PUBLIC SERVICE OBLIGATIONS AND COMPETITION

Similar documents
EUROPEAN COMMISSION. The new Universal service and Users rights Directive

The Voice of European Railways POSITION PAPER DOMESTIC PASSENGER MARKET OPENING IN THE CONTEXT OF THE 4RP. 18 September October 2009 Page 1/9

CEMR Response to the Consultation on the new texts regarding the application of State aid rules to Services of General Economic Interest

DG COMPETITION Unit F3 01 April 2014

CERRE CENTRE ON REGULATION IN EUROPE

Study on the implementation of regulation (EC) n 1370/2007. on public passenger transport services by rail and by road. (prepared by DLA Piper)

Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Progress since the 2004 White Paper on services of general interest

8. But so far the principle of local and regional self-government has not been properly respected in the EU framework. The problem is not confined to

CLEAN ENERGY PACKAGE

Workshop on "Competitive tendering of public service contracts for rail passenger transport: Meeting the challenge" Brussels - 30 th May 2018

IMPLEMENTATION OF ARTICLE 33 and ARTICLE 41 OF DIRECTIVE 2009/73/EC regarding Gas Storage

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES

Retail Price Regulation and EU Law: Mapping the Issues

Consultation on the Notice on the notion of State aid. A EURELECTRIC response paper

Less bureaucracy for small scale financial aid

TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Introduction A shared responsibility of Public Authority in the Union An essential component of the European mode

E R E F European Renewable Energies Federation

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES

SUSTAINABLE PROCUREMENT

Toolkit for Improving Rail Sector Performance. Chapter 8: Buying Services from Railways

Providing high-quality public services in Europe based on the values of Protocol 26 TFEU

ROADMAP. A. Context, Subsidiarity Check and Objectives

Services of General Economic Interest (SGEIs)

Comments on the BEREC Work Programme for 2010

Services of General Economic Interest Opinion Prepared by the State Aid Group of EAGCP. June

CEMR position paper on the proposal for a directive on energy efficiency

Incorporating Social Considerations into Procurement

RWE Thames Water. GREEN PAPER ON PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS AND COMMUNITY LAW ON PUBLIC CONTRACTS AND CONCESSIONS COM(2004) 327 final

Below-Threshold Contracts

ENABLING CONSUMERS TO GENERATE THEIR OWN RENEWABLE ELECTRICITY

Expected key changes in the New Directives on Public Procurement

Procurement by Utilities

PROPOSAL FOR AMENDMENTS

ACS Telecommunications Consultants The Future of the Universal Service Obligation

Committee on the Internal Market and Consumer Protection. of the Committee on the Internal Market and Consumer Protection

Liberalization in the context of the EU Competition Policy

DIRECTIVE (EU) 2018/958 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

The Fourth Railway Package Completing the Single European Railway Area to foster European Competitiveness and Growth

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT

INNOVATION AND REGULATION

15489/14 TA/il 1 DG E 2 A

The Voice of European Railways POSITION PAPER. CER views on the revision of the utilities Directive. May 2012

Implementation of EU Postal Legislation. A guide to the transposition of EC Directive 97/67/EC as amended by Directive 2008/6/EC

DRAFT OPINION. EN United in diversity EN. European Parliament 2016/0404(COD) of the Committee on Legal Affairs

by Mogens Aarestrup Vind and Fie Anna Aaby Hansen, Eversheds Advokataktieselskab 1

Pubic Monopolies, Concessions and Competition Law and Policies

Introduction. The findings. The wider context ANTITRUST

Telecoms: how the Article 7 consultation and notification mechanism works: frequently asked questions (see also IP/10/644)

Application of Social Clauses. Jeanne Copeland Greenville Procurement Partners Ltd.

COMMISSION INTERPRETATIVE COMMUNICATION

Universal Service in the 21 st Century

Belgium-Brussels: HOME/2015/ISFP/PR/DRUG/0062 Waste water analysis report on the stimulant illicit drug markets in the EU 2016/S

(Information) EUROPEAN COMMISSION

Council of the European Union Brussels, 19 February 2015 (OR. en)

COMPETITION IN ELECTRICITY MARKET ACCORDING TO THE REGULATION OF DIRECTIVE 2003/54/ EC

Information Requirements in the Consumer Rights Directive Proposal and in Other Directives

The Role of the Regulator in Respect of Encouraging Consumer Choice, Affordable & Quality Services, Encouraging Investment etc.

