enhancing activities are expected to have a positive impact on milk consumption. The seasonal (quarterly) indicator variables will have a negative sign if milk consumption is lower in that particular quarter relative to the fourth quarter consumption, and a positive sign if milk consumption is higher in that particular quarter. Data To estimate the model described above, one needs to obtain data for each of the respective regions over time. This approach allows one to capture the average relationship between quantity of fluid milk demanded and the various factors of demand. For our study, we gathered quarterly quantity, price, income, population, advertising and non-advertising marketing expenditure data. These data covered the period 1990 to 2004 for Ontario and Quebec, and 1992 to 2004 (quarter three) for the Maritime Provinces. Three sources of data were employed. Quantity data were gathered from both the Canadian Dairy Commission and Statistics Canada. Price, income, and population information were gathered from Statistics Canada and Ellen Goddard. For Quebec, the advertising and promotion expenditure data were gathered directly 8

from the Fédération des producteurs de lait du Québec. The Maritime region data used were gathered from Milk Maritimes, Dairy Farmers of Canada and Ellen Goddard s data set. Advertising and promotion expenditure data for Ontario were gathered from the Dairy Farmers of Ontario and Michael Pearce, consultant to the Dairy Farmer s of Ontario. Specific data sources and manipulations are included in Appendix 1. All of the data used in the econometric models are listed in Appendix III of this report. By way of introduction, Figures 1 through 12 provide a graphical illustration of the key variables in the respective region s demand models (note that these data are plotted in nominal terms no adjustment has been made for inflation). Figure 1 shows quarterly per capita fluid milk sales across the three regions from 1990 to 2004. 1 Three points emerge from this figure: 1) the Maritime region has slightly higher per capita fluid milk sales than Ontario and Quebec, 2) fluid milk sales exhibit strong seasonality, with peak (per capita) sales occurring in quarters 1 and 4 (i.e., the fall and winter) and low sales seasons occurring in quarters 2 and 3 (i.e., spring and summer), 3) per capita fluid milk sales show a declining trend in all three regions, but especially in Ontario and Quebec. Figure 2 further reinforces the first point, illustrating that per capita fluid milks sales have been higher (on average over the sample period 1990 to 2004) in the Maritime region than in Ontario and Quebec. Figure 3 plots the quarterly values of the fluid milk consumer price indices used in this study. These series represent the price the consumer pays at the retail level, but in reference to the price paid at a specific point in time (in this case, the price indices are normalized to equal 1 Due to data limitations, the Maritime region model only includes data from 1992 quarter 4 to 2004 quarter 3. Per capita fluid milk consumption for the Maritime region is based on per capita consumption in Nova Scotia, Prince Edward Island, and New Brunswick. These data do not control for the influx of tourists in the summer time, however, the seasonal pattern in the Maritime region per capita consumption looks similar to that in Quebec and Ontario. 9

Per capita fluid milk sales (litres) 26 25 24 23 22 21 20 19 18 1990 1990 1991 1992 1993 1993 1994 1995 1996 1996 1997 1998 Year/quarter 1999 1999 2000 2001 2002 2002 2003 2004 Maritime Quebec Ontario Figure 1. Per capita fluid milk sales (in litres) in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario, 1990 to 2004. Per capita fluid milk sales (litres) 26 25 24 23 22 21 20 19 24.01 22.53 22.38 Maritime Quebec Ontario Figure 2. Average per capita fluid milk sales (in litres) in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario over 1990 to 2004. 10

130 125 120 Price Index 115 110 105 100 95 90 1990 1990 1991 1992 1993 1993 1994 1995 1996 1996 1997 1998 1999 1999 2000 2001 2002 2002 2003 2004 Year/quarter Maritime Quebec (1992=100) Ontario (1992=100) Figure 3. Consumer price index for fluid milk in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario, 1990 to 2004. Price Index 110 109 108 107 106 105 104 103 102 101 100 108.48 108.24 106.28 Maritime Quebec (1992=100) Ontario (1992=100) Figure 4. Average consumer price index for fluid milk in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario over 1990 to 2004. 11

