PCR Stakeholder Forum Brussels, January 11 th 2016

Similar documents
EUPHEMIA Public Description PCR Market Coupling Algorithm

FB external report for w1, 2017

Revisiting minimum profit conditions in uniform price day-ahead electricity auctions

How the European day-ahead electricity market works

Proposal for a common set of requirements for the DA price coupling algorithm

Principles of Flowbased Market Coupling

MARI: Algorithm Design Principles CLARIFYING QUESTIONS October 10, 2018

I-SEM Trialing of EUPHEMIA: Initial Phase Results Overview. I-SEM EUPHEMIA Working Group 16 th April 2015

Electricity Market Design : Experience from the Nordic electricity market NORDPOOL

17/02/2017 Implementation of CACM Guideline

TERRE project. Elastic need, social welfare and counter-activations

Status CWE Flow-Based Project

Consumer flash estimates

Counter activations in PICASSO. Overview of the options and their implications

Explanatory document to the proposal for the establishment of fallback procedures for Capacity Calculation Region Hansa in accordance with Article 44

Lecture 5: Minimum Cost Flows. Flows in a network may incur a cost, such as time, fuel and operating fee, on each link or node.

Network Flows. 7. Multicommodity Flows Problems. Fall 2010 Instructor: Dr. Masoud Yaghini

Design options of TERRE Project. (Trans European Replacement Reserves Exchange) Executive Summary

All NEMOs proposal for the price coupling algorithm and for the continuous trading matching algorithm, also incorporating TSO and NEMO proposals for

Paid-as-cleared for R2 & R3 activated energy

exchange of balancing energy from Replacement Reserves in accordance with establishing a guideline on electricity balancing 18 th of June

532 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 2, MAY 2008

Inefficiencies in Zonal Market Coupling due to Uncertainties in Generation Shift Keys

Price Formation Education Session Day 1 Economic Dispatch

Electricity Market Integration in SEE from TSOs perspective

ORGANIZED power exchanges have arisen to reduce the

Energy Storage Report: Applications and market potential for energy storage in Italy

Energy Imbalance Market Year 1 Enhancements

Nordic FB Stakeholder Group meeting. April 15 Stockholm Arlanda airport

What can transmission do for a renewable Europe?

Better Markets, Better Products, Better Prices

PowrSym4. A Presentation by. Operation Simulation Associates, Inc. February, 2012

Modeling competitive equilibrium prices in exchange-based electricity markets

Refinement to Comparison between sequential selection and co-optimization between energy and ancillary service markets

Generational and steady state genetic algorithms for generator maintenance scheduling problems

Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP): Basics of Nodal Price Calculation

NEMO Committee Justification document on the consideration of stakeholder views on the All NEMOs Consultation Proposals on CACM Article 9

Analyses on the effects of implementing implicit grid losses in the Nordic CCR

Traffic noise and motorway pavements

Book of Proceedings 3 RD INTERNATIONAL SYMPOSIUM & 25 TH NATIONAL CONFERENCE ON OPERATIONAL RESEARCH ISBN:

Branch and Bound Method

INTERVAL ANALYSIS TO ADDRESS UNCERTAINTY IN MULTICRITERIA ENERGY MARKET CLEARANCE

Reinforcement learning for microgrid management

Using price sensitivity analysis with the supply models to parameterize the market model

A Mathematical Model for Driver Balance in Truckload Relay Networks

All NEMOs proposal for the price coupling algorithm and for the continuous trading matching algorithm, also incorporating TSO and NEMO proposals for

Outcomes TYNDP Visions - Request for Stakeholder Input Period 3 December January 2013

Solutions for Power Generation

ISyE 3133B Sample Final Tests

FONASBA Annual Meeting 2010

LMP Calculation and Uplift

Evaluation of the National Renewable Energy Action Plans

Flexible power generation and interconnection capacity needs of the Italian power system using PLEXOS LT plan.