Comisión Nacional de Comunicaciones ARGENTINA

Regulation and Inefficient Entry *

Public Consultation on the Review of EU Regulatory Framework for Electronic Communications Networks and Services. Launched by the European Commission

Establishment of an Internal Postal Market Joint responsibility of all stakeholders

Reconciling Liberalization and Public Service Obligations 1

Case C-233/94. Federal Republic of Germany v European Parliament and Council of the European Union

DIRECTIVE 2002/20/EC OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL. of 7 March 2002

The 3 rd Postal Directive establishment of an internal postal market

THE PRINCIPLE OF SUBSIDIARITY

Transport Area of Florence School of Regulation (FSR) 19 March 2012

State aid under EU law

The New Approach of the European Commission to Competition Cases in the Energy Sectors Case COMP/ RWE Gas Foreclosure

State aid and waste management

Hellenic Court of Audit, Greece

Message 791 Communication from the Commission - SG(2012) D/50777 Directive 98/34/EC Notification: 2011/0188/D

Introduction. Public services in transport in EU and Central Europe

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION INTERPRETATIVE COMMUNICATION

How to buy, what to buy

How to strengthen competition advocacy through competition screening Geraldine EMBERGER, Directorate-General Competition, unit A-5

European Competition Law. Prof. Fabio Bassan a.a

THE REGULATORY AUTHORITIES

CEMR RESPONSE. Green Paper on e-procurement. Brussels, January 2011

The SGEI Communication

EU ETS Reform EURELECTRIC Statement on the Impact of Overlapping Policies on the EU ETS. A EURELECTRIC statement

The Electricity and Gas Sector in the EU: the Dilemmas of Public Service Obligations in the Context of State Aid

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER INTERPRETATIVE NOTE ON DIRECTIVE 2009/73/EC CONCERNING COMMON RULES FOR THE INTERNAL MARKET IN NATURAL GAS

Council of the European Union Brussels, 4 February 2019 (OR. en)

EXPERT LEVEL TRAINING ON TELECOM NETWORK COST MODELLING FOR THE HIPSSA REGIONS

Official Journal of the European Union DIRECTIVE 2003/54/EC OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL. of 26 June 2003

The Clean Energy package. Position of the Austrian electricity industry

Net Cost of the Universal Postal Service and Financing Options Experiences from Europe

Brexit paper 9: Public procurement post-brexit

European Confederation of Independent Trade Unions (CESI) Opinion Adopted by the Presidium of CESI

Replies to: Questions for the Hearing on the completion of the internal energy market

Brussels, 28 October 2002 (OR. fr) THE EUROPEAN CONVENTION THE SECRETARIAT CONV 369/02

that these standards can only be delivered effectively by devolution of responsibility to the frontline;

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

Committee on the Internal Market and Consumer Protection WORKING DOCUMENT

Trade in services KEY POINTS. PowerShift e. V. and Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives (CCPA) *

Community legal framework for a

TOOL #38. DRAFTING THE EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM

Comments on CFI Jugement in Deutsche Telekom AG

Transcription:

PUBLIC SERVICE OBLIGATIONS AND COMPETITION Summary of presentations and discussions, CERRE Expert Workshop 15 May 2013, Brussels Speakers: Prof. Catherine Waddams (CERRE & CCP-UEA), Dr Michael Harker (CCP-UEA), Antje Kreutzmann (CCP-UEA), Prof. Pierre Bauby (University Paris 8 & Sciences Politiques), Dirk Segers (Director, Regulatory Affairs, Mobistar), François Degorge (Manager, Regulatory Affairs, SNCF) A recent CERRE report on Public Service Obligations and Competition outlines the current provision made for public service obligations across telecoms, postal services, electricity, gas and railways at the European level and as implemented in four EU countries (Belgium, France, Germany and the UK). Antje Kreutzmann, Doctoral Researcher at the Centre for Competition Policy of the University of East Anglia and co-author of the CERRE report, presents a summary of the legal arrangements which are applicable in the different member states. She explains that a minimum set of requirements is present in all member states and all sectors regarding universal service, service continuity and quality, affordability and consumer protection. Furthermore, all analysed member states impose a number of sector-specific obligations on operators, such as security of supply in the energy sector, safety and security requirements in the rail sector and interconnectivity in telecommunications. Antje Kreutzmann shows that, in general, legal provisions regarding PSOs serve as a mediator between the single market and liberalisation policies pursued by the European Commission and the social and cohesion policies being implemented at national level. However, as these provisions often conflict with competition law, they are sometimes not made explicit in legislation and carried out implicitly by the incumbent operator, which is frequently still (partly) state-owned. Furthermore, Antje Kreutzmann points out that many sectors (with postal services and telecommunications as notable exceptions) display worrying regulatory and legislative gaps in the legal framework applicable to PSOs and USO. Dr Michael Harker, Senior Lecturer at the Centre for Competition Policy of the University of East Anglia and co-author of the report, discusses the study s findings regarding the compensation mechanisms put in place to finance universal service obligations. He points out that Art. 106 of the European Treaty provides member states with ample discretion in determining whether USOs fall within the definition of Services of General Economic Interest and to choose appropriate compensation methods. However, the ample freedom that is left to member states is kept in check by the fact that over-compensation of USOs would be considered as an infringement on state aid rules. Possible over-compensation will be dete rmined by the application of the Altmark criteria, i.e. the compensation cannot exceed the costs of provision by an efficient undertaking. Centre on Regulation in Europe (CERRE) asbl Rue de l Industrie 42 Box 16 - B-1040 Brussels - Belgium Ph: +32 (0)2 230 83 60 - Fax: +32 (0)2 23 0 83 70 info@cerre.eu www.cerre.eu 1/5