Dollars per capita 27000 25000 23000 21000 19000 17000 15000 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Year/quarter Maritime Quebec Ontario 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Figure 5. Per capita disposable income in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario, 1990 to 2004. $22,000 Dollars per capita $20,000 $18,000 $16,000 $14,000 $17,722 $17,928 $21,121 $12,000 Maritimes Quebec Ontario Figure 6. Average per capita disposable income in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario over 1990 to 2004. 12

Dollars per '000 people 1000 800 600 400 200 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Year Maritime Quebec Ontario 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Figure 7. Per capita generic advertising expenditure in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario, 1990 to 2004. $700 Dollars per '000 people $600 $500 $400 $300 $200 $100 $471 $536 $643 $0 Maritime Quebec Ontario Figure 8. Average per capita generic advertising expenditure in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario over 1990 to 2004. 13

500 Dollars per '000 people 400 300 200 100 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Year Maritime Quebec Ontario Figure 9. Per capita non-advertising marketing expenditure in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario, 1990 to 2004. $350 Dollars per '000 people $300 $250 $200 $150 $100 $50 $304 $296 $260 $0 Maritime Quebec Ontario Figure 10. Average per capita non-advertising marketing expenditure in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario over 1990 to 2004. 14

Dollars per '000 people 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Year 1998 1999 Maritime Quebec Ontario 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Figure 11. Per capita marketing expenditure in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario, 1990 to 2004. Dollars per '000 people $1,000 $900 $800 $700 $600 $500 $400 $300 $200 $100 $0 $260 $296 $304 $643 $536 $471 Atlantic Quebec Ontario Figure 12. Average per capita marketing expenditure in the Maritime region, Quebec and Ontario over 1990 to 2004. Estimation 100 for the calendar year 1992). The price index in all three regions trends upwards and all appear to follow a similar trend. As shown in Figure 4, however, the average value of the fluid 15

milk price index series is higher in the Maritime region and Quebec than in Ontario. Figure 5 shows the quarterly values of per capita disposable income in all three regions. As evident, per capita disposable income trends upwards over time. However, as Figure 6 illustrates, the average value of per capita disposable income is higher in Ontario than in Quebec and the Maritime region, with the latter two being on par with each other. Expenditure on generic advertising media and production activities (stated in dollars per thousand people) are plotted on an annual basis in Figure 7. This figure uses annual observations to eliminate the wide seasonal variation in these series that make it difficult to view the data in a meaningful way. Per capita generic advertising expenditure trends upwards in the Maritime region and Quebec during this time period. In Ontario, this series initially increases over time, falls in the mid to late 1990s, only to follow the same (upward) trend as Quebec from 1998 onwards. Figure 8 illustrates that, on average, Ontario has spent more per thousand people than Quebec and the Maritime region during the sample period. Figure 9 plots per capita expenditure on non-advertising marketing activities (which includes promotion and sponsorship, nutrition communication and education, public relations and, in the case of Ontario, spending on the milk calendar and ingredient communications). While not shown, considerable seasonality is evident in these series. Nevertheless, it should be clear from Figure 9 that Ontario s per capita spending on non-advertising marketing activities has increased over the sample period. It should be noted that spending items that are classified as public relations in Ontario are classified as non-advertising marketing (i.e. promotion and sponsorship) in Quebec and the Maritime region, thus these items were already accounted for. Note that for both Quebec and the Maritime region, per capita expenditure on non-advertising marketing activities increased into the mid to late 1990s, but generally declined from the late 1990s onward. Nevertheless, Figure 10 shows that on average, per capita non-advertising 16

expenditure in each region are close to each other, with the Maritime region having the highest average per capita non-advertising expenditure, followed by Quebec and then Ontario. Figure 11 plots total marketing expenditure (i.e., advertising and non-advertising expenditure) over time and in each region. In general terms, annual per capita marketing expenditure has increased in all three regions. Recall, however, that these data are provided in nominal terms, so these expenditures do not reflect the impact of media cost inflation. Lastly, Figure 12 shows average (from 1990 to 2004) per capita expenditure on advertising and nonadvertising marketing activities in all three regions. Ontario has the highest per capita marketing spend ($903per thousand people), followed by Quebec ($832) and the Maritime region ($775). Note than differences in per capita advertising spending drive most of the differences in the regional marketing expenditure values. Each of the three regions is distinctively different in terms of their culture and demographic characteristics. Therefore, it is likely that milk consuming behavior in these three markets is different as well. Consequently, rather than estimating one fluid milk demand model based on data from all three regions, we felt it would be more useful and appropriate to estimate three separate demand models for each region. Initially, the following model was specified and estimated for each region: (1) ln SALES t = α 0 + α 1 ln (PRICE t ) + α 2 ln INCOME t + α 3 ln SUBPRICE n 3 + α 4 ln NON-MILKAD+ Σ ω j ln MILKAD t-j + Σ δ k DUMQ k,t, j=0 k=1 where SALES t is quarterly per capita fluid milk sales, PRICE t is the quarterly retail fluid milk price index, SUBPRICE t is the quarterly substitute price index (several products were tried including coffee, fruit juices, and nonalcoholic beverages), INCOME t is quarterly per capita disposable income, NON-MILKAD is expenditures on generic promotion, nutritional education 17

