Labor demand and economic development policy

Similar documents
Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

MONEY, CREDIT, AND FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY: REPLY TO PORTER AND OFFENBACHER

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Introduction to Labour Economics. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. What is Labour Economics?

Natalie Uhrová 1, Petr Skalka 2

REPORT ON CANDIDATES WORK IN THE CARIBBEAN ADVANCED PROFICIENCY EXAMINATION MAY/JUNE 2008 ECONOMICS (REGION EXCLUDING TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO)

LABOUR ECONOMICS - ECOS3008

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

9708 ECONOMICS. Mark schemes should be read in conjunction with the question paper and the Principal Examiner Report for Teachers.

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2015 series 9708 ECONOMICS

Review Questions. The Own-Wage Elasticity of Labor Demand. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

THE LIST OF COURSES OF ECONOMIC DEPARTMENT

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market

Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle

SME Size, Job Creation and the Impact of Exchange Rate Fluctuations: the case of Korea

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Sectoral engines of job-rich growth: Some lessons from ILO sectoral country studies

Knowledge Exchange Report. Economic Impact of Mandatory Overtime on New York State Agriculture

SYLLABUS. Class B.Com. I Sem. Subject Micro Economics

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

MANAGERIAL MODELS OF THE FIRM

LONG-RUN INFORMATION DIFFUSION PROCESSES IN THE PERTH HOUSING MARKET:

Economics. Synopsis. 1. Economic Concepts, Issues and Tools. 2. An Overview of Economics. Sections. Learning Summary. Sections

ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT LEVEL 1 PAPER 3 STUDY TEXT

MARK SCHEME for the May/June 2012 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

MARK SCHEME for the May/June 2012 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

Chapter 1: Ten Principles of Economics Principles of Economics, 4 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

2.2 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

ECONOMICS STUDY TEXT

Study Questions for George Reisman's Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2012 series 9708 ECONOMICS

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2012 series 9708 ECONOMICS


MONETARY ACTIONS AND AGRICULTURE. Speech by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6. The law of diminishing marginal returns begins to take effect at labor input level: a. 0 b. X c. Y d. Z

Relevant Costs and Revenues

Commentson\CatchingUpwiththeLeaders: The Irish Hare", by Patrick Honohan and Brendan Walsh

Chapter 9 Shocks. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 145

DERIVING DEMAND CURVES FOR SPECIFIC TYPES OF OUTDOOR RECREATION

PAPER No. : 02 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS MODULE No. : 03 PRINCIPLES: INDIVIDUAL AND MARKET

Study Questions for George Reisman's Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics

Chapter 8 The Labor Market: Employment, Unemployment, and Wages

CURRICULUM COURSE OUTLINE

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

I ll start with a story in the high-school physics: the story about Isaac Newton s Law of Universal Gravitation.

Business Cycle Theory Revised: March 25, 2009

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

Ten ways to improve evaluation skills and marks in A2 economics

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

LECTURE April Tuesday, April 30, 13

Reply to the Referees John J. Seater 15 April 2008

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Chapter 3. Labour Demand. Introduction. purchase a variety of goods and services.

Lecture 2. Lecturer: Dr. Priscilla T. Baffour. Priscilla T. Baffour 2016/17 1

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Economics. Chapter. 1 E.2 How do producers and consumers deal with scarcity, opportunity costs, and trade offs?

real rigidities The definition of real rigidities Real rigidities and business cycles

September 2006 REAL RIGIDITIES * David Romer University of California, Berkeley

Empirical Analysis of the effect of Human Capital Generation on Economic Growth in India - a Panel Data approach

Transitions of creatives? empirical evidence on occupation and industry specific human capital

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

Introduction [to Recent Developments in the Theory of Involuntary Unemployment]

Kaldorian Approach to Greek Economic Growth

Chapter 1: Ten Principles of Economics Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

Economics Lecture notes- Semester 1:

Derived copy of The Building Blocks of Keynesian Analysis *

Has there been a structural improvement in US productivity?