2 TERRE TSO-TSO Model

Response ELECTRICITY MARKET DESIGN AND THE GREEN AGENDA

NordREG hearing on TSO s & DSO s roles for enabling energy services

Optimal Multi-scale Capacity Planning under Hourly Varying Electricity Prices

Exact solutions to binary equilibrium problems with compensation and the power market uplift problem

Regulating Power Market (RPM) Review Study

Energy Norway response to the ERGEG consultation on the Framework guidelines on Capacity Calculation and Congestion Management for Electricity

Applying Robust Optimization to MISO Look-ahead Unit Commitment

XXXII. ROBUST TRUCKLOAD RELAY NETWORK DESIGN UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY

Innovative grid-impacting technologies for pan-european system analyses: key GridTech results on Demand Response application

ENTSO-E scenarios- general overview. Daniel Huertas Hernando ENTSO-E System Planning Adviser

Developments on Waste to Energy across Europe

Aquifer Thermal Energy Storage (ATES) Smart Grids

Optimization of energy supply systems by MILP branch and bound method in consideration of hierarchical relationship between design and operation

Power System Economics and Market Modeling

Toronto Data Science Forum. Wednesday May 2 nd, 2018

A Convex Primal Formulation for Convex Hull Pricing

Pricing Enhancements Issue Paper and Straw Proposal

Price Formation Education 4: Shortage Pricing and Operating Reserve Demand Curve

Workshop on developed country targets. Bangkok, 3 April EU contribution

Modeling of Electricity Markets and Hydropower Dispatch Task 4.2: Global observatory of electricity resources

Price Formation. Eric Ciccoretti Attorney-Advisor Office of Energy Policy and Innovation Federal Energy Regulatory Commission June 13, 2017

Investor & Analyst Presentation

Optimizing Day-Ahead Electricity Market Prices: Increasing the Total Surplus for Energy Exchange Istanbul

Metaheuristics for scheduling production in large-scale open-pit mines accounting for metal uncertainty - Tabu search as an example.

Chapter 2 Integer Programming. Paragraph 3 Advanced Methods

Expressing Preferences with Price-Vector Agents in Combinatorial Auctions: A Brief Summary

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL

Production Planning under Uncertainty with Multiple Customer Classes

How the Waste-to-Energy industry contributes to Energy Efficiency across Europe

Multiagent Systems: Spring 2006

CACM: an industry view on challenges and benefits. Helene Robaye Head of Regulation & Market Design ENGIE Global Energy Management

Wind Energy The Facts

Adding value to IRENA s REmap 2030 project using a European Electricity Model

Degrees of Coordination in Market Coupling and Counter-Trading

Welcome to the Webinar. A Deep Dive into Advanced Analytics Model Review and Validation

Vehicle Routing Tank Sizing Optimization under Uncertainty: MINLP Model and Branch-and-Refine Algorithm

NZEB IN EUROPE Different speeds on the road to an energy efficient building stock. Maarten De Groote Buildings Performance Institute Europe

Strategy Analysis. Chapter Study Group Learning Materials

Core projects and scientific studies as background for the NREAPs. 9th Inter-Parliamentary Meeting on Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency

Hydropower as Flexibility Provider: Modeling Approaches and Numerical Analysis

CREG PROPOSAL FOR THE ADAPTATION OF THE CBCO SELECTION METHOD AND THE BASE CASE DEFINITION IN THE CWE FLOW BASED MARKET COUPLING

Social Welfare Report / 2012

CHAPTER 5 SOCIAL WELFARE MAXIMIZATION FOR HYBRID MARKET

^ Springer. The Logic of Logistics. Theory, Algorithms, and Applications. for Logistics Management. David Simchi-Levi Xin Chen Julien Bramel

National-strategic transmission investment and zonal pricing

Utilizing Optimization Techniques to Enhance Cost and Schedule Risk Analysis

Transcription:

PCR Stakeholder Forum Brussels, January 11 th 2016

PCR Stakeholder Forum January 11, 2016

Agenda Complexity of the problem Size of the problem; Non-convexities and optimality gap; Heuristics in Euphemia; PRBs Performance indicators Next development steps for the Euphemia algorithm

Introduction From ESC meetings 2015 Concerns expressed by stakeholders: Quality of the solution PRBs Link with solution quality Transparency Heuristics Indicators

1. Complexity of the problem

MRC NO5 NO4 2015 SE1 FRE ERI 53 bidding areas 67 lines Functionalities hourly step and interpolated orders regular block orders Profile block orders Linked block orders Exclusive block orders Flexible block orders Curtailable block orders MIC orders Load gradients Scheduled stops PUN orders Merit orders Flow based intuitive The problem is solved globally : NO3 NO2 NO1 SE3 GB2 GB1 PT For all bidding areas, prices are calculated during the same computation NO1A DK1A DK1 NL BE FR ES MO FB DK2 DE FRAN COAC PRGP SE2 SE4 PL SVIZ CORS SARD MALT SICI FI LRI LBE AUST NORD CNOR CSUD SUD ROSN EE LV LT LRE LBI BSP SLOV MFTV FOGN BRNN GREC Public Documentation on Euphemia is available for download : https://www.epexspot.com/en/market-coupling/pcr