activities, sponsorship, public relations etc, MILKAD t is a generic milk advertising expenditures in the current and previous quarters, and DUMQ k,t represents quarterly dummy variables for the first, second, and third quarter of the year. Quarterly data from 1990 through 2004 are used to estimate the coefficients in equation (1). The model was estimated using ordinary-stage least squares. All monetary variables are deflated by consumer price indices to remove the impact of inflation (see the data appendix). Generic fluid milk advertising was deflated by the media cost index rather than by a retail consumer price index since media inflation is significantly higher than the general consumer price index. A media cost index developed by Kaiser and Schmit (2004), based on media advertising for fluid milk in the United States, was used as a proxy for media inflation costs in eastern Canada. In initial estimation of this model, various age demographic variables were included since changes in the age composition of these regions was thought to influence changes in per capita milk consumption. However, none of these variables were statistically significant, and hence omitted from the final estimated models. One reason why these variables were not significant may be due to the relative high degree of aggregation in them. For instance, the youngest age cohort was between 0 and 19 years of age, which is very broad, and there is evidence that children begin to reduce their consumption of milk well before 19 years of age. One advantage of the double-log form is that it provides coefficient estimates that are direct estimates of elasticities. An estimated elasticity is a measure of the percentage change in the dependent variable, sales in this case, resulting from a one percent change in an independent variable, all else held constant. In the equation specified above, α 1 is the own price elasticity (the elasticity of milk sales with respect to the milk price), α 2 is the income elasticity (the elasticity of milk sales with respect to income), α 3 is the cross price elasticity of fluid milk demand with respect to substitute price, α 4 is the non-advertising marketing activity elasticity, 18

and ω j is the generic milk advertising elasticity. While this was the initial specification used for each region, the final specification differs for each market in terms of which variables were included in the model. In addition, the dynamic effects of advertising were modeled differently for each province. For example, for the Maritime region, only current advertising was included in the final specification. For Quebec, current and lagged advertising was included in the final specification. Lagged advertising captures any carry-over effect that advertising might have. Finally, in Ontario, lagged, but not current advertising was included in the model. Also, the non-advertising marketing variable (NON-MILKAD) was lagged in Ontario as well. These differences imply that the dynamic effects of advertising in each market are different, which may be related to the advertising campaign in each market as well as regional differences in population s reaction to advertising and promotion. 19

Results The detailed estimation results for each province are presented in Appendix II of this report. However, the elasticity estimates of important economic variables are reported in Table 1. 2 The estimated price elasticities were highly statistically significant and negative for each region. The most price responsive market was Quebec, which had an estimated price elasticity of -0.258. This means that a one percent increase in the real (inflation-adjusted) retail fluid milk price would lead to a 0.258 percent decrease in per capita milk demand in Quebec, holding all other demand factors constant. The lowest price elasticity was found in the Maritime region (-0.080) and Ontario was in the middle (-0.145). These results suggest that milk consumers in the Maritime region are the least sensitive to changes in price of all three regions, and consumers in Quebec are the most sensitive to price changes. Table 1. Selected elasticities, evaluated at sample means, for the three provinces. Variable Ontario Maritime Quebec Price -0.145* -0.080* -0.258* Income 0.329* NA NA Price of substitutes** 0.145* 0.027* 0.096* Generic fluid milk advertising 0.027* 0.015* 0.060* Non-advertising marketing elements*** 0.014 0.008* 0.041* * Statistically significant from zero at the 10 percent level or less. ** Price of substitutes in Ontario is representative by the retail price index for fruit juices, while the retail price index for coffee is the substitute price used in the Maritime region and Quebec. *** Nutrition communication, promotion, sponsorship, public relations and ingredient/calendar expenditure was aggregated into one variable. 2 It should be noted that a time trend was also included in the Ontario model, and an intercept dummy variable was included in the Quebec model. See Appendix II for details of the estimation results. 20