Carl M. Campbell III

Comment BERTOLA & CABALLERO

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

The Tire Industry Economic Impact Study. Methodology and Documentation Prepared for: U.S. Tire Manufacturers Association

AN PRODUCTIVITY BASED HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

Macroeconomics II Unemployment

Topics in Labor Supply

ECO401 Current Online 85 Quizzes Question Repeated ignore In Green color are doubted one

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

Keynes' Labor Market: A Reply. By Allan H. Meitzer

The True Cause of Business Cycle

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

New firms are the most productive

TEACHING MICRO AND MACRO AS SEPARATE COURSES

Trade Liberalisation and Its Impact on Employment: An Analysis of Indian Experiences (With Special References of Indian Manufacturing Industries)

Field 048: Social Studies Economics Assessment Blueprint

What Causes Changes in Unemployment over the Short Run *

Neoclassical economics (1890s 1930s)

Chapter 2--Financial Reporting: Its Conceptual Framework

Some Implications of Labor Adjustments in a Dual Economy Framework: Wyoming's Energy-Agriculture Interface

Chapter 11 Pay and Productivity: Wage Determination within the Firm

Economics Challenge Online State Qualification Practice Test. 1. An increase in aggregate demand would tend to result from

Interest and the Length of

Full file at

RECENT EVIDENCE ON IMPROVED INVENTORY CONTROL: A QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE U.S. ECONOMY FOR THE PERIOD Sweidan, Osama D. *

TOWARDS INTERGENERATIONAL EQUITY IN LP BASED LONG TERM FOREST PLANNING MODELS. Roger Church and Peter J. Daugherty 1

Transcription:

Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 1984, volume 2, pages 45-55 Labor demand and economic development policy G L Clark Department of Geography, The University of Chicago, Chicago, I L 60637, USA Received 20 December 1982; in revised form 3 April 1983 Abstract. Neoclassical theory presumes that the demand for labor is a function of its real wage. Many local development agencies have taken this proposition as an article of faith, designing policies that effectively lower the real cost of labor. Empirical evidence for the textiles and electronics industries in a set of states in the USA provides only limited support for this theory and its implied policy menu. Alternative models of the demand for labor are explored, including neo-keynesian fixed-price quantity-adjustment models. Analysis is based on a set of time-series adjustment models which emphasize the dynamics of labor demand. 1 Introduction The High-Technology Industry Council of, an employer organization representing firms associated with the burgeoning semiconductor industry, has complained in recent years about the cost and availability of labor. They contend that not only are skilled, highly educated workers difficult to find and retain, but that even production workers are in limited supply. Digital, the multinational computer company headquartered in, has also contended that labor is in short supply, arguing as well that the Boston area is becoming expensive compared to lower-wage regions in other parts of the USA. In response, economic development agencies in have sought to reduce the cost of labor through tax credits and wage subsidies. These policies take seriously the neoclassical notion that the demand for labor is a function of its relative price (relative, that is, to the market price of output and the marginal productivity of labor). And, in many other states, economic development agencies obviously believe this conception, as evidenced by their advertising in the national media of the relative cost advantages of locating in their states. Despite the apparent faith of local policymakers in the neoclassical labor demand model, and the claims of industry representatives, it is not clear that labor markets actually function according to theoretical expectations. This paper considers in detail the various theories and determinants of local labor demand. The neoclassical real wage hypothesis is tested using data from two industries, textiles and the electrical and electronics equipment industry, in a set of southern, western, and northern states in the USA over the period 1954-1976. Since it is shown that the neoclassical model is of limited applicability, alternative models of labor demand are tested, including those premised upon fixed-price assumptions. Profit, output, and the distribution of income between labor and capital are considered in a sequence of tests of theories and public policies. Time-series labor demand equations are estimated in the context of regional industrial growth and decline using the autoregressive maximum likelihood estimation procedure recently introduced by Beach and MacKinnon (1978). Yearly time-series data were provided by the Census of Manufacturers (Department of Commerce, various years), the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (Browne et al, 1980), and the Department of Labor (1982).

