Loss Leader or Low Margin Leader? Advertising

Similar documents
Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Endogenous market transparency and product differentiation

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

EconS Bertrand Competition

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice

Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1

Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm.

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy

URL:

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Volume Discounts, Loss Leaders, and Competition for More Profitable Customers

EconS Asymmetric Information

EconS Vertical Di erentiation

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models

Two Lectures on Information Design

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

EconS Bundling and Tying

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

A note on acquisition of complements in a vertically differentiated market

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

P rofit t (1 + i) t. V alue = t=0

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

AN ASCENDING AUCTION FOR INTERDEPENDENT VALUES: UNIQUENESS AND ROBUSTNESS TO STRATEGIC UNCERTAINTY. Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris

SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY. Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

Consumer Basket Information, Supermarket Pricing and Loyalty Card Programs

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

MEMO. 1 Single-Product Monopolist. 1.1 Inverse Elasticity Rule. Date: October Subject: Notes from Tirole on Monopoly Ch.1: pp

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

The Retail Space-Exchange Problem with. Pricing and Space Allocation Decisions 1

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors. Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Multiproduct Intermediaries

Bonanno, G. (1987), Location Choice, Product Proliferation and Entry Deterrence, Review of

NET Institute*

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Part III. Sources of market power. Chapter 6. Advertising and related marketing strategies

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations

The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

Reciprocal dumping with Bertrand competition

Linking Reputations: The Signaling and Feedback Effects of Umbrella Branding

Incentives for environmental R&D

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 2

Faculty & Research. Working Paper Series. Strategic Segmentation Using Outlet Malls. by A. Coughlan and D. Soberman

Entry and Merger Policy

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 27 Monopoly

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ

Informative Advertisement of Partial Compatible Products

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

Monopoly. The single seller or firm referred to as a monopolist or monopolistic firm. Characteristics of a monopolistic industry

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

Customer Data, Consumer Myopia and Investment in Targeting Technology

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game

BUYER POWER AND EXCLUSION IN VERTICALLY RELATED MARKETS.

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Competition in Two-Sided Markets

Retention Strategies in a Switching Cost Model

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

E ciency Wages. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

Advertising Competition in Retail Markets

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Search and Categorization

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Managing Price Promotions. Within a Product Line

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

TRANSPORTATION PROBLEM AND VARIANTS

Centre for Development Economics

Transcription:

Loss Leader or Low Margin Leader? Advertising And The Degree of Product Di erentiation Witness Simbanegavi y 18 August 008 Abstract This paper isolates the conditions that give rise to loss leader pricing. I show that for su ciently low distance between rms, the advertised good is priced below cost irrespective of whether rms advertise the same or di erent products. Instead, if products are su ciently di erentiated, loss leader pricing may result only if rms advertise the low reservation value product, otherwise the advertised good is a low margin leader. Thus, whether the advertised good is a loss leader or a low margin leader is primarily a function of the extent of di erentiation between competing rms. Thus the loss leader story is not driven by the fact that rms advertise the same products but rather, by the fact that rms carry similar products. Keywords: Informative advertising, loss leader, low margin leader, product di erentiation JEL Classi cation: L13; L15; M37 1 Introduction Advertising provides information to consumers and thus help direct them to the rms where they potentially get the greatest surplus. In this way, both consumers and rms potentially bene t from advertising (Bagwell and Ramey; Financial support from ERSA and the UCT Block Grants is gratefully ackowledged. All remaining errors are mine. y School of Economics, University of Cape Town, Private Bag Rondebosch, 7701 Cape Town, South Africa. Witness.Simbanegavi@uct.ac.za 1

1994a, 1994b). For this reason, the relationship between advertising and prices and advertising and pro ts has long been a subject of great interest to economists and thus has spawned a huge literature. 1 In the case of multiproduct rms, a common occurrence is that rms advertise some, but not all their products. Indeed, both empirical evidence (Milyo and Waldfogel (1999), Walters and MacKenzie (1988)) and casual observation support the hypothesis that rms advertise only a subset of their products. This raises new and interesting implications for rm pricing: for example, the pervasive issue of "leader" pricing can only be studied for multiproduct rms. In this setting, advertising can be used both as a source of information for consumers and also as a tool to extract more consumer surplus through a careful selection of the products to advertise and astute pricing of the advertised and the non-advertised products. The advertised good could be sold at a loss (loss-leader good) or the rm could simply reduce margins on the advertised good but still sell at a pro t (low margin leader good). 3 This paper attempts to understand the conditions that lead to the advertised good being priced below cost (loss leader) or above cost (low margin leader). This question is important because whether rms price above or below cost will have implications for rm behaviour. Indeed, casual observation 1 Important contributions include Benham (197), Butters (1977) and Grossman and Shapiro (1984). A common nding in this literature is the negative association between advertising and prices (Benham, 197; Grossman and Shapiro, 1984; Bagwell and Ramey, 1994a, 1994b; Milyo and Waldfogel, 1999; among others). There are several reasons why rms may want to advertise only a handful of their products (Ellison, 005; pages 607-611). One obvious reason is that many rms, especially retail rms, carry hundreds if not thousands of products and therefore printing an encyclopaedia (read brochure) to communicate all the prices would be very costly and even more, the intended readers may be put o by the shear size of the brochure. Another possible rationale for advertising only a subset of the products is the desire of rms to create some ambiguity in the minds of consumers which the rms can exploit. The failure by rms to avail all the information to consumers generates a need for consumer search. However if search is costly, either consumer search will be limited or consumers will solely rely on the little information provided by the rms. In either case, rms can potentially exploit the ambiguity resulting from the less than full search. 3 A good is termed a loss (low margin) leader if it is deliberately priced below marginal cost (low but above marginal cost) in order to attract consumers to the advertising store and hence pomote sales of higher margin products. According to Investopedia, "A classic example [of a loss leader] is that of razor blades. Companies like Gillette essentially give their razor units away for free, knowing that customers will have to buy their replacement blades, which is where the company makes all of its pro t. Another example is Microsoft s Xbox video game system, which was sold at a loss of more than $100 per unit to create more potential to pro t from the sale of higher-margin video games." (investopedia.com)