Income was positive and statistically significant in the Ontario market, but was highly insignificant (and hence deleted) in the other two markets. In Ontario, a one percent increase in real (inflation-adjusted) per capita income leads to a 0.329 percent increase in per capita demand, holding all other factors constant. The income elasticity was about twice as high in magnitude as the price elasticity in this market. On the other hand, the fact that income was not significantly different from zero in both the Maritime region and Quebec suggest that milk is more of a staple good in these markets. The price of substitutes was statistically significant in all three regions. In Quebec, the cross-price elasticity of fluid milk demand with respect to the price of coffee was 0.096, i.e., a one percent increase in the retail price index for coffee results in a 0.096 percent increase in per capita demand for fluid milk products, holding all other demand factors constant. In the Maritime region, this elasticity was estimated to be 0.027, which is much smaller in magnitude. Thus, while different from zero, it appears that coffee prices have only a marginal impact on fluid milk demand in the Maritime region. 3 A one percent increase in the retail price for fruit juices in Ontario resulted in a 0.145 percent increase in per capita fluid milk consumption holding all other demand factors constant. Similar to the Maritime region and Quebec, the retail price of substitutes in Ontario appear to only have a marginal effect on fluid milk demand. Generic fluid milk advertising in all three markets had a positive and statistically significant impact on per capita consumption. Quebec had the highest advertising elasticity equal to 0.060, i.e., a one percent increase in advertising results in a 0.060 percent increase in per capita demand. The Maritime region had the lowest advertising elasticity of 0.014 followed by Ontario at 0.027. A statistical test was conducted to determine whether these advertising 3 The retail price index for tea was also included for the Maritime region, but it was statistically insignificant from zero and hence omitted in the final model. 21

elasticities were statistically different from each other. The results indicated that they were statistically different in each market. These advertising elasticity values are similar to those estimated in previous studies for fluid milk. For example, Kaiser and Schmit (2004) estimated a value of 0.037 for generic fluid milk advertising in the United States, which is just about the average of the ones computed for the three Canadian regions. The elasticity for the non-advertising marketing activities was also measured. In the model, all non-advertising marketing activities were aggregated into one variable. For Ontario, total expenditures on the ingredient/calendar, nutrition communication, promotion sponsorship and public relation activities were not found to have a statistically significant effect on demand for fluid milk. However, the dynamics of investment in this aggregate marketing activity are long, ranging between three and six quarters back. In the Maritime region, the non-advertising marketing activities had a positive and marginally statistically significant impact on per capita milk demand. A one percent increase in expenditures on these activities was found to increase per capita milk demand by 0.008 percent holding all other demand factors constant. In Quebec, the combination of these activities had an elasticity value of 0.041, which was statistically significant. Simulation In the previous section, the econometric models for Ontario, the Maritime region and Quebec were presented. Such models allow one to isolate the impact of generic promotion and advertising on the demand for fluid milk. Although such information is quite important, what matters most for dairy farmers is the return on their investment. Is putting more dollars in generic advertising or non-advertising elements a good investment for dairy farmers? To answer this question, the demand equations generated using econometric tools are used to simulate the demand impact of an increase in generic advertising or promotion for a 22

certain period of time. From these simulations, an average and marginal rate of return can be computed. In short, the average producer rate of return (APROR) measures the producer return to total investment in generic advertising, while the marginal producer ate of return (MPROR) measures the producer return to incremental investment in generic advertising. As expected, the econometric results show that an increase in advertising and promotion stimulates the demand for fluid milk. The resulting shift in demand creates a new equilibrium price and quantity; i.e., the point where the new demand equal the supply. To find these new equilibrium points, the supply elasticity is usually needed. However, in Canada, supply management affects the supply response differently. When quota is binding, which is the case in Canada, the supply curve is vertical at the quantity fixed by the quota. Therefore, the supply response needs to be treated differently in order to find the appropriate new price and new quantity. In Canada, it appears that price and quantity are not linked in the short run. Shifts in demand are monitored by using butter stocks. If the demand for dairy products is greater than farm milk supply, the stock of butter decreases and production quota can be increased. The opposite is true when supply is greater than demand. These quantity adjustments are made without any price adjustment. Similarly, when the farm milk price is increased, based on cost of production calculation, there is no quantity adjustment made in the short run. Thus, the following assumption will be made when computing the ROR on an increase in advertising and promotion expenditure: An increase in demand will result in an increase in supply without any effect on price in the short run. Figure 13 illustrates our assumption. 23