46 G L Clark 2 Wages as prices Neoclassical economic theory is so well-known that we need not dwell upon its intricacies. Efficient allocation of scarce resources is the objective of neoclassical theory. The price of any good, be it labor or cheese, is a signal that enables exchange and a means of valuation. Given a set of resources, tastes, and preferences, the use of any good or factor of production will be determined by demand. And, given a set of possible uses for resources, their specific use will be allocated to those willing to pay the most. Prices, then, effectively provide a relative measure of the value of any set of goods. Assuming marginal productivity conditions and perfect competition, neoclassical theory supposes that demand and supply will equilibrate at full employment. Again, it is prices that make this result possible; they are assumed to be infinitely flexible, and are the means of allocating resources. For policymakers concerned with stimulating local economic development, the implications of this model are stark. For instance, given a national, even international, commodity market, local agencies must ensure that local firms are competitive. A condition for competitive strength is that labor must be paid the value of its marginal product; that is, local wages must be standardized by the market price of output and labor productivity. It is also required that local firms must be as competitive as other firms in the industry, regardless of location. For regions dominated by older and less efficient firms, this means that the competitive strengths of other more efficient firms outside the region would directly affect the pricing behavior of local firms. Consequently, labor in the older region would be paid less than labor in other regions. It should not come as a surprise to see economic development agencies focus upon reducing the real costs of local production through subsidies and tax credits. National policymakers have also taken this theory seriously, insisting that maximum national wealth is only possible if production and resources are sectorally and spatially allocated in accordance with their most efficient uses. The President's National Urban Policy Report (1982), for example, contended that national wealth has been compromised by past attempts at stimulating local economic development regardless of the best market solutions. Plant-closing legislation, minimum wages, and local direct job creation programs have all been the targets of conservative critics of local development policies. Enterprise zones have been promoted by the federal government, and depend to a large extent on the real wage notion of neoclassical theory. The costs of production are reduced via reduced regulations, differential wage scales, and the like, and the demand for labor thereby stimulated. Again, competitive pricing is assumed, and 'institutional' forces that are thought to maintain artificially high wages are implicated as being the causes of higher local unemployment. These arguments are familiar to many. The most immediate question, however, is whether or not empirical evidence supports the theory and its policy prescriptions. To test the proposition that the demand for labor is a function of its real wage, data were collected from the US Census of Manufacturers (Department of Commerce, various years) and the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (Browne et al, 1980) for two industries, textiles (a declining industry) and the electrical and electronics equipment industry (a growing industry), in a set of northern, southern, and western states in the USA. By choosing this set of industries and places, it was hoped that the geographical diversity and range of different employment conditions would be given fullest expression. For example, in Kentucky and, textiles is a growth industry compared with the situation in and. On the other hand, the electrical and electronics equipment industry has been growing in many states since 1954, and has accelerated in recent years, especially in California.

Labor demand and economic development policy 47 and The relationships tested regarding the neoclassical 'wages as prices' hypothesis were: MHOURSp = a+/jrwagesi'7i + e,, (1) MHOURSW'= ce+/3rwages^i+7lprod^; + e,, (2) where the dependent variable, MHOURS, was the formal labor demand dependent variable for a point in time t, in state z, and in industry /; R WAGES and LP ROD were, respectively, the relevant real wage and average labor productivity independent variables for state i and industry /, lagged one time period, t \ (1) ; a, f5, and y were parameters, and e was an error term. All variables in these and subsequent equations were differenced, so that instead of dealing with levels, we were dealing with changes over time. Total man-hours were chosen to represent labor demand, rather than employment, because there are a number of different strategies employers can use to vary the quantity of their labor input. Actual changes in the level of employment is one strategy, but so too is overtime. Man-hours as a variable is the most general one for indicating labor demand (Baily, 1977). Since the estimated equations were based on yearly time-series, an estimation method sensitive to serial autocorrelation was required. In this paper, Beach and MacKinnon's (1978) maximum likelihood regression procedure (MLRP) was used to account for possible biases that may result from the existence of first-order autoregressive autocorrelation. Hazledine (1978) has noted that there have been few tests of dynamic labor demand functions that have used disaggregated sectoral data, let alone disaggregated spatial data. On these two counts, we should expect to see variations in parameter estimates, as well as, perhaps, variations in parameter signs and significance levels. It should also be acknowledged that the use of lagged independent variables also implies a number of assumptions. First, like Nickell (1978), I assume that a firm's demand for labor changes slowly in response to changes in determining variables. Transaction costs of hiring and firing workers, as well as fixed technical production relationships between labor and capital, may all conspire to make labor demand a lagged adjustment process. Second, and more technically, I would also argue that if we are to establish causality between the dependent and independent variables, the temporal sequence of change and response must be unambiguous. Thus I use a time-series methodology that tests adjustment of the dependent variable to changes in the independent variables in the previous time period. Results of analysis indicated that the 'wages as prices' hypothesis is hardly tenable as a general explanation of the demand for labor. If we assume that labor demand is an inverse function of real wages, the results in table 1 provide little systematic evidence for policies that seek to reduce the local cost of labor as a condition for further employment growth. For the sample states with electrical and electronics equipment industries, the signs on the wage parameter were positive, implying that increasing real wages are associated with increasing labor demand in the subsequent period. This is not the result predicted by neoclassical theory; the sign on the wage parameter should have been negative. For textiles, two states do in fact have significant negative parameters, and states that have been ^ ' Real wages were measured in terms of total compensation per year per production employee weighted by the national producer price index for the relevant industry. This index measures "average change in prices received in primary markets of the United s by producers of commodities in all states of production" (Department of Labor, 1982, page 166). In this context, the real wage is defined from the producers' perspective.

