No THE MUSEUM PASS GAME AND ITS VALUE REVISITED. By Arantza Estévez-Fernández, Peter Borm, Herbert Hamers. January 2004 ISSN

Similar documents
Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Price Discrimination: Exercises Part 2

The effects of the Dutch museum pass on museum visits and museum finances 1

Inventorymodel: an R Package for Centralized Inventory Problems by Alejandro Saavedra-Nieves

The Price of Anarchy in an Exponential Multi-Server

The Relevance of a Choice of Auction Format in a Competitive Environment

Industrial Organization

Optimal Inventory Allocation under Substitutable Demand

Operations and Supply Chain Management Prof. G. Srinivasan Department of Management Studies Indian Institute of Technology, Madras

Econ 302: Microeconomics II - Strategic Behavior. Problem Set # 3 May 31

Learning by Observing

Harvard University Department of Economics

The Ascending Bid Auction Experiment:

Introduction to Economic Institutions

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

RSM 392H1: Competitive Strategy

Economics 101 Fall 2013 Answers to Homework #6 Due Tuesday, Dec 10, 2013

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

"Solutions" to Non-constant Sum Games

Agility in Repeated Games: An Example

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Overview Day One. Introduction & background. Goal & objectives. System Model. Reinforcement Learning at Service Provider

Fair Division of a Dollar among Partners. 1 Introduction

Shapley (1953) started out with the following set of axioms.

A New Model for Visualizing Interactions in Analysis of Variance

Price dispersion and loss leaders

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

WORKING PAPER SERIES Judo Economics in Markets with Asymmetric Firms Daniel Cracau Working Paper No. 2/2013

The Retail Space-Exchange Problem with. Pricing and Space Allocation Decisions 1

Heuristic Algorithms for Simultaneously Accepting and Scheduling Advertisements on Broadcast Television

A perfectly competitive industry has identical firms and identical consumers. Each consumer earns $10,000 a year.

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

Quantitative Analysis for Management, 12e (Render) Chapter 2 Probability Concepts and Applications

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the

University of California, Davis

Making Optimal Decisions of Assembly Products in Supply Chain

INTRODUCTION TO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

The Robustness Of Non-Decreasing Dynamic Pricing Laura van der Bijl Research Paper Business analytics Aug-Oct 2017 Prof.

The Sealed Bid Auction Experiment:

Ranking Terrorists in Networks Husslage, Bart; Borm, Peter; Burg, T.; Hamers, Herbert; Lindelauf, R.

Motivating Examples of the Power of Analytical Modeling

This is a refereed journal and all articles are professionally screened and reviewed

INTRODUCTION TO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Imperfect Competition

Group Incentive Compatibility for Matching with Contracts

Chapter 11 Perfect Competition

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results *

Demand- how much of a product consumers are willing and able to buy at a given price during a given period.

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #17: Part I: Demand Reduction in Multi-Unit Auctions Revisited

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization

Optimization Prof. Debjani Chakraborty Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur

How to Cite or Link Using DOI

Bundling by Competitors and the Sharing of Profits. Abstract

First Exam in the Course: Labor Economics for Diplom/Master. 10 August 2011

University of Groningen. Investment evaluation with respect to commercial uncertainty Broens, Douwe Frits

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects

DEMAND CURVE AS A CONSTRAINT FOR BUSINESSES

Note on webpage about sequential ascending auctions

Quantity discount newsvendor model with and without price differences among buyers

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics DOES PRODUCT PATENT REDUCE R&D?

Synergistic Model Construction of Enterprise Financial Management Informatization Ji Yu 1

Overcoming the Limitations of Utility Design for Multiagent Systems

Combinatorial Auctions

PERFORMANCE EVALUATION OF DEPENDENT TWO-STAGE SERVICES

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Anti-Sharing as a Theory of Partnerships and Firms

Coordinating a Multi-Retailer Decentralized Distribution System with Random Demand Based on Buyback and Compensation Contracts

Equilibrium Selection and the Role of Information in Repeated. Matching Markets

PROBLEM SET 3. a) Find the pure strategy Nash Equilibrium of this game.

