EU and German Competition Law II (Abuse of a dominant position, Merger Control)

Similar documents
ABUSE OF DOMINANCE. John Pheasant Lecture to National Law University, Jodhpur 24 January 2014

EU Competition Law Abuse of Dominance (Article 102 TFEU) Eirik Østerud

Intellectual Property Right Holders and Dominance

The Abuse of a Dominant Market Position. Mihail Busu, PhD Romanian Competition Council

Article 102TFEU ESTABLISHING DOMINANCE

2. Facebook is a US American company. Why does the Bundeskartellamt have competence to investigate in this case?

Abuse of dominance Evidentiary issues: European overview. Maarten Schueler Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM)

COMPETITION AUTHORITY OF KENYA GUIDELINES ON RELEVANT MARKET DEFINITION I. INTRODUCTION

The Moov Case (Intermediation Platform): An European and German Perspective

EU Competition Law II (Abuse of a dominant position, Merger Control)

Anti-unfair competition developments

COMMISSION NOTICE on the definition of the relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law.

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

Abuses of dominant position in the Commission s Guidance and the case-law of the Court of Justice and the General Court

The A-Soft Case (Online Distribution): An European and German Perspective

Merger Review in the United States and the European Union. Jeffrey I. Shinder Constantine & Partners

Types of abuses and anti- competitive agreements in regulated sectors

Suspected anti-competitive conduct investigation related to the market for locksmith wholesale services

Case T-83/91. Tetra Pak International SA ν Commission of the European Communities

Excessive pricing in pharmaceutical markets

Session 2: Competition Policy Fundamentals

Aditya Bhattacharjea Delhi School of Economics

Chapter 1: Introduction to Quantitative Techniques for Competition Policy. Quantitative Methods for Competition and Regulation Albert Banal-Estanol

Case AT Slovak Telekom Saint Martin's Conference, Brno, 11 November 2015

Rebates: Formalism, Effects and the Real World

WALA 2015 Annual Conference

13 C H A P T E R O U T L I N E

A Guide to Competition Law

PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N CASE FAIR OSTER. PEARSON Prepared by: Fernando Quijano w/shelly Tefft

Bundeskartellamt prohibits Facebook from combining user data from different sources

Alleged competition concern car advertising platform market

Case comment Solvay C-57/01 Top Slices Rebates

Abuse of Dominance Under Art 102 Towards multiple standards?

Excessive Pricing in Pharmaceutical Markets - Note by Denmark

Case T-219/99. British Airways plc v Commission of the European Communities

Selective distribution networks and parallel imports within EU countries

Pubic Monopolies, Concessions and Competition Law and Policies

THE ABUSE OF THE DOMINANT POSITION WITHIN THE IN- TERNAL MARKET OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY: FROM THEORETICAL ASSUMPTIONS TO PRACTICE

Vertical restraints, digital marketplaces, and enforcement tools

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

Wholesale call origination on the public telephone network provided at a fixed location

E-Commerce of Healthcare Products in the EU

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of (Text with EEA relevance)

Competition issues in Online Retailing

EXPERT LEVEL TRAINING ON TELECOM NETWORK COST MODELLING FOR THE HIPSSA REGIONS

Stretching EU competition law tools for search engines and social networks

RECOMMENDATIONS. (Text with EEA relevance) (2014/710/EU)

NV Nederlandsche Banden-Industrie Michelin v Commission of the European Communities

Do we need ex ante price regulation in a liberalised postal market?

antitrust complying with and using competition law

Most Favoured Nation clauses and online platforms: competitive effects and EU competition law

THE TETRA PAK CASE: ARE LOYALTY REBATES TREATED DIFFERENTLY BY THE CHINESE ANTITRUST REGULATOR?

First Annual Conference Competition and Regulation Contemporary and Comparative Issues

Exclusionary Abuses: Between Per Se Prohibition and Rule of Reason Dr. Vassilis Karagiannis Senior Associate

Monopoly. The single seller or firm referred to as a monopolist or monopolistic firm. Characteristics of a monopolistic industry

THE EU MERGER REGULATION: SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES

CPI Antitrust Chronicle May 2015 (1)

Article 102 TFEU. Assessing the dominance: the relevant market. A necessary precondition The product market The geographic market

Anti-competitive exclusionary conduct in EU antitrust practice

EU Competition Webinar Series (Part II) Keeping Distributors in Check in the Online Space

Competition policy: The challenge of digital markets

The Anti-monopoly Commission of the State Council. Anti-monopoly Guideline on Abuse of Intellectual Property Rights.