48 G L Clark characterized as declining (absolutely and relatively) in terms of the national growth patterns of that industry. Yet, for Kentucky and, two relative growth states for textiles, the signs are positive, albeit that, in the case of Kentucky, the parameter is insignificant. Other writers have found positive and significant signs on real wage parameters, particularly when modelling the short-run dynamics of labor demand. Hamermesh (1975) explained this result by what he termed the 'interdependence effect'. Essentially, workers are assumed to be very sensitive to changes in relative earnings, more so than to wage levels. The wages of one group of workers are the reference point for another, so that, in general, there exists a high degree of interdependence between workers in their relative wages. As a consequence of increasing the wage of one group of workers (say, for example, in response to increasing labor productivity), a firm may have to adjust the wages of all workers. Otherwise those workers not included in the wage increase may slacken their work effort. If this was to happen, according to Hamermesh (1975) firms may have to increase the hours worked of all Table 1. Labor demand and real wages. a p DW a R 2 P Arkansas California (d) Kentucky -34500* 10200* 1.78-50400 29600* 1.47 74700 11000* 1.64-4020 22200 1.87 3 500 1160 1.50 171000* -18000* 1.55 130000* -6900* 1.52 311000* 29000* 1.70 0.71* 0.67* -0.01 0.74* 0.33* 0.66* 0.17* 0.43 0.01 0.60* 0.85* 0.47 0.69* 0.52* 0.76* 0.65* a DW is the Durbin-Watson statistic; R 2 is the coefficient of determination; p is an autocorrelation Table 2. Labor demand, real wages, and labor productivity. Arkansas California (d) (d) Kentucky (d) a -34600* 2800 78100-4249 385 167000* -4640* 276000* 0 10300* 20100 9950 22300-274 -15300 17000* 47800* 7-19 827 319 294-112 -1150-316 -6430 DW a 1.80 1.83 1.64 1.86 1.88 1.55 1.83 1.75 R 2 0.71* 0.06 0.33* 0.76 0.02 0.85* 0.52* 0.78* P 0.67* 0.11 0.67* 0.21 0.08 0.49* -0.19 0.63* a DW is the Durbin-Watson statistic; R 2 is the coefficient of determination; p is an autocorrelation

Labor demand and economic development policy 49 employees, even hire extra employees to sustain targeted production levels. In this sense, increasing wages would cause increasing labor demand. Lack of theoretical consistency in the sign and significance of the real wage parameter is consistent with aggregate empirical macroeconomic studies that have found real wages to be of limited importance in explaining the demand for labor (Hazledine, 1981). In response, some writers have included labor productivity variables, on the assumption that real wages may not adequately reflect variations in labor productivity. Table 2 reports the results of a test of such an augmented neoclassical labor demand model. The results of this test are even more disheartening for those who would depend upon the veracity of the neoclassical model. There were no significant coefficients (whether negative or positive) found on the real wage variable and the labor productivity coefficients were uniformly insignificant. 3 Prices and profits If changing wages have little relevance in the majority of state industries studied here, as signals for allocating resources, what then determines changes in the demand for labor? And, if increasing real wages are related to employment and production restructuring, we still require an explanation of the demand for labor per se. One implication to be drawn from the fact that increases in real wages rarely negatively affect changes in the demand for labor relates to pricing practices of firms in general. If production costs do not directly affect factor demand, then there is some question as to the general significance of commodity prices being the signals for final demand. Perhaps, commodity prices are not set on the basis of cost but on the basis of profit. That is, if input costs are assumed given or predictable, then variations in product demand over the short run would be reflected in changing profit levels. A second implication is that some firms may price their products on a cost-plus (or mark-up) schedule that has as its objective function a certain expected profit. This scenario is not as neat as the neoclassical vision of competition in a flex-price world. The expected profit hypothesis depends upon a set of arguments that essentially deny the validity of neoclassical competitive market assumptions. For instance, lack of immediate importance of input-cost constraints in setting commodity prices suggests that either demand for firms' commodities are relatively secure, regardless of price, or that commodities are rationed in the market by quantity produced. In either event, the price of the good is likely to be relatively stable, less sensitive to every shift in demand than assumed by neoclassical theory. Gordon (1981) has noted, in fact, that commodity prices are sticky, like money wages, and that they are clearly less sensitive to demand than, for example, output. Indeed, consumer prices adjust relatively slowly, whether at the national or at the local level (Clark, 1984). Under these conditions, commodity prices are set in accordance with a cost-plus mark-up system. Thus the demand for labor is simply a function of profit. To test this hypothesis, the following two relationships were tested for the sample industries, states, and time period noted in the previous section: and MHOURSJ'' = a+j3rprofitjl{+e,, (3) MHOURS^ = a+ftrprofit/k^ + e,, (4) where RPROFIT and RPROFIT/K were, respectively, the gross (before taxes) real profit of each industry-state combination and real profit (again before taxes) on