Block orders and complex orders A block is defined as a set of quantities, a single price, and optionally a minimum acceptance ratio In a complex order, the hourly orders must be rejected if out-of-the-money and accepted if in-themoney the accepted ratio can vary from one period to the other The variable term (VT) has a block effect You can recover a fixed cost (FT) A block can lose money on some periods, as long as overall the block is not PAB must have the same accepted ratio on all periods A fixed cost can be implicitly integrated (as you know the minimum quantity that can be accepted) 7

5000 4500 4000 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 MRC Orderbook Growth Block and Complex Orders MRC - Daily Number of Block Orders Nb Regular Blocks Nb Exclusive Blocks max 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2011 2015 Nb Linked Blocks Nb Flexible Blocks #daily MRC Blocks : x 2.08 (+1664 block orders) Max (#daily MRC Blocks) : x 2.12 (+2462 block orders). #Complex orders stable 5000 4500 4000 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 On MRC, the number of block orders has doubled between 2011 and 2015 0 MRC - Daily Number of Complex Orders Nb Complex Orders max 80 76 84 80 78 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

MRC Orderbook Growth Merit/PUN orders 2011 2015 #Merit orders : x 1.4 #PUN steps cagr: 81% MRC - Number of PUN/Merit Orders* PUN steps/hour* 45000 100.00 40000 35000 30000 25000 80.00 60.00 Avg Max 20000 15000 40.00 10000 5000 20.00 0 Avg.2011 Max 2011 Avg.2015 Max 2015 0.00 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 * Period 25/02/201X 09/07/201X

What makes it difficult to prove optimality in the current setting? The combinatorial nature of block and smart orders All non-convex requirements Strict linear pricing, no Paradoxically Accepted Block The price intuitiveness requirement The PUN requirement The Minimum Income Condition Taken separately, these requirements are relatively easy. Complexity comes from the combination. 10

Geometric intuition Welfare increase direction Set of points with same welfare Best valid solution Valid solutions for Euphemia 11

Definitions Welfare increase direction Set of points with same welfare Integer blocks and MICs selections (no block accepted below its minimum acceptance ratio) 12

Definitions Space defined by convex (easy) constraints (clearing, export, ) Welfare increase direction Set of points with same welfare Integer block and MIC selections (no block accepted below its minimum acceptance ratio) 13

Definitions Space defined by convex (easy) constraints (clearing, export, ) Welfare increase direction Set of points with same welfare Integer blocks and MICs selections (no block accepted below its minimum acceptance ratio) Space defined by convex and non-convex (difficult) constraints (no PABs, MIC, PUN, ) 14

Gap = upper bound - lower bound Initial upper bound = Best welfare when satisfying the convex constraints only Welfare 0 GAP Initial lower bound = 0 15

Best achievable solution Best welfare when satisfying the convex constraints only Welfare The best achievable solution of the true problem is unknown Initially 0 16

Finding a valid solution is not easy Best welfare when satisfying the convex constraints only Welfare 2 GAP 1 Initially 0 Each branching defines 2 new sub-problems (accept/reject a block) 17

Decreasing the gap is not easy either Best welfare when satisfying the convex constraints only Welfare GAP 4 5 Best feasible solution found 3 Initially 0 18

The gap is 0 when the optimal solution is reached Best welfare when satisfying the convex constraints only Welfare Two successive block cuts 6 7 GAP = 0 Initially 0 19

Summary: the search tree Welfare Upper bounds 0 2 5 6 7 Non integer solution to the convex problem Lower bounds 3 Infeasible problem Integer solution to the convex problem Euphemia valid solution 20

In practice 1. Euphemia is limited by time A real search tree has billions of nodes! 2. Euphemia has to find at least 1 valid solution Hence we have implemented various heuristics 3. But because of non-convex constraints, we overestimate the gap The optimal solutions in the convex space give upper bounds on the welfare 21