suggest that when rms sell a product below cost, they try to avoid selling large quantities of the loss leader product. Alternatively, the rms restrict the quantities that each individual consumer can purchase at any one point (Hess and Gerstner (1987: 358)). This incentive to restrict quantities is however weak in the case of low margin leader pricing since every unit sold generates a positive pro t. The central questions are: Why are the leader products sometimes priced below marginal cost (sold at a loss) and sometimes priced above marginal cost? In other words, when or under what conditions should we expect the leader good to be sold at a loss? In particular, what is the role of the extent of di erentiation between the competing rms in the loss leader - low margin leader story? I also study the implications of leader pricing for rm pro ts. I consider two rms, each selling two products but only advertising a single product. The rms are located at the end points of a linear city of unit length. Consumers (who are uniformly distributed on the unit interval) are assumed to be completely uninformed about prices and rm locations (products) unless they are reached by advertising. In other words, I am assuming that search costs are prohibitive so that consumers do not actively engage in information acquisition activities. Following Butters (1977), advertising messages are randomly distributed over consumers. I show that loss-leader pricing crucially depends on how strong competition between the rms is. The strength of competition between the rms is a function of both advertising and the degree of product di erentiation. For su ciently low distance between the competing rms, the advertised good is priced below cost, irrespective of whether rms advertise the same or di erent products. If instead products are su ciently di erentiated, the advertised good is priced above marginal cost. It turns out that the extent of marketing is not a ected by the choice of the advertised product. The advertising intensity is the same whether rms advertise similar or di erent products. Equally, pro ts are not a ected by the choice of the advertised product. Hence, in equilibrium rms will randomly select the good to advertise. The intuition for this result is as follows: Since all consumers have the same reservation value for each product and the reservation value is perfectly known to all (consumers and rms), the advertised price provides a su cient statistic for the consumer s expected surplus. As a result, 3

it does not matter for the consumer s visitation decision whether rms advertise the same or di erent products. Closely related are Lal and Matutes (1994) who study price and advertising by multiproduct rms and Ellison (005) who studies a vertically di erentiated goods model in which rms only advertise the low quality good. However, neither Lal and Matutes nor Ellison explicitly model the advertising decision. Generally, when rms advertise, the post advertising equilibrium is characterized by a market partitioned into segments of variably informed consumers and this has additional implications for rm pricing. Even more important, our objective and those of Lal and Matutes and Ellison are quite distinct. Neither of these studies distinguish between loss leader and low margin leader pricing. Moreover, both Lal and Matutes and Ellison only consider the case where the market is fully covered. However, as Soberman (004) shows, for some constellations of the di erentiation parameter, some informed consumers nd it pro table not to purchase. Also related is Bagwell and Ramey (1994a) who study dissipative advertising. They show that "ostensibly uninformative" advertising may bring about coordination economies. These coordination economies manifest themselves in the form of greater demand to the rm and lower prices to consumers. Thus, they nd a negative association between advertising and price. We di er with them in several ways: First, in our model, advertising is (directly) informative whereas in theirs, it is not. Second, whereas in our model rms advertise only a subset of the products they sell, in theirs, they neither advertise the prices nor the products they sell. Rather, rms advertise for instance, their size. Also, in Bagwell and Ramey, product di erentiation is unimportant. Closest to the present study is Hess and Gerstner (1987) who study the e ects of leader pricing on store pro ts and market outcomes. However, unlike the present study, they do not distinguish between loss leader and low margin leader pricing. As we argued above, this distinction is important since it has implications for rm strategy. The paper is organized as follows. Section sets out the model. Section 3 examines price and advertising when di erentiation is low. Section 4 studies price and advertising when di erentiation is high and Section 5 concludes the paper. 4