Furthermore, Michael Hanker points out that the potential compensation mechanisms that may be used by national authorities have been set out in the European Commission s Green Paper on Services of General Interest. 1 These include direct public subsidies, special or exclusive rights, tariff averaging and contributions by market participants to sectoral funds. The European Commission furthermore expresses a clear preference for direct public subsidies, because they are the most transparent and least distortionary compensation mechanism and because they do not create barriers to entry. In the telecommunications sector, Michael Harker points out that the Universal Service Directive s Recital 4 explicitly outlines how compensation mechanisms should be designed. The compensation should be limited to the net cost of providing the USO, taking into account the possible intangible benefits (e.g. enhanced brand recognition, access to telephone directory information) that the operator may derive from providing the USO. Furthermore, compensation schemes are only required if the net cost of providing the USO represents an unfair burden for the operator, i.e. if the cost is excessive in view of the undertaking s financial situation and market share. Therefore, the cost of the USO might be found, by the regulatory authority, to be an unfair burden for some operators but not for others. As Michael Harker explains, these stringent limits on the development of compensation mechanisms imply that they have only been put in place in 4 European member states. In the railway sector, the situation is very different. Public service contracts are established for all services which operators would not provide if they were only considering their own commercial interest. These public service contracts are awarded by auctions and guarantee the exclusive exploitation rights for a given railway route. The railway directives contain detailed guidance on the compensation methodology and if compensation schemes comply with the directives, they do not require prior notification to the European Commission under state aid rules. To conclude, Michael Harker points to the fact that even when the general regime is relatively prescriptive, such key concepts as unfair burden and intangible benefit were left undefined and had to be filled in by the Courts. This has the advantage of providing ample flexibility to the re gulatory framework, but is also raises the level of legal uncertainty and instability of compensation schemes. Furthermore, Dr Harker points to the fact that there has been very little competition for the market of USOs, with incumbents mostly in charge of providing universal services. In this regards, sectoral funds and competitive tendering are recent developments which may increase the efficiency of providing USOs and raise the level of transparency about their true costs. Prof. Catherine Waddams, Joint Academic Director of CERRE, Professor at the Centre for Competition Policy of the University of East Anglia and Project Director for this research project, presents the results of a survey which has been administered to CERRE member organisations regarding their experience with USOs. The survey collected respondents views regarding, on the one hand, what USOs should ideally include (e.g. geographical coverage, income inequalities, effect on innovation), and, on the other hand, what the effect of existing USOs has been on the sector s performance. 1 EUROPEAN COMMISSION (2003), «Green Paper on Services of General Interest», COM(2003) 270. 130515_CEW_PSOComp 2/5