Euphemia s PUN search is heuristic Because we decompose the problem We only look for PUN after we have found a solution for other zones Because even if GME were alone, we could miss some solutions We do not look into some intervals where probability to find a solution is very low This is required if we want to find a solution fast enough It gives us time to find other solutions Note: Euphemia s results on the GME perimeter are very similar to the UPPO algorithm used previously, and Euphemia is faster 22

Euphemia s treatment of the MIC condition is heuristic To invalidate a solution that contains paradoxically accepted MICs, we create 2 branches But we explore only one branch by lack of time The other branch is unlikely to provide better solutions The PRMICs reinsertion module compensates this 6 5 5 6 7? 7 23

Euphemia s treatment of the intuiveness requirement is heuristic In flow based mode, solutions may naturally contain flows from high price zones to low price zones: this is a non-intuitive solution Euphemia detects these situations, and adds inequalities to enforce an intuitive solution This mechanism is proved to converge and is fast However, inequalities may not be added in the optimal order 24

Why do we have PRBs? 1 In uniform pricing, it s either no PABs or no PRBs, but not both Price Hourly demand Supply block 1 Supply block 2 Quantity 25

Why do we have PRBs? 1 In uniform pricing, it s either no PABs or no PRBs, but not both 2 The branch-and-bound tree solved by Euphemia is very large A block can be PRB in the first solution found and be accepted in another better solution. It may happen that the second solution is not found within 10 minutes. 26

Maximizing the welfare is not equivalent to minimizing the number of PRBs Price Hourly demand 450@50 Solution with best welfare: Block 3 accepted, 2 PRBs 340@27 1 2 3 210@39 400@40 110@38 Quantity Solution with min number of PRBs Blocks 1 and 2 accepted, 1 PRB Minimizing PRB utility loss would be a different market design choice 27

Sequential reinsertion of the PRBs 1. Compute the list of PRBs in the solution, and sort it by decreasing δ P ( From the worst to the least PRB ) The size of the list is limited to 15 orders 2. Force the 1 st block in this list to be accepted If the welfare of the solution increased, continue to 3. Otherwise, try reinserting the next order in the list 3. Check the non-convex requirements If the prices are OK, go back to 1. Otherwise, try reinserting the next order in the list This is called local search. We apply small changes to the solution 28

How does Euphemia deal with small blocks? Is a small block more likely to become PRB? YES, because we are optimizing the welfare, so even a deep in-the-money block may get rejected The delta P rule was added for this reason Is a block submitted in a small bidding area more likely to become PRB? - NO, Euphemia does not make any distinction - In practice, it may happen because of market circumstances (price, quantities, and other ) δ P P P Q Q 29

2. Performance

Euphemia Main Releases since Go-Live Euphemia Development In order to cope with the expending perimeter and the increasing number and complexities of the products that are used, significant performance improvements have been implemented within Euphemia.* In 2014, 4 releases of Euphemia have been put in production : 05/02/2014 05/03/2014 09/04/2014 18/09/2014 31/12/2014 Euphemia 6.0 Euphemia 7.0 Euphemia 7.0b Euphemia 8.2 Initial Release of Euphemia Bug Fixes Bug Fixes Better handling of numerical difficulties In 2015 01/01/2015 22/01/2015 15/05/2015 29/10/2015 Euphemia 8.2 Euphemia 9.1 Euphemia 9.2 Euphemia 9.3 Better handling of numerical difficulties PUN Search Improvement Branching Strategy Improvement PUN Search Improvement and PRB Re-insertion

E9.3 (Nov. 2015) E9.2 (May 2015) E9.1 (Jan. 2015) E8.2 (Sept. 2014) Time to the 1 st solution: from 12 to 2 min in 1 year 60% 40% 20% Sessions (%) 10 min 20 min Median 12:03 0% 60% 40% 20% 5:10 0% 60% 40% 2:44 20% 0% 60% 40% 2:08 20% Simulation on 2014 data including GME, with flow-based model in CWE 0% 1-2 2-3 3-4 4-5 5-6 6-7 7-8 8-9 9-10 10-11 11-12 12-13 13-14 14-15 15-16 16-17 17-18 18-19 19-20 20 and over Number of analyzed sessions varies depending on the time frame. Minutes 32