Model and Preliminaries.1 Model Consider a linear city of unit length served by two rms, rm 0 and rm 1; where each rm s identity corresponds to its location. Each rm sells two products, product 1 and product which are either compliments or independent but not substitutes. However, across rms, the products are substitutes. 4 Firms advertise only one of their products. Following Butters (1977), advertising messages are randomly assigned over consumers. Let i denote the advertising (ad) reach of rm i; i = 0; 1: The cost of reaching fraction i of consumers is a i =; a > t=: 5 Each good is produced at a constant marginal cost, c; and rms simultaneously and non-cooperatively choose prices and advertising intensities to maximize pro ts. There is no entry or exit and there are no xed costs. Consumers (who are rational) are uniformly distributed on [0; 1] according to taste. That is, each consumer is identi ed by a point on the unit interval that corresponds to her most preferred brand. I assume that consumers are completely unaware of the existence of rms or products unless they are reached by advertising. I also assume that search costs are prohibitive so that consumers do not actively engage in information acquisition activities. Each informed consumer buys at most one unit of each product and uninformed consumers stay out of the market. 6 A unit of good 1() generates gross surplus of v 1 (v ) and consumers incur a shopping cost of t per unit distance. If an informed consumer chooses not to purchase, they get zero surplus. Transportation costs are applied to both goods (bundling) the decision to visit a particular store is based on the expected surplus from buying at that store.. Timing The timing of the actions is as follows: In stage 1, rms simultaneously decide on the advertised price and the advertising level, and send out the ads. In stage 4 Think of, for example, two retail stores which specialize one in Philips products (TV and video camera) and the other in Sony products (TV and video camera). 5 The parameter t measures the transportation cost incurred by consumers when visiting a store. 6 Since there are no repeat purchases, consumers have no loyalty to any particular vendor. 5

, consumers receive ads and make purchase plans based on the advertised price and the expected price of the non-advertised good. At the same time, rms simultaneously decide on the prices of the unadvertised goods. Lastly, in stage 3, purchases are made and payo s are realized..3 Preliminaries The objective of this section is to derive the demands faced by the rms. Observe that given the advertising intensities 0 and 1 ; the market is delineated as follows. Fraction 0 1 of consumers receive advertising messages from both rms (fully informed); fraction i 1 j ; i; j = 0; 1; j 6= i receive ads from rm i but not rm j (partially informed) and fraction (1 0 ) (1 1 ) receive no ads from either rm (uninformed). I assume that 0 1 is large enough so that rms nd it worthwhile to compete for the fully informed consumers. 7 To start with, we need to derive the prices of the unadvertised products. To do so, suppose rm i advertises good k and rm j advertises good `; so that p ik and p j` are the advertised prices for rms i and j respectively. Let p E i` and pe jk denote the expected prices of the non-advertised products at rms i and j; respectively, k; ` = 1;. I assume that whenever rms advertise the same good rational consumers expect the rms to charge the same price; that is p E i` = pej`:8 Given the consumers beliefs/expectations, what prices will the rms actually charge for the non-advertised products? To answer this question, we consider what happens in the second stage where, having decided on the advertising level and advertised prices in rst stage, rms simultaneously decide on the non-advertised prices. 9 In the second stage, having committed itself to the advertised price p ik and advertising level i ; rm i s problem is to choose the non-advertised price, p i`; to maximize (p i` c) D i p ik ; p j`; p E i`; pe jk ; i; j. Observe that the demand that rm i faces is independent of p i`; the non- 7 If this assumption is not satis ed, a symmetric equilibrium may not exist as at least one rm may nd it pro table to charge a high price and only serve its captive consumers. 8 If the rms advertise the same good, say good k; then there are three possible con gurations of the expected prices of good `; the non-advertised good: Either p E i` = pe j`; pe i` < pe j` or p E i` > pe j`: Since the non-advertised products are (physically) similar and the consumers are rational, the most reasonable beliefs that consumers can have are that p E i` = pe j`: Hence the assumption. 9 Stage 3 is super uous. It is only meant to close the model. 6

advertised price. 10 Since demand is determined by the advertised prices and the expected prices p E i` and pe jk, it follows that pro ts are maximized by ensuring that all visiting consumers buy the non-advertised good, that is, by setting p i` = p E i`; i = 0; 1: As for consumers, the decision to visit a store is based on expected surplus. The uncertainty here derives from the fact that one of the goods they anticipate purchasing is not advertised and, as a result, the price is not known with certainty. A fully informed consumer located at x (0; 1) gets expected surplus v k + v` p ik p E i` tx buying from rm i and surplus v k + v` p j` p E jk t (1 x) buying from rm j. 11 Thus, rm i faces demand D full i = i j p j` + p E jk p ik p E i` + t =t; j 6= i from the fully informed consumers. Partially informed consumers purchase whenever it is individually rational to do so. Let y i denote the location of a consumer who receives only rm i s ad(s). Buying yields surplus v k +v` p ik p E i` ty i. Given the consumers outside option, rm i faces demand D partial i = i 1 j vk + v` p ik p E i` =t from the partially informed consumers. So what is p E i`? I use a standard argument to deduce this. Observe that in equilibrium consumers expectations for the non-advertised price must coincide with the actual price charged by rm i for this good: As a matter of fact, in this model, if rms did not advertise at all, the market would unravel for the simple reason that consumers would foresee themselves being held to the reservation prices once search costs are sunk (Lal and Matutes, 1994; Bagwell, 005; p.75). Therefore by extension, rational consumers must anticipate being held to the reservation value of the non-advertised good once they are in the store. It follows therefore that p E i` = v`; i = 0; 1; ` = 1; : Hence, p i` = p E i` = v`: Putting the two paragraphs above together, we have that in the general case, rm i faces the demand: D i = i 1 j (vk p ik ) =t + j (p j` p ik + v k v` + t) =t ; i 6= j: (1) 10 Of course the actual quantity demanded of the non-advertised good depends on p i`: 11 The meaning of "fully informed" as used here is in respect to the advertised prices only. A fully informed consumer is one who receives advertising messages from both rms and hence is aware (fully informed) of the advertised prices at both stores. Prices of the non-advertised products can only be discovered upon visiting a store. 7