50 G L Clark capital invested (2). Through the use of Beach and MacKinnon's (1978) MLRP, expressions (3) and (4) were transformed to adjustment modes, so that changes in the demand for labor were functionally related to previous changes in gross real profit and gross real profit on capital invested. For interpretive purposes we could imagine that expression (3) represents the managers' notion of profit, whereas expression (4) could represent investors' or shareholders' notions of profit. Real profit, the managers' version, was clearly an important determinant of the demand for labor in the electrical and electronics equipment industry (table 3). Not only was the parameter of the correct sign (positive, implying an increase in profit will increase the demand for labor, and vice versa) and significant for Arkansas, California, and, but the coefficients of determination (R 2 ) were very reasonable for a time-series methodology. However, it was also true that, for the textile industry in general, real profit was not a significant determinant of the demand for labor. This was despite the fact that, in some instances, the coefficients of determination were quite strong. What is immediately apparent is that gross real profit is significant for southern, western, and northern states in the electronics industry, a general result that cuts across geography, something that was not the case when we considered the impacts of real wages on the demand for labor. When real profit, the investors' version, is included as the independent variable, a markedly different picture emerges (table 4). This variable is not significant for any industry or state. Thus far we have two broad conclusions. Real wages are only significant and of the correct sign in determining the demand for labor for two northern states with textile industries. Real profits, on the other hand, are significant and important determinants of the demand for labor in the electronics industry for states from a variety of US regions. This industry is one that has grown rapidly over the past two decades, and the observations made already, concerning the 'sticky' nature of prices, may apply with some force. For instance, for many product lines, demand has Table 3. Labor demand and real profit. a P DW a R 2 p Arkansas California (d) Kentucky 5550* 149000* 110000* 262 7380* 80700* 77200* 382000* 0.13* 0.60* 0.07* 0.01 0.04-0.01 0.05 0.06 1.88 1.63 1.71 1.83 1.68 1.53 1.88 1.70 0.66* 0.60* 0.49* 0.02 0.03 0.19 0.54* 0.72* 0.57* 0.91* 0.50* 0.34 0.61* 0.98* 0.94* 0.60* a DW is the Durbin-Watson statistic; R 2 is the coefficient of determination; p is an autocorrelation * ' Real profit was measured by gross profits, before tax, of firms in each state and industry, weighted by the producer price index. Profits were calculated by subtracting the total wage bill of all employees and the cost of other inputs from the total value-added of the industry and state. Real profit capital invested measured real profits relative to the value of real net capital invested for each industry and state. Both series were standardized by 1972 producer prices, the source for the capital data being the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (Browne et al, 1980) and Gertler (1983).