Economics of two-sided markets

Market Definition and Market Power in Payment Card Networks

LIMITED. Discussion Paper for the formulation of. Guidelines on the application of Article 82 of the Treaty EUROPEAN COMMISSION

Can Analysis of Dominance be taken UPPwards? Possible Lessons from Mergers

Ethical Implications of Trade

Implications of E-commerce for Competition Policy - Note by Romania

Enforcement of EU competition policy

(Text with EEA relevance) (2009/C 45/02) I. INTRODUCTION

BSH Position Paper regarding Preliminary Report on E-Commerce Sector Inquiry

Competition Issues in Aftermarkets - Note from Israel

Formalism Effects Rebates and the real world. Lia Vitzilaiou April 2016

Prohibition of the abuse of a dominant position

Chapter 12. Monopoly. Chapter Outline. Key Ideas. Key Ideas. Introducing a New Market Structure. Evidence-Based Economics Example 11/25/2016

Wholesale call origination on the public telephone network provided at a fixed location

Article 101 (3) TFEU

SUSTAINABLE PROCUREMENT

Internet Sales and Contractual Restrictions of Competition Law Lessons learnt from the EU e- Commerce Sector Inquiry

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

Abuse of Collective Dominance: The Need for a New Approach

Competition Issues in Aftermarkets - Note from Italy

MFN clauses. Competition enforcement in the face of regulatory intervention. EU Competition Law Summit. Spyros Droukopoulos.

Selective distribution after Coty and the interplay of the geo-blocking regulation with competition law

Competition Summary

1. Purpose. This policy provides Employees with guidance on behaviours or actions that may be noncompliant with anti-trust or anti-competition laws.

Big Data and Competition: The policies, issues and challenges ahead

PRICING AND ITS MODELS

EU-China Trade Project (II) Evidentiary issues in antimonopoly cases

European Competition Law. Prof. Fabio Bassan a.a

Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

Case T-228/97. Irish Sugar plc ν Commission of the European Communities

Samson Esayas, NRCCL

The presentation focuses on two central issues in relation to the regime of species protection under the EU Habitats Directive, namely the central

Implications of E-commerce for Competition Policy - Note by Chinese Taipei

UNFAIR PRICING: THE ASPEN CASE. Antonio Buttà AGCM Chief Economist

Article 102 TFEU. Assessing the dominance: the relevant market. A necessary precondition The product market The geographic market

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

Case No COMP/M AVNET/ BELL MICRO. REGULATION (EC) No 139/2004 MERGER PROCEDURE. Article 6(1)(b) NON-OPPOSITION Date: 02/07/2010

Transcription:

EU and German Competition Law II (Abuse of a dominant position, ) 23 May 2017 Summer term 2017 Tuesday, 10-11 h Room IV, Alte Universität Prof. Dr. Florian Bien, Maître en Droit (Aix-Marseille III) Chair for International Business Law, International Arbitration Law and Private Law

Antitrust Law Three pillars Restrictive agreements Abuse of a dominant position Merger control Art. 101 TFEU Art. 102 TFEU Regulation Nr.139/2004

A. Article 102 TFEU

I. Overview EU and German Competition Law II:

Article 102 TFEU Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market in so far as it may affect trade between Member States. Such abuse may, in particular, consist in: (a)directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions; (b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers; (c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage; (d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.

Art. 102 TFEU: Prohibition of abuse of a dominant position Four preconditions: Possible Effect on Inter-State Trade Undertaking Dominant Position in the whole or substantial part of the internal market Abuse (Exploitative or exclusionary)

Legal consequences Finding and termination of infringement - Art. 7 of Regulation No 1/2003 [...] it (the Commission) may impose on them any behavioral or structural remedies which are proportionate to the infringement committed and necessary to bring the infringement effectively to an end. [...] Commitments - Art. 9 of Regulation No 1/2003 [ ] Commission may by decision make those commitments binding on the undertakings. [ ] Fines - Art. 23 of Regulation No 1/2003 [ ] 2. The Commission may by decision impose fines on undertakings and associations of undertakings where, either intentionally or negligently: (a) they infringe Article 81 or Article 82 of the Treaty; or [ ]