If rms advertise the same good however, the demand reduces to D i = i 1 j (vk p ik ) =t + j (p j` p ik + t) =t : (1 ) For what follows, I make the following assumption: Assumption A1. c + p at < min fv 1 ; v g : Assumption A1 ensures that in equilibrium consumers visit the stores in the single product case. If c + p at is greater than or equal to min fv 1 ; v g ; visiting consumers get negative surplus since they incur positive transportation costs and hence no consumer would visit a store. 1 3 Low di erentiation In this section I study the equilibrium pricing and advertising strategies of multiproduct rms when di erentiation is low. That is, I assume that the market is fully covered, i.e., the consumer who travels the furthest distance (unit interval) nds it pro table to purchase). The market is covered when v k p ik +t: 13 This says that the gross surplus from purchasing a unit of good k at rm i exceeds the total cost of purchasing this good at rm i for the consumer who travels the furthest distance. It follows therefore that all consumers who receive at least one ad from rm i will make a purchase. That is, ey i v k p ik t = 1: The demand function (1) reduces to D i = i 1 j + j (v k v` + p j` p ik + t) =t under low di erentiation. 1 This assumption is implicit in the analyses of, for example, Bagwell (005; Section. 5), Tirole (1988; Chap. 7) and Soberman (004). 13 Ideally, full market coverage requires that v k + v` p ik p E i` t 0: However, since p E i` = v`; this condition reduces to v k p ik t 0: Put di erently, because the non-advertised good yields zero expected surplus in equilibrium, the non-advertised price does not a ect the visitation decision of consumers. 8

Price and Advertising Assume that rm i advertises good k and rm j advertises good `; i; j = 0; 1; i 6= j and k; ` = 1;. Then, rm i s pro t is: i j (v k v` + p j` p ik + t) i = max (p ik + v` c) i 1 j + fp ik ; i g t a i Observe that our formulation allows for the rms to advertise the same product. In this case, v k = v` and rm i s objective function becomes i j (p jk p ik + t) a i = max (p ik + v` c) i 1 j + i : fp ik ; i g t Taking the rst order conditions of () with respect to p ik and i and equating them to zero gives and @ i @p ik = t + p j` j + (c p ik t + v k v`) j = 0; i; j = 1; ; j 6= i; (3) () @ i @ i = 0: 14 (4) Equation (3) gives the relation between prices and advertising. One of the features that distinguishes the present model from the models of Lal and Matutes (1994), Ellison (005) and Hess and Gerstner (1987) is that in the present model, consumers are ex-post heterogeneous: some receive ads and some don t. In other words, although all consumers are ex-ante uninformed, expost they are di erentially informed some are fully informed of all advertised prices, others are only partially informed and yet others are not informed at all. The Lemma below characterizes the relationship between the advertised prices and the advertising intensity when di erentiation is low. Lemma 1 Let t < (v 1 + v c) =: 15 There exists a negative association between advertising and prices. That is, @p ik @ < 0; i = 0; 1; k = 1; : Proof. Solving the rst order conditions @ i =@p ik = 0 and @ j =@p j` = 0 for 14 @ i @ i = (p ik p j` c + t v k + v`) p ik + v ` + p j`c ct + cv k p j`v` cv` + tv` v k v` j tv` + 4ct p ik t + at i = 0 15 This is the condition for low di erentation. See appendix for derivation. : 9

p ik and p j` as functions of the advertising intensities and the parameters yields p ik = p j` = 4t 3 j t 3 j + t + c t 3 v` ; i + 4t + c t v 3 k : i The advertised prices are clearly decreasing in the advertising intensity. When di erentiation is low, there is a negative association between the advertised price and advertising level irrespective of whether rms advertise the same or di erent products. The intuition can be framed in two ways: in terms of demand elasticity and in terms of business stealing. First, when differentiation is low, demand by partially informed consumers is price inelastic while demand by fully informed consumers is price sensitive. Because an increase in the advertising intensity raises the share of fully informed and thus price sensitive consumers, it raises the demand elasticity and hence lead to lower equilibrium prices for the advertised good. 16. Second, a rm that advertises more will have more consumers in the competitor s backyard aware of its product. In order to induce these consumers to ditch the nearby rm in favour of the distant rm, the distant rm must compensate these consumers for the additional search costs they incur. Ideally the rm would want to price discriminate and give targeted discounts to these consumers (consumers in the competitor s backyard). However, because advertising cannot be targeted in the present model (i.e., price discrimination is not feasible), the rm can only compensate these consumers by charging lower (advertised) prices and thus assuring them greater expected surplus. The nding of a negative association between advertising and prices is quite common in both the theoretical literature (Grossman and Shapiro, 1984; Bagwell and Ramey, 1994a, 1994b; Soberman, 004; among others) and empirical literature (Benham, 197; Milyo and Waldfogel, 1999; among others) on advertising. Unlike the present study however, Grossman and Shapiro (1984) and Soberman (004) study single product rms while Bagwell and Ramey (1994a, 1994b) on the other hand only consider non-price ("uninformative") 16 In a symmetric advertising equilibrium, rm i s demand is given by D i = (1 ) + (v k v` + p j` p ik + t) and the elasticity of demand is " i p t ik = @Di p ik @p ik D i = p ik t+p j` p ik t+v k : Now, @"i p v` @ = p ik t > 0. (t+p j` p ik t+v k v`) 10