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 27 Monopoly

Paradoxes of Expected Value

Econ 380 Problem Set #6 Answer Sheet. 1. (3 points) The marginal control cost curves for two air pollutant sources are given by

Multiple Sourcing and Procurement Process Selection with Bidding Events

Check Your Understanding: The Profit Motive-The Marshallian Diagram

Applying Stackelberg Game to Find the Best Price and Delivery Time Policies in Competition between Two Supply Chains

1 Double Marginalization & Two Part Tariff

Lecture notes development

Multiproduct Pricing in Oligopoly

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Overview for Families

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

Some relationships between evolutionary stability criteria in games

Ch. 7 outline. 5 principles that underlie consumer behavior

How to Accomplish Effectiveness of Six Sigma

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Paper 11 Urban Economics

Economics 101A (Lecture 27) Stefano DellaVigna

Journal of Industrial Organization Education. Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Bilateral and Multilateral Exchanges for Peer-Assisted Content Distribution

CHAPTER 5: DISCRETE PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTIONS

PRICE DISPERSION AND LOSS LEADERS

Targeted Advertising with Inventory Management

Externalities. 5 Microeconomics ACTIVITY 5-2

Transcription:

No. 2004 07 THE MUSEUM PASS GAME AND ITS VALUE REVISITED By Arantza Estévez-Fernández, Peter Borm, Herbert Hamers January 2004 ISSN 0924-7815

The museum pass game and its value revisited Arantza Estévez-Fernández a, Peter Borm a,b, Herbert Hamers a Abstract: This paper is a reaction on Ginsburgh and Zang (2003). It reconsiders the problem where a group of museums offer a pass such that the owner can visit these museums an unlimited number of times during a fixed period of time. The problem addressed is how to share the total joint income of this pass system among the museums. Ginsburgh and Zang propose to use the Shapley value of an associated cooperative game. Arguments are provided to model this problem within the framework of bankruptcy problems. Keywords: Museum pass problem, bankruptcy problem. 1 The Ginsburgh and Zang s model Ginsburgh and Zang (2003) stated the following problem: Museum passes which give visitors (tourists as well as residents) unlimited access to participating museums during a limited period of one to several days (perhaps a whole year for residents) have become very common in many European or North-American cities, regions, or even entire countries. The problem is how to share the net income from the sale of passes among the participating museums. Ginsburgh and Zang consider the following cooperative game (N, v) to analyze this allocation problem. The set of museums that participate in the museum pass system is denoted by N. The price of the museum pass is denoted by π. Let M be the set of customers that buy a museum pass. For each j M, let K j N denote the set of museums that customer j visits (at least once). The value of a coalition S N is then defined as v(s) = π {j M : K j S}, i.e., the game is based on the sum of M unanimity games: v = π j M u Kj. The Shapley value of this game is proposed as a way to share the joint income, M π, from the pass system. We now provide two examples which illustrate serious drawbacks of Ginsburgh and Zang s proposal. Example 1.1. Suppose that we have two museums, 1 and 2, with a museum pass. The regular prices of a ticket for museum 1 and 2 are 10 and 5 Euro, respectively. The price of the museum pass is 12 Euro. Assume that each person who buys the museum card goes once to each museum and that the total number of museum passes sold is 100. Using Ginsburgh and Zang s solution, each museum would obtain 600 Euro from the museum pass system. In this case museum 2 obtains more than it would have obtained if all visitors had bought regular tickets. a CentER and Department of Econometrics and Operations Research, Tilburg University, P.O.Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands. b Corresponding author. E-mail: P.E.M.Borm@uvt.nl

Example 1.2. Suppose again that we have two museums, 1 and 2, with a museum pass. The regular price of a ticket for both museum 1 and 2 is 10 Euro while the price of the museum pass is 15 Euro. Assume that each person who buys the museum card goes once to museum 1 and twice to museum 2 and that the total number of museum passes sold is 100. Using Ginsburgh and Zang s solution, each museum would obtain 750 Euro from the museum pass system. In this case both museums obtain the same amount, although museum 1 and 2 would have earned 1000 and 2000 Euro respectively if all visits had been on the basis of regular tickets. These examples clearly show that Ginsburgh and Zang s solution is not always suitable. In particular Ginsburgh and Zang s solution does not take into account possible asymmetries with respect to both the prices of the regular tickets of the museums and the number of times that a visitor (with a pass) goes to one museum. Moreover, Ginsburgh and Zang s model also has an informational drawback: it requires to know the exact list of museums that each particular pass holder visits. 2 A bankruptcy approach to museum pass problems In this section we model the museum pass problem as addressed in Ginsburgh and Zang (2003) as a bankruptcy problem. A museum pass problem is denoted by (N, π, p) where N is the (finite) set of museums that are involved in a museum pass system, π is the price of the museum pass and p = (p i ) i N R N is the vector of regular prices of the museums. Let (µ, m) be a realization of the museum pass system, i.e, µ is the number of museum passes sold and m = (m i ) i N R N measures the number of visits 1 that have been made to the individual museums using a museum pass. Since it is reasonable to assume that µπ i N m ip i (all customers want to profit from their passes) we can define the associated bankruptcy problem (E, c) as follows. The estate E is the total revenues that are obtained from the sale of the museum passes, i.e., E = µπ, and the vector of claims represents the total amount that each museum would have obtained if all visits had been made with a regular ticket, c R N with c i = m i p i for i N. There exist various types of allocations rules for bankruptcy problems (for a survey see Thomson (2003)). We will consider the following classic rules: the random arrival rule, the constrained equal award rule, the constrained equal loss rule and the Talmud rule. Besides, we introduce a modification of the proportional rule that takes into account minimal rights of the museums. The proportional rule with minimal rights assigns to each museum its minimal right plus the amount that it gets when the proportional rule is applied to the remainder (the original estate minus the sum of all minimal rights) with a new vector of claims which is the difference between the initial vector of claims and the vector of minimal rights. The minimal right of a museum i N is the 1 If a particular visitor with a museum pass visits a museum twice, this counts as two visits.