Labor demand and economic development policy 51 expanded rapidly (as for electronic calculators and the like) and technology has transformed both the nature of production and the commodity itself (for example, portable radios). At the same time, the industry has become more concentrated, leading to a reduced importance for competitive pricing and an increased likelihood of the strategy of profit targeting being pursued. For an economic development agency aiming to stimulate local employment, these results have two specific implications. First, the notion of cost efficiency seems much less relevant for growing industries compared with declining industries. In fact, given the relative insignificance of input prices as constraints for firms in the electronics industry, policies such as wage subsidies may simply be cash transfers to those firms rather than incentives to hire more labor. At the same time, it is also plausible that wage interdependence may lead to employment restructuring, so that in the longer run the whole local economy may itself be transformed (Clark, 1981). Second, it is also apparent that the demand for labor is quite sensitive to profit, albeit a quite specific definition. Conventional accounting notions of profit relative to capital invested are not as relevant as the gross flow of profits. Table 4. Labor demand and real profit/capital invested. Arkansas California (d) Kentucky a 16000 164000* 141000* -448 7460* 83300* 88300* 44000* P 0.54 418.00 17.60-0.54 1.47-11.40 5.81 0.66 DW a 1.68 1.50 1.66 1.85 1.73 1.55 1.76 1.69 R 2-0.24-0.20 0.28-0.01 0.04 0.21 0.54* 0.69* P 0.96* 0.93* 0.75 0.30 0.66* 0.98* 0.93* 0.79* a DW is the Durbin-Watson statistic; R 2 is the coefficient of determination; p is an autocorrelation 4 Output and labor adjustment Keynesian economists often argue that price adjustment is rare in a modern economy and that quantity adjustment is the rule. As demand changes in the short run, firms adapt by changing output, not the price of their goods nor the price of their inputs. As a consequence, prices are 'sticky' in the short run and productive resources are allocated on the basis of quantity requirements. From this position it is then argued that as output changes so too does the demand for labor. Essentially, quantity adjustment brings forth further quantity adjustments. If we presume that prices do not vary in the short run, there should be a direct relationship between output and employment. Indeed, many short-run labor demand models have no price or profit variables, preferring instead to link employment to output and to lagged values of itself (see, especially, Ball and St Cyr, 1966). In the absence of output measures, employment then becomes a lagged function of itself. Of course, theoretically, the supposed adjustment process is more complex than its empirical representation. Firms are assumed to have a desired level of employment, subject to planned output. In some

52 G L Clark cases [for example, Peel and Walker (1978)], scale variables are also included to account for particular production functions and their implied labor demand schedules. Because employment fluctuates less than output in the short run, and because desired employment levels cannot be measured, the theoretical elegance of these models often degenerates into the empirical forms noted above. Conventional regional econometric models, such as the economic base formulation, take this logic as an article of faith. Indeed, so well-accepted is the supposed relationship between output and employment that few researchers bother to make the logic explicit, let alone test its veracity. Yet, for all the apparent importance of this conception in the regional economic development literature, the evidence noted below hardly supports the notion of a direct relationship between changes in output and changes in the demand for labor. The following relationship was tested: MHOURS{»> = ce+^rprofit^i+troutput^ + e,, (5) where ROUTPUT was the variable representing the output hypothesis (3). Real profit was retained as an independent variable to hold revenue effects constant. Again, the whole relationship was transformed to a dynamic form, concerned with changes not levels. In the previous section, it was observed that changes in real profits are important determinants of changes in the demand for labor in the electronics industry, but not in the textile industry. However, when we take output into account, it is obvious that neither real profit nor real output are significant determinants of the demand for labor (table 5). This was true for both industries in all states; there were no exceptions. For those that have assumed employment to best represent output, as for example in the economic base model, this result must be viewed with a great deal of alarm. Agreed, these results are based on a dynamic time-series model, and it is true that, cross sectionally, output and employment are highly correlated, yet these results also imply that the most conventional and widely used regional impact model may have little empirical veracity. Models utilized by authors, such as Vernez et al (1977), which deal explicitly with employment as an indicator of short-run demand shifts, may be prone to significant errors. Table 5. Labor demand, real profit, and real output. Arizona California (d) Kentucky 5530* 132000* 121000* -1700 4140* 54200 63200* 319000* P 7 DW a R 2 0.08 0.56 0.16-0.08-0.38-0.27-0.05-0.32 0.03 0.01-0.05 0.59 0.30 0.17 0.07 0.20 1.87 1.65 1.72 1.81 1.67 1.93 1.94 1.82 0.69* -0.16 0.51* 0.11 0.29* 0.40* 0.53* 0.76* 0.54* 0.84* 0.53* 0.23 0.40 0.96* 0.94* 0.61* a DW is the Durbin-Watson statistic; R 2 is the coefficient of determination; p is an autocorrelation ^ Real output measured the value of output, or value-added, based on the 1972 producer price index for the two industries and their states.