S1 S2 Ps a b D2 D1 Figure 13. Illustration of the impact of an increase in fluid milk demand following and increase in generic promotion. Following an increase in advertising or promotion expenditure that stimulates demand, the quantity sold moves from point a to point b. Thus, the shift in demand from D1 to D2 is met by a shift in supply, from S1 to S2. The net result is only a change in quantity from a to b at the initial price Ps. Rate of Return Simulations Both average and marginal rates of return were computed for each region. The average rate of return to advertising was calculated on the basis of simulating two scenarios over the period 2000-2004: (1) baseline simulation of demand based on historical levels of advertising, and (2) a no-advertising scenario, where advertising expenditures were set to zero over the same time period. 4 The total benefits of advertising were captured by multiplying the Class 1a price less the marginal cost of production (estimated by using cash cost expenses plus short term interest 24

costs and adjusted for butterfat) in the appropriate region for a specific quarter, by the increase in fluid milk quantity demand due generic advertising. 5 The total benefits obtained were then divided by total advertising costs to which ten percent was added to take into account other costs such as administrative costs related to generic advertising. The MPROR for both advertising and promotion was calculated on the basis of running additional scenarios based on adding $10,000 per quarter to either advertising or promotion over the period 2000-2004. Similar to the APROR, the MPROR was computed by multiplying the Class 1a price less the marginal cost of production and adjusting for butterfat in the appropriate region for a specific quarter, by the increase in fluid milk demand due to the increase in advertising or non advertising marketing expenditures and then divided by 10,000. The quantity of fluid milk consumed was computed using the estimated demand function and is relative to the baseline, which is the situation before the increase in advertising or promotion spending. Because the results are compared from a base, which already includes advertising and promotion spending, the results is interpreted as marginal effect. For the MPROR calculation, it is important to note that the nominal increase in advertising or promotion spending was applied uniformly in each quarter, while advertising and promotion spending are usually not uniformly distributed across quarters. It should also be noted that a $10,000 per quarter increase in spending is more important in the Maritime region than in Quebec and Ontario in relative terms, given the smaller advertising and promotion budget of this region. 4 The level of advertising was actually not zero, but set at one percent of spending level for each quarters because the logarithm of zero is not defined. 5 The average fluid milk butterfat content is used in each region and compared with average raw milk butterfat, it is assumed that the extra butterfat is used in class 4. 25

Rate of Return Results Table 2 shows the APROR for advertising results for the three regions, averaged over all quarters between 2000 and 2004. The average rate of return was greater than one in each region and was the highest in Quebec at 7.35, followed by Ontario at 3.39 and the Maritime region at 2.23. The average rate of return means that each dollar invested in generic advertising has generated $7.35, $3.39 and $2.23 in net returns to dairy farmers in Quebec, Ontario and the Maritime region, respectively. These results suggest that dairy farmers are benefiting from generic milk advertising in each region studied. Table 2. Average rate of return of generic advertising for the period 2000-2004, by regions. Region APROR Maritimes 2.23 Ontario 3.39 Quebec 7.35 Source: authors calculations The producer marginal rates of return averaged over 20 quarters (2000-1 to 2004-4) are presented in Table 3 (the quarterly MPROR are presented in appendix IV). A large MPROR implies that extra money in advertising or promotion would generate a large return for the incremental investment. Therefore, a MPROR greater than one, could be interpreted as underspending, while a MPROR less than one as over-spending. The impact of increasing advertising spending (by $10,000 per quarter) is the greatest in Quebec, with a marginal producer rate of return of 5.04, followed by Ontario and the Maritime region with marginal producer rate of returns of 1.05 and 0.67, respectively. This implies that increasing advertising by $10,000 per quarter would result in an average increase in farm 26