advertising. We now derive the equilibrium price and advertising levels. To begin with, suppose that both rms advertise the same good, say good k: Then, solving the rst order conditions for p ik ; p jk ; i and j, noting that k = ` gives: p ik = p jk = c + p at v` (5) i = j = = 1 + p a=t : (6) Substituting (5) and (6) into the rms objective function () noting that k = ` yields = a= 1 + p a=t : (7) It can easily be shown that p ik = p jk < c; so that the advertised good is a loss leader. 17 In other words, when rms advertise the same good, price competition is so intense that rms advertise prices below marginal cost. We next consider the equilibrium price, advertising and pro t con gurations when rms advertise di erent products. The question here is whether advertising di erent products softens price competition. One is tempted to answer this question in the a rmative as advertising di erent products potentially reduces comparison shopping. To this e ect, let the rms advertise di erent products so that rm i advertises good k and rm j advertises good `: Then, solving the rst order conditions given in (3) and (4) for p ik ; p jk ; i and j yields: p ik = c + p at v` (8) p j` = c + p at v k (9) i = j = = 1 + p a=t (10) and = a= 1 + p a=t : (11) Using similar arguments as above, it can easily be shown that p ik < c and p j` < c: That is, the advertised prices are below marginal cost even when rms advertise di erent products. 17 From (5), p k = c + p at v` = c + p at (v` c) : Clearly, p k < c if and only if p at (v` c) < 0 and p at (v` c) < 0 if and only if c + p at < v`. But this is nothing other than Assumption 1. Hence, we conclude that indeed p k < c. 11

Equations (5) (11) and the preceding discussion can be summarized in the following proposition. Proposition Let t < (v 1 + v c) =: (i). Irrespective of whether rms advertise the same or di erent products, the advertised product is priced below marginal cost when di erentiation is low. That is, p k = c + p at v` < c; k; ` = 1; ; k 6= `: (ii). The advertised prices are asymmetric when rms advertise di erent products but the extent of marketing and pro ts is exactly the same as when rms advertise the same product. Since consumers do not actively search in this model, market shares are determined solely by the advertised prices. Holding the rm s advertising reach constant, the lower the advertised price the higher the consumers expected surplus and hence the greater the likelihood that each ad received results in a sale. When rms advertise the low reservation value good, competition for market share is tougher as the rm that succeeds in attracting more consumers will sell more units at the higher non-advertised price. The larger the di erence between the reservation values the greater the incentive to undercut. Given low di erentiation, this leads to a much lower equilibrium advertised price. When rms advertise the high reservation price good instead, there are two opposing e ects. On the one hand, low di erentiation induces rms to compete more aggressively for market share (products are similar). On the other hand, rms realize that visiting consumers will pay a lower (reservation) price on the non-advertised good and this restrains the aggression. However, the low di erentiation e ect dominates and rms advertise prices below marginal cost in either case. Examples of markets in which di erentiation is generally low are the grocery retail market and the liquor retail market. Supermarkets, for instance, sell products that are almost (if not exactly) physically similar. Competition therefore is mainly on prices. Because they carry similar products, consumers do not have a strong inclination to buy from one particular store as opposed to another and, as a result, price competition is intense. Moreover, when rms advertise similar products, there is even more downward pressure on the advertised prices since advertising similar products facilitates comparison shopping. The presence of non-advertised products further exacerbates price competition 1

since rms anticipate earning higher pro ts from the sale of the higher margin non-advertised products. This intense price competition results in rms o ering loss leaders. Part (ii) of the proposition is straight forward. The incentives to attract consumers to the store are driven by the expected pro t from the sale of the non-advertised good. When rm i advertises the low reservation value good (say good 1), the incentive to attract consumers is greatest as each visiting consumer will pay v (which is higher). Consequently, rm i advertises a lower price in the hope of increasing store tra c. In contrast rm j, which advertises the high reservation value good (good ), advertises a higher price. This is meant to compensate for the fact that visiting consumers will only pay v 1 ; which is lower. Thus the rm advertising the high reservation value good will have a higher advertised price. Consumers understand this and thus will not be fooled by rm i s low advertised price 18. The above result allows us to rationalize the "surprising" nding of Walters and MacKenzie (1988) that, in retail markets, loss-leader pricing fails to stimulate store tra c and hence is unpro table. Walters and MacKenzie interpret this nding as "pointing to the fact that locational convenience and overall price perceptions are more important determinants of patronage than weekly specials" (p. 60). I turn their explanation on its head. Because di erentiation is typically low in the retail sector (which they studied), weekly specials are a crucial determinant of visitation 19. As a result, a rm that o ers such specials would substantially increase its market share if rivals would not follow suit. Realizing this, rms always try to match price cutting by rivals and this enable them to maintain their market shares. This is a typical prisoner s dilemma. A rm that succeeds in undercutting its rival can greatly increase its pro ts since it then faces a large demand and sells the non-advertised good at its reservation price. On the other hand, if both rms undercut (symmetrically), then each rm maintains its market share. In this sense, undercutting is a (weakly) dominant strategy for each 18 Because rms cannot commit to not eece consumers once search costs are sunk, they have to o er price discounts as a way to commit to leave consumers su cient surplus to make the shopping trip worthwhile. 19 When I asked him why they advertised so frequently in the newspaper (weekly basis), the manager of a large non-food retail chain in Cape Town candidly responded "If we did not advertise, instead of 8000 customers over the weekend, we would only get about 4000. So you can see why". 13