Labor demand and economic development policy 53 Lest the reader dismiss this result as an aberration, I should hasten to note the consistency of this result with other recent macroeconomic and regional labor market studies. Hall (1980), in a study of employment fluctuations at the national level, observed that output is clearly more volatile than employment in the short run. In fact, employment is quite sticky, adjusting much more slowly to consumer demand shifts than output. Elsewhere I have observed that this is also the case in many local labor markets (Clark, 1983). 5 Wages and profits The final issue I wish to address regarding the determinants of the demand for labor relates to the relationships between capital and labor. In particular, the question considered in this section is whether or not changes in the distribution of income (in the form of wages and profits) affect changes in the demand for labor. Radicals have argued that, in the short run and given total revenue, as labor exerts a stronger hold over capital (as for example in a boom period), wages should increase relative to profit, thereby initiating a subsequent decline in the demand for labor (Rowthorn, 1980). This argument is essentially premised upon a zero-sum conception of income distribution. All we need assume is that the stock of labor is relatively limited in the short run, albeit sometimes underemployed. To investigate the relevance of this hypothesis, an empirical test was developed such that: MHOURSj*' = a+jsrjustj/i+tkin'ri+e^, (6) where RJUST was the ratio of real profits to real wages and KIN was the capital intensity of production (4). So as to retain the concern with dynamic adjustment, these variables were also differenced. The results of analysing this relationship are shown in table 6. In only one instance were changes in the distribution of income between capital and labor a significant determinant of changes in the demand for labor. For 's electronics industry, an increase in profits relative to wages will cause an increase in the demand for labor in the subsequent time period. Otherwise there was no apparent relationship between the distribution of income and the demand for labor, holding capital Table 6. Labor demand, income distribution, and capital intensity. Arkansas California (d) (d) Kentucky a 14100 17700 51700 13000 9280* 110000* 92900* 370000* P 230 27800 101000* -51600-254 -22700 7470 90600 7 0.4 x 10 6-0.2 x 10 7 0.3 x 10 7-0.2 x 10 7-0.1 x 10 6-1.2 x 10 7-0.1 x 10 7 0.1 x 10 7 DW a 1.69 1.88 1.71 1.83 1.64 1.84 1.80 1.63 R 2-0.24 0.03 0.49* 0.15 0.02 0.46* 0.56* 0.72* P 0.96* 0.02 0.69* 0.14 0.75* 0.95* 0.91* 0.70* a DW is the Durbin - Watson statistic; R 2 is the coefficient of determination; p is an autocorrelation ^ Income distribution measured the relative shares of gross real profit and the total real wage bill as a ratio based on the variables noted above, and capital intensity measured the amount of capital per production employee, standardized by the 1972 producer price index.

54 G L Clark intensity constant for the other states and industries. This result should not come as too much of a surprise. After all, over the 1954-1976 period, real wages and real profits generally increased for many sectors and geographical areas. Indeed, this period is dominated by the sustained postwar economic boom that extended through to the early 1970s. Only in the last couple of years of the period under study was there any apparent systematic shift in this pattern. Even the significant parameter result for has some ambiguity. The positive sign on the estimated parameter indicates that, as profits increase relative to wages, so too does the demand for labor. Previously it was noted that real profits by themselves are significant determinants of the demand for labor in that industry and state. Thus both results may in fact measure the same phenomenon: the demand for labor is sensitive to the flow of profits. It is nevertheless striking that the relationship is significant for 's electrical and electronics industry. This state and industry has in the past been dominated by the automobile industry (principally as a component/input manufacturer), with many similar labor relations practices very high wages, stable workforces, and a great deal of union organizing. 6 Conclusions Many economic development agencies in the USA are significantly involved in stimulating the local demand for labor. Although the policies and practices vary from state to state, two types of policies can be identified. The first could be thought of as an input-cost subsidy approach, wherein the logic of conventional neoclassical theory is followed. Under the assumption that firms operate in a competitive price environment, any policy that reduces the costs of production, like wage subsidies, would presumably stimulate the demand for labor as firms' commodities become more competitive. The evidence presented here did not support this supposition, except in two cases, the textile industry in and in [which confirms Tannenwald's (1982) case-study findings]. For states where textiles and electronics have been growing, it is apparent that the cost of labor is not the crucial constraint on labor demand. Furthermore, it was apparent that wage interdependence may exist in states' growth industries, leading to short run increases in the demand for labor [empirical evidence for the theoretical propositions developed in Clark (1981)]. One explanation of this result could be that prices do not perform their allocative function, as suggested by neoclassical theory, in many industries. In fact, prices of commodities and labor are quite sticky in the short run, implying that quantity adjustment is crucial. However, when the relationship between changes in output and changes in the demand for labor was tested, no significant short-run relationship could be established. It is simply not the case that changes in output and employment are closely related in the short run, despite their cross-sectional correlation. The economic base multiplier is on very shaky ground as a predictive tool, let alone as an evaluative method. Thus, the input-cost type of policy cannot be sustained in its most obvious case (real wages as prices) or even in its modified quantity-adjustment case, where, given real wages and commodity prices, output is the crucial lever. The second general type of economic development policy is based on profits. In this paper, evidence was presented that confirms the logic of this approach. For the electronics industry in three of the four states, it is gross real profits that determine the demand for labor. Notice, however, that profits were measured before taxes and were significant only as a stream of revenue. When the demand for labor was related to profits on capital invested, no significant relationship was observed. A related test, that of the significance of changes in the distribution of income between capital and labor for changes in the demand for labor, was found to be generally insignificant.