revenues of $50,400, $10,500, and $6,700 per quarter in Quebec, Ontario, and the Maritime region, respectively over this period. Table 3. Average marginal producer rate of return of increasing generic advertising or promotion by $10,000 per quarter, for the period 2000-2004, by simulation. Simulations MPOR Maritime region, generic advertising 0.67 Maritime region, promotion 1.05 Quebec, generic advertising 5.04 Quebec, promotion 3.95 Ontario, generic advertising 1.05 Ontario, promotion 1.02 Source: authors calculations As for the impact of increasing expenditure on the non-advertising marketing elements, the impact is the greatest in Quebec, with a producer marginal rate of return of 3.95, followed by the Maritime region and Ontario with producer marginal rate of returns of 1.05 and 1.02, respectively. The latter number should be interpreted with caution because Ontario elasticity coefficient for non-advertising marketing elements is not significant. It is interesting to note that Ontario s marginal rate of return for advertising is slightly above 1.0, meaning that advertising in that region is close to optimal. Increasing advertising would generate benefits that are larger than the costs of the additional spending in Quebec. On the other hand, increasing generic advertising in the Maritime region would generate less net revenues than the cost of the investment. In all regions, but the Maritime region, an incremental increase in advertising spending of $10,000 per quarter generates a better return than in nonadvertising marketing elements. From an optimal point of view, Quebec should devote the major part of future budget increases to advertising. Among the three regions, Quebec would clearly benefit the most from an increase in both advertising and promotion. Results indicate that Ontario s spending on 27

advertising and non-advertising marketing elements, as well as the Maritime region spending in non-advertising marketing elements are near optimal, their marginal producer rate of return (MPROR) being close to one. On the other hand, MPRORs indicate that the Maritime region has over-spent on advertising. Considering that the three regions have pooled their advertising and promotion budget, these results suggest that advertising and non-advertising spending should increased in Quebec and maintained in real terms in Ontario, while non-advertising marketing elements should be maintained in real terms in the Maritime region and advertising reduced in real term. Figure 14 illustrates the relationship between advertising spending and marginal rate of return on advertising, using 2000-2004 Quebec data. As previously mention, a decrease in advertising spending is likely to result in an increase in the MPROR, as illustrated for the period 2002-2004 in Figure 14. MROR Spending ROR 9.00 8.00 7.00 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Years 700 680 660 640 620 600 580 560 540 520 500 Spending Figure 14. Comparison of per capita annual generic advertising expenses and MPROR, Quebec, 2000-2004. 28

This inverse relationship helps to understand the large differences between Quebec s MPROR for advertising and Ontario s and the Maritime region MPROR. Other possible reasons are: The fact that the advertising elasticity is higher in Quebec than elsewhere, which may be due to the campaigns in Quebec being more successful or efficient; Despite the fact that Ontario spends more per capita than the Maritime region and Quebec, they also have a larger market to reach. Since the cost of reaching 2 million people is not twice the cost of reaching 1 million, total spending should also be considered as an important indicator; Dilution and saturation effects, consumers in Ontario and the Maritime region watch and read a lot of American materials (choices are numerous); while in Quebec for numerous consumers Quebec media would be the major source of information. Therefore, a dollar spend in Quebec advertising is likely to reach more people and to be more efficient. The MPROR estimated above are not out of range when compared to those for other promotion checkoff programs. A list of estimated marginal benefit-cost ratios for selected food commodities can be found in appendix V. Numerous other measures of the impact of generic advertising on dairy farmers revenues can be done. Our analysis has concentrated on the important measures, the APROR as well as the MPROR. Further measures can be explored, such as the average rate of return (AROR), which is similar to the APROR with the difference that the marginal cost of producing the extra milk and the butterfat adjustment are not taken into account. The net average producer rate of return (NAPROR) can also be used. The NAPROR is simply the APROR from which advertising is netted out of the additional profit generated. Mathematically this can be simplified as NAPROR = APROR 1. Another possible measure is the discounted average producer rate of return (DAPROR). DAPROR measures the additional producer profits generated by generic advertising, but discounted to present value to account for the time value of money. This measure is increasingly recognized as the most appropriate measure of the return of generic 29