All steps have been improved throughout the versions Time to solve the root node went from more than 1 min with E8.2 to 0:32 with E9.1, and 0:15 with E9.2 Ongoing work (cf. next slides) Integer solution Euphemia valid solution 1 st solution = E9.1 E9.2 E9.2 E9.4 E9.1 E9.3 Solution to the convex problem Number of nodes to find the first solution went from 49 with E9.1 to 31 with E9.2 Solution to the nonconvex problem (but PUN) Time dedicated to PUN went from 7:05 with E8.2 to 1:17 with E9.1, and 0:25 with E9.3 Start Time First solution 33

E9.3 (Nov. 2015) E9.2 (May 2015) E9.1 (Jan. 2015) E8.2 (Sept. 2014) Number of solutions found: from 1 to 3 in 1 year 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 80% Sessions (%) No solution Median 1 Simulation on 2014 data including GME, with flow-based model in CWE 60% 40% 20% 0% 80% 1 60% 40% 20% 0% 80% 60% 2 40% 20% 3 0% 0 1 2 3 4 5 and over Number of analyzed sessions varies depending on the time frame Solutions 34

A posteriori evaluation of the gap The solutions returned by Euphemia (version 9.3) are very good Based on our preliminary results, their welfare is about 17 k below the upper bound Median: 17 Upper bound on the gap, first half of 2015 Q1: 9 Q3: 29 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 k Methodology, assumptions, and further analysis in the next slides 35

3. Next development steps for the Euphemia algorithm

Next main steps to improve performance and quality of solutions Better evaluation of the gap Local search to decrease the number of PRBs Multi-threading, incl. internal measures to decrease numerical difficulties External measures to decrease numerical difficulties 37

Next main steps to improve performance and quality of solutions Better evaluation of the gap Local search to decrease the number of PRBs Multi-threading, incl. internal measures to decrease numerical difficulties External measures to decrease numerical difficulties 38

Complex orders cause the main overestimation of the gap A complex order is defined as: A set of step supply curves, one per period Optionally A MIC (minimum income condition) constraint for the complex order acceptance Income Fixed Term + Variable Term accepted quantity A Load Gradient condition, to set a maximum variation of the the accepted quantity between consecutive periods A Scheduled Stop condition, to shut down a plant smoothly if not accepted 39

How does it compare to a block order? A block is defined as a set of quantities, a single price, and optionally a minimum acceptance ratio In a complex order, the hourly orders must be rejected if out-of-the-money and accepted if in-themoney the accepted ratio can vary from one period to the other The variable term (VT) has a block effect You can recover a fixed cost (FT) A block can lose money on some periods, as long as overall the block is not PAB must have the same accepted ratio on all periods A fixed cost can be implicitly integrated (as you know the minimum quantity that can be accepted) 40

Why do complex orders cause the main overestimation of the gap (1)? To decrease the gap, we must: 2 Prove that the most promising nodes are not valid (breadth first search) 1 Find a good valid solution (Dive down in the tree) Step 2 cannot be performed efficiently! We have to evaluate (almost) all combinations of complex orders with a MIC condition (and handle the blocks, the PUN, etc.) 41

Why do complex orders cause the main overestimation of the gap (2)? The variable term makes the MIC constraint non-convex The solution of the convex problem is based on the prices of the hourly orders, which can be very different from the VT Euphemia assumes first that the order has to be accepted at the hourly steps price But the MIC constraint is not expressed in the initial relaxation of the problem; the MIC can actually request a different price This discrepancy appears in Euphemia s optimality measure 42

To mitigate these effects, we propose to early deactivate some MIC orders Early deactivation of MICs that are unlikely to be satisfied Reduces the number of nodes to explore Improves the upper bound when there is not enough time to prove that these MICs should be deactivated An assumption on market prices is made, based on past results, with a safety margin Approach: Compute tentative income and quantities of orders under these assumed market prices Deactivate MIC order if tentative income violates the MIC Gap improves significantly 43

Early deactivation of MICs reduces the gap by 2,208 k * 5,000 k 4,000 k 3,000 k Average gap: 2,313 k Mind: the primal and dual problems are not equivalent: primal only uses partial information on MIC orders, hence it overestimates the gap Given our assumptions on prices, OMIE solutions are identical in both cases and PCR but OMIE is not impacted 2,000 k 1,000 k Average gap: 105 k 0 * Preliminary testing. Historical sessions, first half of 2015 Historical sessions, first half of 2015, with early deactivation of some MIC orders 44