The results of the survey were in this respect not very surprising, with most regulators answering that they thought USOs were working well (i.e. bringing sizeable benefits to targeted social groups and not altering innovation incentives and the level playing field), and operators more critical of the actual impact of USOs. Also not surprisingly, incumbent operators and new entrants disagreed about the impact of USOs on the level playing field, with incumbents seeing USOs as a burden on their ability to compete and new entrants as a generous subsidy to the incumbent, distorting competition. Prof. Pierre Bauby, Professor of Political Sciences at the University-Paris 8 and Sciences Politiques, explains that the development of a European approach to Services of General Economic Interest is a quite recent phenomenon, which has been gradually introduced after the adoption of the Single European Act of 1986 and the first waves of liberalisation. Since then, the liberalisation process has deepened (through the adoption of successive sectoral legislation packages) and extended to new sectors. This increased liberalisation has been accompanied by European initiatives aimed at rebalancing competition with a renewed attention f or general interest objectives. In Prof. Bauby s view, in the field of Services of General Economic Interest we could even speak about a European Acquis Communautaire based on Art. 106 TFEU. The latter gives, in application of the subsidiarity principle, the general competence to provide and finance SGEI to national, regional and local authorities. Furthermore, as long as these authorities respect the fundamental principles of the EU (i.e. transparency, non-discrimination, equal treatment and proportionality), these SGEI are not subject to competition policy and state aid rules. Prof. Bauby presents an analytical grid which shows that SGEI are at the intersection of 4 conflicting but complementary policy objectives. These objectives are 1) long-term public policies; 2) economic, social and territorial cohesion; 3) subsidiarity between the different levels of government; and 4) the deepening of the single market and the promotion of competition. He points out that, within each sector, the relative importance of the various policy objectives widely differs, due to particular national traditions, diverse European policies and sectoral idiosyncrasies. Finally, Prof. Bauby stresses that analysing how PSOs distort competition, already reflects an a priori judgement the prevalence of competition and that one could also frame the debate as analysing how competition distorts the provision of PSOs Dirk Segers, Director of Regulatory Affairs at Mobistar, explains that USOs have a long history in the Belgian telecommunications sector and that they urgently need to be updated to reflect changing social lifestyles and technological developments. For example, the universal geographical provision of fixed-line telephony and the necessity of pay phones have been rendered obsolete by the ubiquity of mobile telephony. Other obligations could be satisfactorily carried out by competitive providers, such as the provision of telephone directory information. Regarding the existence of social tariffs, Dirk Segers shows the complexity of the system currently in place in Belgium, which in the end only yields limited benefits to disadvantaged customers (max. 11/month). Furthermore, the system is rendered inoperable by the existence of multi -play bundles (which do not allow attributi ng costs to the bundle s 130515_CEW_PSOComp 3/5

components) and the changing nature of the beneficiaries status (unemployment, age, disability, etc.). To illustrate this, he explains that Belgacom cleaned out its database of social tariff recipients in 2005 and that this led to the removal of 17,000 people who, although they had not been eligible for social tariffs for years, were still benefiting from them. Furthermore, Dirk Segers regrets the high level of legal uncertainty that exists around the USO fund that has been set up in the Belgian telecoms sector. Due to annulments by the European Court of Justice and the Belgian Constitutional Court, no compensation mechanism is yet in place, but operators are obliged to keep provisions on their books for these funds. This is non negligible and represents for Mobistar around 1.5% of total profits. Finally, Dirk Segers also points out that USOs (e.g. social tariffs, emergency services) are only supported by telecoms operators. This introduces increasing distortions to competition with the emergence of over-the-top providers (such as Skype) which are not included in the scope of USO regulations, although they directly compete with telecoms operators. François Degorge, Regulatory Manager at SNCF, points out that the tension between PSOs and competition derives from an inherent tension between citizens (who benefit from PSOs) and customers (who benefit from competitive offerings). Historically, public sector companies used to address citizens needs, and through the liberalisation process, these companies are more and more subject to tensions between their new-found obligation to cater to customers in a competitive environment and their traditional role as providers of public services to all citizens. Therefore, before defining PSOs in a competitive market, a number of questions need to be explicitly addressed by public authorities. First, governments need to define the exact scope of what will be covered by the PSO (in terms of beneficiaries, extent of services, etc.). They also need to explicit which provider will be in charge of delivering the service and at which price. François Degorge explains that many problems with PSOs and USOs derive from the fact that even these simple questions are not always clearly answered by public authorities. Furthermore, François Degorge points to a number of specificities from the railway sector which make the provision of PSOs particularly difficult. For example, he explains that, contrary to other sectors, the customer is an integral part of the service provided by railway undertakings. Therefore, he wonders how the concept of provider of last resort will be implemented. Will incumbent operators be requested to assist new entrants in case of incidents? If so, at what cost and how will the incumbent be compensated? François Degorge also explains that liberalisation can be implemented through different modes of competition (i.e. open access competition and franchises), and that these different modes of competition have strongly different impacts on PSO provision. Therefore, the existence and extent of PSO needs to be taken carefully into account when choosing how to open up markets to competition. Finally, François Degorge shows that a number of PSOs in the railway sector, such as national defence and continuity of service obligations, are not explicitly defined in legislation. The absence of a clear definition leads to a miscalculation of their true costs, through the 130515_CEW_PSOComp 4/5

existence of extensive cross-subsidies, which will become problematic with the development of competition. During the discussions, some participants point to the fact that tendering might be hard to implement in practice due to the high level of information asymmetry between incumbents and potential new entrants. For example, in the telecoms sector, it will be difficult for newcomers to bid for the provision of social tariffs in an auction, because the incumbent operator has much more information about the marketing profile of these customers than the new entrants. 130515_CEW_PSOComp 5/5