Possible forms of abuse 1. Exploitative abuse Supplier Abuse by paying excessively low prices Competitor Dominant Undertaking Distributor Abuse by charging excessively high prices

Possible forms of abuse 2. Exclusionary abuse Supplier Abuse by forcing existing competitors out of the market Potential Competitor Dominant Undertaking Abuse by preventing potential competitors from entering the market Distributor

Possible forms of abuse 3. Leveraging of market power from one market to another Competitor Dominant Undertaking Third Market Abuse by entering a third market and by trying to monopolize it

Possible forms of abuse 3. Leveraging of market power from one market to another Competitor Microsoft Market for Media Players Market for Browsers Quasi-monopoly of Microsoft in the market for operating systems for PCs

Leveraging: The Microsoft examples Market for operating systems: Microsoft = dominant Market for Browsers Leveraging Internet Explorer Google Chrome Mozilla Firefox Safari

II. Delineation of the relevant market

Delineation of the relevant market Gives the answer to Product market Geographic market Which other firms impose a competitive constraint on the one under investigation

1. Relevant product market a) Demand-side oriented market concept or concept of the interchangeability of the products from the buyer s perspective Product characteristics Price Criteria according to the Commission Intended use Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU), Judgment of 13 February 1979, C-85/76 - Hoffmann-La Roche (28) [...] The concept of the relevant market in fact implies that there can be effective competition between the products which form part of it and this presupposes that there is a sufficient degree of interchangeability between all the products forming part of the same market in so far as a specific use of such products is concerned.

1. Relevant product market b) Price elasticity Change of the demand of a product in case of a price rise Demand declines High elasticity Demand remains the same Low elasticity The more the price rise of a product leads the buyers to other products, the more possible it is that those products belong to the same relevant product market

1. Relevant product market c) SSNIP Test : small but significant non-transitory increase in price by the producer (5%-10%) Hypothetical monopolist test definition of substitutable products and services Would enough customers be inclined to switch their purchases to readily available substitutes? Yes Wide market definition * More suitable in the merger control No Prices could be raised profitable No competitive constraint

1. Relevant product market d) Supply-side substitutability As criterion when: Suppliers switch the production to the relevant products and market In response to small and permanent changes in relative prices Without significant additional costs or risks

2. Relevant geographic market Area with homogeneous conditions of competition, significantly different than the ones of the neighboring areas E.g. : Regional markets Territory of a member state Group of member states (Benelux) EU

2. Relevant geographic market Two kind of characteristics for the delineation of the market: Indicators for the existence of separate markets: significant differences concerning market shares, selling and production prices etc. Possible reasons for the fragmentation of the markets: consumer preferences, climatic conditions, language barriers, cost of transporting products, market entry barriers etc.

3. Aftermarkets/Secondary markets Market for parts and accessories used in the upkeep or enhancement of a previous purchase (spare parts) Compatibility with the primary product of high importance narrow definition of market for secondary products E.g. printer/toner, razor/razor blades Commission s Notice (56) [ ] The method of defining markets in these cases is the same, i.e. assessing the responses of customers based on their purchasing decisions to relative price changes, but taking into account as well, constraints on substitution imposed by conditions in the connected markets. [ ]

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms Internet Platforms: Intermediaries which facilitate the interaction of two or more user sides Matching platforms Advertising platforms (facilitating attention) Transaction platforms, e.g. Ebay Non transaction platforms, e.g. Dating platforms E.g. Google search, Yahoo search

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms Matching platforms Transaction platforms, e.g. Ebay Non transaction platforms, e.g. Dating platforms Intermediation Ebay Dating Platform Distributor Consumer Man Woman Contract of sale Acquaintance

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms Advertising platforms (facilitating attention) E.g. Google search, Yahoo search Attention Google Search Searcher Brand

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms Economic particularities of internet platforms and their implications to the assessment under the aspect of competition law a) Direct and indirect network effects b) Economies of scale c) Dynamism of digital business models New German law: 18 para. 3a GWB 2017 For the assessment of the market power of an undertaking on multi-sided markets and networks have to be especially taken into account 1. direct and indirect network effects, 2. the parallel use of more services and the changing possibilities for the user, 3. its economies of scale in the context of network effects, 4. its access to competition relevant data 5. competitive pressure based on innovations