individual rm. However, this strategy does not maximize joint pro ts and rms settle for an equilibrium with low advertised prices but with the same level of demand. 0 This makes loss-leader pricing appear as if it were less important. 1 I nd the present argument more convincing, for if price specials were unimportant, why are retailers "placing greater emphasis on hotter price specials"? (Lal and Matutes, 1994; p. 345). 4 High di erentiation (Regime H) In the previous section, I examined price and advertising strategies by multiproduct rms when di erentiation is low; that is, v k p ik t > 0; where p ik is the advertised price. For such parameter constellations, all consumers who receive at least one advertising message from rm i will make a purchase as they are guaranteed positive surplus from doing so. However, as Soberman (004) notes, for some parameter constellations, some informed consumers may optimally choose not to purchase. This happens whenever the parameter values are such that t= < v k p ik < t: This is the condition for high di erentiation (Soberman, 004) or the condition for incomplete (market) coverage (Hamilton, 004). In this section, I consider the case when di erentiation is high. Di erentiation is said to be high if, given the prices, at least one partially informed consumer does not make a purchase. In the double inequality above, the condition: v k p ik < t tells us that the consumer located at rm j but who only receives advertising messages from rm i would get negative surplus were they to travel to rm i since the consumer surplus is less than the transportation costs. Hence, this consumer will not purchase, even though they are informed. 0 That loss leader pricing does not increase demand in our model is a consequence of the unit demands assumption. With downward sloping demands, total demand can increase in equilibrium but market shares will not. 1 Since competitors always match price cutting by rivals, the full e ect of loss leader pricing on store tra c and pro ts is never realized in equilibrium. This gives a biased reading of the importance of loss leader pricing. This suggests a di erent empirical method to test for the e ect of loss leader pricing counterfactual analysis. What would be the e ect on pro ts of rm i were competitors to not reciprocate when rm i lowers its price? I asked a manager of a major food retail chain why they advertise and the answer I got pretty much con rms the intuition above. She responded that "it s the competition thing. If we don t frequently advertise to inform our consumers of the specials we have they will go to those stores that advertise". 14

The other condition: t= < v k p ik tells us that a consumer located in between the two rms who travels distance no more that 1= to go to rm i will purchase whenever they receive at least one advertising message. These conditions give the degree of product di erentiation compatible with high di erentiation. In particular, under high di erentiation, the degree of product di erentiation is such that t t; t v 1 +v c; (v 1+v c) and the demand 3 that rm i faces is given by equation (1) exactly. 3 The objective, as before, is to try and pin down the conditions that cause the leader good (advertised good) to be priced below cost or to be a low margin leader. To proceed, suppose rm i advertises good k and rm j advertises good `; so that the advertised prices are respectively p ik and p j`; k; ` = 1; ; i 6= j: Firm i and rm j s objective functions are then: H i H j = max p ik ; i (p ik + v` = max p j`; j (p j` + v k c) i c) j 1 j v k p ik t + j p j` + v k p ik v` + t t (1 i ) v` p j` p ik + v` p j` v k + t + t i t a i (1) a j : (13) Observe that our formulation allows for the case where rms advertise the same good, good k. In this case, rm i s problem reduces to H i = max p ik ; i (p ik + v` c) i 1 j v k p ik t p jk p ik + t a i + j t : (14) Consider rst the case when the rms advertise the same good. Di erentiating with respect to p ik and then solving for p ik (at the symmetric equilibrium: p ik = p jk = p k and i = j = ) one gets: 4 p k = [4c + (v k v`) + (t c (v k v`)) ] = (4 3) : (15) 3 In regime H; we have that t= < v k p < t: The rst inequality, evaluated at the full information (highest) price, gives the upper bound to regime H while the second inequality gives the lower bound. Evaluating this condition at p H 1F = t + c v gives t v1+v (v1+v c) c; 3 : 4 Due to complexity of the rst order conditions, it is not possible to solve the rst order @ i @p ik @ j @p j` conditions: = 0; @i @ = 0; = 0 and @j i @ = 0 simultaneously for p ik ; p j j`; i and j : Hence we contend with analysing the relationship between the advertising levels and the advertised prices. See also Soberman (004). 15