Limitations of early deactivation A few infeasible MIC orders with low difference between tentative costs and incomes cannot be rejected early Deciding the acceptance of these orders remains hard and limits the ability to decrease the gap Hence the proposed approach is a speedup and reduces the gap, but it does not close the gap How did we reduce the gap further? Geographical decomposition to obtain a good upper bound on the welfare 45

Motivation of the geographical decomposition If we can find 2 groups of variables such that each constraint only contains variables from one group: Z * Maximize 3x 1 + 2y 2-4x 2 + 10y 1 Subject to x 1 + 9x 2 5 3y 1 + 2y 2 15 y 2 5 x 2 0 Then the problem can be solved by decomposition Z 1 Z Maximize 2y 2 + 10y 2 1 Z * = + Subject to 3y 1 + 2y 2 15 y 2 5 Maximize 3x 1-4x 2 Subject to x 1 + 9x 2 5 x 2 0 46

Motivation of the geographical decomposition Z 1 Z Maximize 2y 2 + 10y 2 1 Z * = + Subject to 3y 1 + 2y 2 15 y 2 5 Maximize 3x 1-4x 2 Subject to x 1 + 9x 2 5 x 2 0 This is interesting if it is possible to solve very efficiently the resulting subproblems. In our case, OMIE alone is fairly easy to optimize PCR without OMIE remains challenging, but we can provably obtain solutions of good quality 47

How can we apply this idea to improve the upper bound on the welfare, and thus the gap? It is not so simple: we must find a way to decompose the problem PCR is nearly decomposable, there is only one line between OMIE and the other PXs Z 2 PCR\OMIE Z 1 OMIE The constraints regarding this line are the only ones including variables from both groups 48

A valid upper bound on PCR welfare OMIE flow up flow down PCR\OMIE The flow variables are used on both sides. 49

A valid upper bound on PCR welfare OMIE flow up flow down PCR\OMIE The flow variables are used on both sides. We decompose the problem as follows: OMIE S OMIE = D OMIE = D PCR\OMIE S PCR\OMIE PCR\OMIE S OMIE is a supply order inserted in PCR\OMIE that represents the import from OMIE. Its quantity is defined as the ATC from Spain to France, and its price is set to the average of the prices in Spain and France in a valid Euphemia solution. D PCR\OMIE, D OMIE, and S PCR\OMIE are defined in a similar way. 50

A valid upper bound on PCR welfare OMIE flow up flow down PCR\OMIE The flow variables are used on both sides. We decompose the problem as follows: OMIE S OMIE = D OMIE = D PCR\OMIE S PCR\OMIE PCR\OMIE Removing some constraints from our maximization problem can only lead to solutions with a higher welfare. 51

A valid upper bound on PCR welfare OMIE flow up flow down PCR\OMIE The flow variables are used on both sides. We decompose the problem as follows: OMIE S OMIE = D OMIE = D PCR\OMIE S PCR\OMIE PCR\OMIE Removing some constraints from our maximization problem can only lead to solutions with a higher welfare. Hence we obtain a valid upper bound: Welfare * OMIE D PCR\OMIE S PCR\OMIE France + Spain S OMIE D OMIE PCR\OMIE Welfare 1 Welfare 2 52

Conclusion of the gap evaluation The solutions returned by Euphemia are of high quality Based on our preliminary results, their welfare is about 17 k below the best achievable welfare Upper bound on the gap, first half of 2015 Median: 17 Q1: 9 Q3: 29 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 k 53

Conclusion of the gap evaluation Taking into account our assumptions on the prices (cf. slide on Early deactivation of some MIC orders ), the achieved gap on OMIE is zero The residual gap is thus on PCR without OMIE Our developments will focus on decreasing this residual gap

Next main steps to improve performance and quality of solutions Better evaluation of the gap Local search to decrease the number of PRBs Multi-threading, incl. internal measures to decrease numerical difficulties External measures to decrease numerical difficulties 55

How can we improve the solution? By improving the PRB reinsertion module (local search) Demand Swaps between blocks Supply Multiple reinsertions Price Accepted blocks Rejected blocks Quantity 56

Next main steps to improve performance and quality of solutions Better evaluation of the gap Local search to decrease the number of PRBs Multi-threading, incl. internal measures to decrease numerical difficulties External measures to decrease numerical difficulties 57

Work plan for Euphemia 10 3 Multi-threading to explore and close the gap 1 Find a valid solution 2 Look for a better solution by local search, attempt to remove PRBs 58