amount that remains if all other museums claims have been fully satisfied (or 0 if the estate is not high enough to satisfy these claims). Next we reconsider Example 1.1 and Example 1.2 using the random arrival rule and the proportional rule with minimal rights. Example 2.1. Consider the museum pass problem introduced in Example 1.1. For the associated bankruptcy problem (E, c) we find that E = 1200 and c = (1000, 500). Then the allocation proposed by the random arrival rule and the proportional rule with minimal rights coincide and equals (850, 350). This outcome clearly takes into account the asymmetry in regular prices between the two museums. Example 2.2. Consider the museum problem introduced in Example 1.2. For the associated bankruptcy problem (E, c) it holds that E = 1500 and c = (1000, 2000). Then the allocation proposed by the random arrival rule is (500, 1000). For the proportional rule with minimal rights this is (400, 1100). Both outcomes reflect the fact that there is a clear difference in the visiting attitude of museum pass holders although the museums are symmetric on the basis of prices. In the examples above we have just considered two rules: the random arrival rule and the proportional rule with minimal rights. Not without reason: the following example illustrates contextspecific drawbacks of the constrained equal award rule, the constrained equal loss rule and the Talmud rule. Example 2.3. Let (N, π, p) be a museum pass problem with N = {1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6}, π = 15 and p = (10, 10, 8, 5, 3, 3). Consider a realization (µ, m) with µ = 10 and m = (16, 11, 7, 10, 7, 5) 2. The associated bankruptcy problem has an estate E = 150 and a vector of claims c = (160, 110, 56, 50, 21, 15). Table 1 provides possible allocations to this problem on the basis of several bankruptcy rules. Museums 1 2 3 4 5 6 Rules Random Arrival Prop. with minimal rights Constrained Equal Loss Constrained Equal Award Talmud 53.4667 42.8667 20.8000 18.8000 8.0500 5.7500 58.2524 40.0485 20.3884 18.2039 7.6456 5.4612 100 50 0 0 0 0 28.5 28.5 28.5 28.5 21.0 15.0 39.5 39.5 28.0 25.0 10.5 7.5 Table 1: Several bankruptcy rules applied to a museum pass problem. 2 Note that we, contrary to Ginsburgh and Zang, do not need data about how many times a specific visitor goes to a particular museum.

The general principle behind the constrained equal loss rule is to divide the losses of each museum (with respect to their claims) as equal as possible. In Example 2.3 we see that museums 3, 4, 5 and 6 do not get anything whereas they have visitors using the museum pass. For this reason it seems that the constrained equal loss rule is not a good solution in this specific context. The general principle behind the constrained equal award rule is that it tries to divide the estate as equal as possible (taking the claims as upper bounds). In Example 2.3 we see that museums 5 and 6 get their claims whereas museums 1, 2, 3 and 4 get an equal amount. Assuming that the claims somehow reflect the quality or attraction of a museum 3 then the museums with higher claims are essential to make the pass system a success. For this reason the proposed equality within the top of museums seems an undesirable aspect and we do not consider the constrained equal award rule as a good choice to solve the museum pass problem. The Talmud rule for this particular case boils down to the constrained equal award rule for the bankruptcy problem with the same estate but where all claims are halved. Obviously this implies that we have the same kind of reasons to discard the Talmud rule as the constrained equal award rule itself. 3 Conclusions This paper provides a bankruptcy model for the museum pass problem introduced by Ginsburgh and Zang (2003). It is illustrated that some classical bankruptcy rules are more appropriate to solve museum pass problems than others. Contrary to the rule proposed by Ginsburgh and Zang (2003), the strength of these rules is that they take into account asymmetries with respect to prices in regular tickets and the number of visits to museums. We want to stress, however, that this paper does not provide a final general answer: it just provides a more adequate framework to analyze museum pass problems. A specific solution will typically depend on the particular features of the type of instance at hand (large or small asymmetries, informational aspects, etc.). References Ginsburgh, V. and Zang, I. (2003), The museum pass game and its value, Games and Economic Behavior 43, 322 325. Thomson, W. (2003), Axiomatic and game-theoretic analysis of bankruptcy and taxation problems: a survey, Mathematical Social Sciences 45(3), 249 297. 3 High claims can reflect that either the the number of visits is high or the price in the regular tickets is high.