Labor demand and economic development policy 55 For an economic development agency contemplating these results, one thing stands clear. If gross profits can be stimulated, then so can the local demand for labor. But this implies quite stark public-sector distributional consequences which may not be politically palatable. Acknowledgements. Thanks to the W F Milton Fund for financial support for computer analysis. The PhD program in Urban Planning at Harvard University provided funds for a research assistant, Takatoshi Tabuchi. Ron McQuaid and John Whiteman of Harvard University and Meric Gertler of the University of Toronto generously provided comments and advice on a previous draft. This paper was presented to a seminar group at the ORL-Institute of the Federal Institute of Technology, Zurich, Switzerland, June 1983. Thanks to Dr Beat Hotz-Hart of the ORL for his Institute's support and the German Marshall Fund of the USA for a travel award. Any errors or omissions are the author's responsibility. References Baily M N, 1977, "On the theory of layoffs and unemployment" Econometrica 45 1043-1064 Ball R R, St Cyr E, 1966, "Short term employment functions in British manufacturing industry" Review of Economic Studies 33 179-207 Beach C M, MacKinnon J G, 1978, "A maximum likelihood procedure for regression with autocorrelated errors" Econometrica 46 51-58 Browne L E, Mieszkowski P, Syron R F, 1980, "Regional investment patterns" New England Economic Review July/August issue, pages 5-13 Clark G L, 1981, "The employment relation and spatial division of labor: a hypothesis" Annals of the Association of American Geographers 71 412-424 Clark G L, 1983, "Fluctuations and rigidities in local labor markets, Part 1: Theory and evidence" Environment and Planning A 15 165-185 Clark G L, 1984, "Does inflation vary between cities?" Environment and Planning A 16 forthcoming Department of Commerce, various years Census of Manufactures (US Government Printing Office, Washington, DC) Department of Labor, 1982 Supplement to Producer Prices and Price Indices Data for 1981 (Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington, DC) Gertler M, 1983 Capital Dynamics and Regional Development PhD thesis, Urban Planning Program, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA Gordon R J, 1981, "Output fluctuations and gradual price adjustment" Journal of Economic Literature 19 493-530 Hall R E, 1980, "Employment fluctuations and wage rigidity" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity issue 1, pages 91-123 Hamermesh D S, 1975, "Interdependence in the labor market" Economica 42 420-429 Hazledine T, 1978, "New specifications for employment and hours functions" Economica 45 179-193 Hazledine T, 1981, "Employment functions' and the demand for labor in the short run" in The Economics of the Labour Market Eds Z Hornstein, J Grice, A Webb (HMSO, London) pp 149-181 Nickell S J, 1978, "Fixed costs, employment, and labor demand over the cycle" Economica 45 329-345 Peel D A, Walker I, 1978, "Short run employment functions excess supply and the speed of adjustment: a note" Economica 45 195-202 President's National Urban Policy Report, 1982 (US Government Printing Office, Washington, DC) Rowthorn R, 1980 Capitalism Conflict and Inflation (Lawrence and Wishart, London) Tannenwald R, 1982, "Are wage and training subsidies cost effective? some evidence from the new jobs tax credit" New England Economic Review September/October issue, pages 25-34 Vernez G, Vaughan R, Burright B, Coleman S, 1977, "Regional cycles and employment effects of public works investments" R-2052-EDA, Rand Corporation, Main Street, Santa Monica, CA