Equation (15) gives the equilibrium price as a function of the advertising intensity 5 : A careful analysis of (15) shows that loss-leader pricing is possible under high di erentiation. More precisely, let k = ` so that rms advertise the same product. Then, Proposition 3 Let t t; t and let t t; t be implicitly de ned by: p k (t () ; ; v; c) = c; where p k is the advertised price, k = 1;. (i). If v k < v` and t (t; t ) ; then p k < c and (ii). If t > t and/ or v k > v`; then p k > c: Proof. Let rms advertise good k so that p k is the advertised price. Notice that (from (15)) @p k =@t > 0: Since t > t = v 1+v c; it follows that p k = 4c+t c+(v i v j ) (v i v j ) > p 4 3 k j t=t p k = c + (v k v`) ; k; ` = 1; ; k 6= `: If v k < v`; advertising good k (the low reservation price good) gives p k < c: Thus, for t! t + and for jv k v`j large, p k < c: However, if v k > v`; then advertising good k (the high reservation price good) gives p k > c and hence p k > c: The proposition states that loss leader pricing is possible under high di erentiation but only if two conditions are met; namely, that rms advertise the low reservation price good and the di erentiation parameter t is su ciently low. If either of these conditions is violated, then we have low margin leader pricing (price exceeds marginal cost ). Observe that under high di erentiation, products are less similar and therefore price di erences have to be large to induce consumers to switch to the distant supplier. However, for t! t + ; most partially informed consumers make a purchase and thus competition for market share can be intense. 6 A higher non-advertised price adds to the incentives to compete vigorously. Thus, when rms advertise the low reservation price good and the market is almost fully covered, undercutting may result in prices below cost. However, when products are su ciently di erentiated (t > t ), the incentive to undercut is reduced. Hence, for large t; rms advertise prices above marginal cost when they advertise the low valuation good. When rms 5 In contrast to Lemma 1, the relation between price and advertising is positive when differentiation is high (Soberman, 004). When products are su ciently di erentiated, demand is more elastic in the presence of informational product di erentiation. Higher advertising, by increasing the share of fully informed consumers, reduces overall demand elasticity and thus allow rms to charge higher prices. 6 Demand elasticity under high di erentiation is given by: " p = p ik ( ) p ik +v k +p j`+p ik +t v k v` and @"i p @t = @D i @p ik p ik D i = p ik ( ) (v k p ik +p j`+p ik +t v k v`) < 0: In other words, demand is more elastic for low t. This makes price competition more intense leading to lower prices. 16

advertise the high reservation price good however, it is never optimal to advertise prices below marginal cost. The fact that di erentiation is high (products are less similar) and the fact that the non-advertised (reservation) price is lower when rms advertise the high reservation price good both induce rms to advertise higher prices. I next consider the case when rms advertise di erent products. As argued earlier, advertising di erent products potentially has additional implications as it reduces comparison shopping. Di erentiating (1) and respectively (13) with respect to p ik and respectively p j` and solving simultaneously for p k and p`; k 6= ` yields, 7 p k = [4c + (v k v`) + (t c (v k v`)) ] = (4 3) (16) p` = [4c + (v` v k ) + (t c (v` v k )) = (4 3)] (17) It turns out that the equilibrium advertised prices are exactly the same as when rms advertise the same product (observe that the expressions for p k in (15) and (16) are identical). It is therefore immediate from the proof of Proposition 3 that loss leader pricing is possible only for the rm advertising the low reservation value good. It follows therefore that if rm i advertises good k while rm j advertises good `; and good k happens to be the low reservation value good, then for t! t + and for jv k v`j large, p k < c: That is, loss leader pricing is possible, depending on the extent of product di erentiation. However, for rm j; which advertises good `; p j` j t=t = c v k v` : Since v k < v`; it follows that the lowest price that can be charged by rm j exceeds the marginal cost. Thus, rm j s advertised good is a low margin leader independent of the degree of product di erentiation. The intuition is the same as when rms advertise the same product: the rm advertising the high reservation value good realizes that visiting consumers will only pay a lower (reservation) price for the non-advertised good hence the diminished incentive to lower the advertised price. However, because advertising is necessary for visitation, the asking price has to be below the reservation price. This explains low margin leader pricing. In the present model where advertising is essential for visitation, advertising serves as a commitment device: it guarantees consumers su cient surplus to 7 I suppress subscripts i and j: 17

make the visitation worthwhile (Lal and Matutes, 1994). However, due to competition, rms tend to overcommit. Overcommitment is more pronounced when rms products are more similar as it implies loss leader pricing. When products are su ciently di erent however, the advertised good is a low margin leader. Thus, from Propositions and 3 we can pin down the conditions that give rise to loss leader pricing. Corollary 1 The following conditions are su cient for loss-leader pricing; (i) Low di erentiation and (ii) Firms advertise only a subset of their products. Our nding that advertising di erent products does not soften price competition is somewhat surprising. Intuition suggests that advertising di erent products ought to soften price competition as it makes across rm price comparisons more blurred. It appears the devil is in the model assumptions. Although each rm only advertises one product among its o erings, rational consumers already know the non-advertised prices. The explanation is that in the present model the advertised price is a su cient statistic for the consumer s expected surplus. This is so for two reasons. First, the reservation value of the non-advertised good is the same for all consumers and is perfectly known to both rms and consumers and second, consumers expectations are correct in equilibrium. As a result, it does not matter for the consumer s expected surplus whether rms advertise the same or di erent products. The outcome is as if both goods were advertised. This also explains the invariance property of advertising intensities and pro ts as shown in (6) and (??) and (10) and (11). Hence rms are indi erent as to which good to advertise since the choice doesn t a ect pro ts. 8 The present model provides theoretical support to the ndings of Milyo and Waldfogel (1999). In a study of the e ect of price advertising on prices in the liquor retail market, Milyo and Waldfogel nd that advertising stores substantially cut only the prices of the products they advertise and moreover, that the e ect of price advertising on prices is di erent depending on whether a rival in the vicinity is advertising the same good. Advertised prices are much 8 I conjecture that in a more general setting where reservation values di er among consumers or where rms do not know consumers reservation values for certain, this might no longer be the case. 18