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms a) Direct and indirect network effects (1) Direct network effects The more users of a service, the bigger is the benefit for the single user e.g.: mobile services (2) Indirect network effects A greater number of users on one side of the market attracts more users on the other market side Platform subsidises one side of the market by charging a higher price to the other, the one that is less price sensitive e.g.: dating platforms hotel booking platforms equal price sensitivity lower price sensitivity of hotels Granting of zero-priced services to one side of the platform e.g. for dating platform users, (financed by advertisers) or for or hotel guests problem: market entry barrier; concentration but: Multihoming? (see 18 para. 3a Nr. 2 GWB)

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms a) Direct and indirect network effects cont d Difficulties concerning the delineation of the relevant market in cases of zero-priced services SSNIP-Test (-); therefore idea of an SSNDQ-Test: small but significant non-transitory decrease in quality (criticism: practicability?!) Qualitative criteria, e.g. physical characteristics, end use, price including costs for switching from one service to another (+) Application of competition law also to services provided free of charge? European Commission (+) Germany: Until now, German courts have only taken into consideration possible influence of free services (booking of a hotel by final consumers) on the market side where prices are charged (e.g. platform hotels) as well as the interchangeability with non-zero-priced platforms BUT : New German law: 18 para. 2a GWB 2017 The assumption of a market is not precluded by the fact that a service is provided free of charge. Competition law can be applied to services for which the client does not pay with money.

4. Market definition with regard to Internet platforms b) Economies of scale EU and German Competition Law II: high fixed costs e.g.: operation of the website + low variable costs tendency to concentration of market power; risk of market entry barriers c) Dynamism of digital business models Innovations and dynamism of digital business models can lead to fast-moving changings concerning the balance of power on a given market ( disruptive innovation ).

III. Dominant Position

Dominant Position CJEU, Judgement of 13 February 1979, C-85/76 - Hoffmann-La Roche Economic strength of an undertaking Preventing the effective competition on the relevant market + Allowing the undertaking to behave independently of its competitors, customers and consumers

Dominant position: Two stage examination Definition of relevant market Relevant product market Relevant geographic market Assessment of the dominance (Guidance on the Commission's enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty, Official Journal C 45, 24/02/2009) A. The market position of the dominant undertaking and its competitors B. Possibility of the expansion of actual competitors and of the entry of new ones C. Countervailing buying power

IV. Abusive Behaviour

1. Exploitative Abuses

Most common examples Unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions Art. 102 (2) (a) TFEU Exploitation: Earning of monopoly profits at the expense of the customer or the supplier Measurement of the fairness of prices CJEU, Judgment of 14 February 1978, C-27/76 - United Brands Abusive pricing is the behavior that allows a dominant undertaking to gain commercial advantages that it wouldn t gain within normal and effective competition Criterion: Price that is inadequate to the value of the provided service

Court of Justice, Judgment of 14 February 1978, C-27/76 United Brands v Commission [Charging] a price which is excessive because it has no reasonable relation to the product supplied may be an abuse of a dominant position [within the meaning of subparagraph (a) of article 86 [now article 102 TFEU]. This excess could, inter alia, be determined objectively if it were possible for it to be calculated by making a comparison between the selling price of the product in question and its cost of production, which would disclose the amount of the profit margin; however the Commission has not done this since it has not analyzed UBS s cost structure. (para. 250 and 251)

Court of Justice, Judgment of 4 May 1988, C-30/87 - Corinne Bodson v Pompes Funèbres In Corinne Bodson v Pompes Funèbres, one question before the Court of Justice was whether Pompes Funèbres, which had been given an exclusive concession to provide external services for funerals in a particular French town, was guilty of charging excessive prices. The Court of Justice said that, given that more than 30,000 communes in France had not granted exclusive concessions such as that enjoyed by Pompes Funèbres, but instead had left the service unregulated or operated it themselves, it must be possible to make a comparison between the prices charged by undertakings with concessions and other undertakings: Such a comparison could provide a basis for assessing whether or not the prices charged by the concession holders are fair

Assessment of the unfairness Cost/Price analysis Price Comparison Comparison with the prices of the same undertaking charged in another time period or to other customers Comparison with the prices of other undertakings

2. Non-price based exclusionary conduct