1 Feasible solution finder (FSF) Candidate solution: Selection of blocks and MICs Intuitive cuts PUN search Blocks and MICs cuts Euphemia valid solution 59

2 Local search The blocks and MICs selection is improved by simple operations: swaps, reinsertions, Euphemia valid solution Improved Euphemia valid solution Local search will be applied on each solution returned by the FSF 60

3 Tree exploration To reduce the gap, we have to work on the balance between depth and breadth exploration. Upper bound Lower bound Other interesting candidate solutions will be discovered along the way, and fed to the FSF 61

Where can we benefit from multi-threading? 1 FSF and local search 2 First, applied on the primal problem (root node) to find a first valid solution as soon as possible Then, applied to improve locally solutions found in the tree 3 Tree exploration Multiple threads simultaneously processing different nodes, and collaborating to decrease the gap 62

What Euphemia 10 will look like 3 Tree exploration FSF + local search 1 1 st Solution 2 The number of threads is illustrative 63

How does E10 address our current issues? FSF Local search Tree exploration Solution quality (gap) Number of PRBs Numerical difficulties 64

Next main steps to improve performance and quality of solutions Better evaluation of the gap Local search to decrease the number of PRBs Multi-threading, incl. internal measures to decrease numerical difficulties External measures to decrease numerical difficulties 65

Numerical issues impact the algorithm performances, and its robustness Small orders Quantity and /or price difference Small slopes for interpolated orders Curve aggregation can increase this issue Hybrid curves with steps and interpolated orders could be a solution Lots of decimals Currency conversion 66

Plan For mid 2016: Euphemia 9.4 with Local search to decrease number of PRBs, and other change requests Gap re-evaluation module For end 2016: Euphemia 10 with multithreading for more scalability, and yet more provably optimal solutions 67

Thank you! N-SIDE Watson & Crick Hill Park Bldg. H Rue Granbonpré, 11 B- 1348 Louvain-la-Neuve Bertrand Cornélusse Tel: +32 477 32 42 75 Email: bcr@n-side.com

Thank you - Q&A

Supplementary slides

Long term improvements More radical solutions could involve to alter the market design to ease the complexity of the problem. This could imply at least three possible approaches: 1. Reduce the amount of blocks types and other complex products allowed per participant and market (bidding zones). 2. Reducing the range of products treated in Euphemia 3. Relaxing the linear pricing rule (accept that the result has more than one price per bidding zone and time period) Following slides gives some more insight in to 2 and 3

2. Reducing the range of products treated in Euphemia Harmonization of products One such product could possibly be the new Thermal Order, modelling a thermal unit Minimum stable generation (similar to minimum acceptance ratio) Load gradient (similar to complex orders) Start up profile and cost (similar to MIC fixed term) Minimum running time when started, minimum down time Shut down profile (similar to scheduled stop) Must run conditions (capacity not available to the market) Flexible in time (similar to exclusive groups) Variable cost expressed in /MWh Etc. Caveat This product may actually bring additional complexity compared to (smart) blocks or MICs. This product would work only if 1 Thermal Order would replace multiple blocks. According to our provider the Thermal Order would also need us to consider a more radical market design and pricing regime change (next slide)

3. Relaxing the linear pricing rule Van Vyve model An alternate market design is discussed in [2011] Linear prices for nonconvex electricity markets: models and algorithms, M. Van Vyve; It builds on experiences from electricity markets in both US and Europe The model drops some of the current requirements in the current market design, and becomes more computationally tractable; The proposal does not respect the CACM one price per bidding zone and time unit requirement Preliminary thoughts of our algorithm provider (N-Side) are that such a model could be solved to (near) optimality with a proven optimality gap. If confirmed after extensive modelling and testing in pan-europe or MRC production like scenarios, this solution could possibly would address the main concerns expressed by Market Parties Platform

Van Vyve model - Caveats The proposed model however does introduce a series of significant changes to the current European market design: Out-of-the-money orders can be accepted, i.e. paradoxically accepted orders; These orders could be compensated via uplifts : some of the surplus generated by in-the-money orders would be funneled to these loss giving orders. Effectively this is a deviation from the single price per bidding zone and time period requirement of CACM: some orders receive uplifts on top of the clearing price, others pay uplifts on top of the clearing price. The net effect is that different orders pay/receive a different price even when they are in the same Bidding Zone;