lower if rivals close by are advertising the same good. Proposition above is in agreement with these ndings. Although tough competition for market share leads to advertised prices below cost, the tough price competition does not get (directly) transmitted to the non-advertised products. Instead, the competition is transmitted from the non-advertised products to the advertised products. 5 Concluding Remarks I study price advertising when rms advertise only a subset of their products. I nd some support for the empirical ndings that price advertising a ects advertised and non-advertised prices di erently. I show that the degree of product di erentiation is decisive for loss leader pricing. When di erentiation is low, equilibrium is characterized by loss leader pricing while when products are su ciently di erent, equilibrium is characterized by low margin leader pricing. Based on this analysis, I provide a game theoretic (and coherent) explanation to the nding of Walters and MacKenzie (1988). Assuming that consumers reservation values are known to rms, though standard in the literature, masks potentially interesting dynamics. This assumption, together with rationality, xes the price of the non-advertised good. However, in reality, this is not the case. Future research should consider relaxing this assumption. References [1] Bagwell, Kyle (005), "The Economic Analysis of Advertising", Forthcoming; Handbook of Industrial Organization. [] Bagwell, Kyle and Ramey, Garey (1994), "Coordination Economies, Advertising, and Search Behavior in Retail markets", American Economic Review, 84, 498-517. [3] Bagwell, Kyle and Ramey, Garey (1994), "Advertising and Coordination", Review of Economic Studies, 61, 153-171. 19

[4] Benham, Lee (197), "The E ect of Advertising on the Price of Eyeglasses", Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 337-35. [5] Butters, Gerard R. (1977), "Equilibrium Distributions of Sales and Advertising Prices", Review of Economic Studies, 44, 465-491. [6] DeGraba, Patrick, (006), "The loss leader is a turkey: Targeted discounts from multi-product competitors", International Journal of Industrial Economics, 4, 613-68. [7] Ellison, Glenn (005) "A Model of Add-on Pricing", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 10, 585-638. [8] Grossman, Gene M. and Shapiro, Carl (1984), "Informative Advertising with Di erentiated Products", Review of Economic Studies, 51, 63-81. [9] Hess, James. D and Eitan Gerstner (1987), "Loss leader Pricing and Rain Check Policy", Marketing Science, 6, 358-374. [10] Lal, Rajiv and Matutes, Carmen (1994), "Retail Pricing and Advertising Strategies", Journal of Business, 67, 345-370. [11] Milyo, Je rey and Waldfogel, Joel (1999), "The E ect of Price Advertising on Prices: Evidence in the Wake of 44 Liquormart", American Economic Review, 89, 1081-1096. [1] Simbanegavi, Witness (005), "Equilibrium Pricing When Only Some Goods are Advertised", mimeo. [13] Soberman, David A. (004), "Research Note: Additional Learning and Implications on the Role of Informative Advertising", Management Science, 50, 1744-1750. [14] Tirole, Jean (1988), "The Theory of Industrial Organization", MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. [15] Walters, Rockney G. and MacKenzie, Scott B. (1988), "A Structural Equation Analysis of the Impact of Price Promotions on Store Performance", Journal of Marketing Research, 5, 51-63. 0

Appendix A: Derivations of Limits to the region of Low Di erentiation We want to derive restrictions on the di erentiation parameter, t; that guarantee that the market will be fully covered. 9 That is, the consumer who travels the entire unit distance nds it pro table to purchase. We proceed by showing that if the advertised price, p i1 ; exceeds v 1 t; rm i s pro ts can be increased by reducing the price to below or about v 1 t: In other words, the maximum price observed cannot exceed v 1 t: Technically, if v 1 t is the maximum price, then, for p i1 > v 1 t; we must have @ 1 @p i1 < 0: That is, any price higher than v 1 t yields lower pro t. Consider rm 1: Suppose then that p 11 > v 1 t: Then, D 1 = 1 (1 ) v 1 p 11 p + 1 p 11 +t t t and 1 = (p 11 + v c) 1 (1 ) v 1 p 11 p + 1 p 11 +t a 1. Di erentiating with respect to p 11 gives, @ 1 t t @p 11 = 1 (1 ) v 1 p 11 p + 1 p 11 +t t + (p t 11 + v c) t and @ 1 = @p 1 11 t ( ) < 0: That is, rm i s pro t is concave in own price. t being the maximum price consistent with full market coverage, it fol- v 1 lows that @ 1 @p 11 j p=v1 t 0: @ 1 @p 11 j p=v1 t = ( ) (v 1 + v c t) 0 only if v 1 + v c t 0 () t v 1+v c: Thus, for t < v 1+v c; prices higher than v 1 t cannot be observed. That is, p + t v 1 which is the condition for full market coverage when rms advertise good 1. 9 We closely follow Soberman (004). 1