Assortative Matching > 0. (2)

Similar documents
Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory

An Alternative to Signaling: Directed Search and Substitution

Microeconomics Exam Notes

I. Decision Making Units

Citation Journal of Integrated Creative Stud

Lecture 1:Human Capital Theory. September 27, 2017 Hideo Owan Institute of Social Science

EXTERNALITIES AND PRICING ON MULTIDIMENSIONAL. MATCHING PLATFORMS: Online Appendix

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013

Section 1: Introduction

Does Signaling Solve the Lemons Problem? Timothy Perri * March 31, Abstract

The economics of competitive markets Rolands Irklis

Mobility Costs and Localization of Labor Markets

SEARCH THEORY; CURRENT PERSPECTIVES 1

DO NOT OPEN THE QUESTION PAPER UNTIL INSTRUCTED TO DO SO BY THE CHIEF INVIGILATOR. MICROECONOMICS TWO HOURS (2 Hours)

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

Compensating Wage Differentials in Title Matching Equilibrium. Author(s) Han, Seungjin; Yamaguchi, Shintaro.

Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

The Flexible-Salary Match: A Proposal to Increase the Salary Flexibility of the National Resident Matching Program

The Gender Gap in Earnings - Explanations II

Microeconomics

The O-Ring Production Function and Incomplete Contracts

ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory MARKET FAILURES. Asymmetric Information Externalities Public Goods

Is assortative matching efficient?

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

Matching: The Theory. Muriel Niederle Stanford and NBER. October 5, 2011

THE TIMING OF EDUCATION

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

Firm Supply. Market demand. Demand curve facing firm

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research

Two Lectures on Information Design

DEFINITIONS A 42. Benjamin Disraeli. I hate definitions.

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION

Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge

Labour market recruiting with intermediaries

Sharon M. Oster. Karl E. Case. Ray C. Fair. Principles of Microeconomics NINTH EDITION. Wellesley College. Yale University.

Preview from Notesale.co.uk Page 6 of 89

October 25, Your Name: Midterm Exam Autumn Econ 580 Labor Economics and Industrial Relations

Market Shares of Price Setting Firms and Trade Unions. Thomas Grandner. Working Paper No. 61. December 1998

A MODEL FOR DETERMINING AN OPTIMAL LABOR CONTRACT UNDER PROFIT SHARING SYSTEM

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

PRACTICE QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL EXAM (Part 1)

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model March. Sciences Po

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ASSIGNMENT OF WORKERS TO JOBS IN AN ECONOMY WITH COORDINATION FRICTIONS. Robert Shimer

Market structures Perfect competition

SUMMARY OF THE MODELS OF UNIT 4

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion

Producing Goods & Services

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

The party with: greater information high quality of her goods/services Produces a SIGNAL

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

What Is Covered. Econ 2 Final Exam. The Big Concepts. An Outline of Topics Covered In Econ 2

Review Chapters 1 & 2

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012.

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market

Objective. Sessions on Economics. Types of Economic Analysis. Session 2

Introduction to Managerial Economics

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Characterization of the Support of the Mixed. Strategy Price Equilibria in Oligopolies with. Heterogeneous Consumers

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

When the M-optimal match is being chosen, it s a dominant strategy for the men to report their true preferences

MARKETS. Part Review. Reading Between the Lines SONY CORP. HAS CUT THE U.S. PRICE OF ITS PLAYSTATION 2

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

Sellers goods have unobservable quality to buyers. Borrowers ability to repay is unobservable to banks who lend

College Record: 59.7% 4 year school, 13.1% 2 year school, 9.9% trade school

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

Oshoring in a Knowledge Economy

PROBLEM SET 3. a) Find the pure strategy Nash Equilibrium of this game.

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS (EC201)

Lecture 1 An Introduction

Harvard University Department of Economics

Microeconomics: MIE1102

Learning About the Nature of Production from Equilibrium Assignment Patterns

FOUNDATION COURSE MOCK TEST PAPER PAPER 4: PART I : BUSINESS ECONOMICS

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

DO NOT OPEN THIS BOOKLET OR TURN IT OVER [until told to do so]

Incentives in Crowdsourcing

On Optimal Multidimensional Mechanism Design

Topics on Matching Theory

Producing Goods & Services

In each case: fixed firms in the market, then entry/exit

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Managing Decentralized Inventory and Transhipment

Information. Course Readings:

5-3 - Copyright 2017 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved

Topics in Economic Theory III: Labor Markets

MONOPSONY IN MOTION. Alan Manning IMPERFECT COMPETITION IN LABOR MARKETS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON AND OXFORD

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Economics 817: Game Theory

Transcription:

Assortative Matching In a marriage market the competition for spouse leads to sorting of mates by characteristics such as wealth, education, and other characteristics. Positive assortative matching refers to a positive correlation in sorting between the values of the traits of husbands and wives (matching of likes); negative assortative matching refers to a negative correlation (matching of unlikes). While it has been long recognized that sorting of husbands and wives by characteristics occurs in all cultures and societies, economists have tried to understand sorting patterns in the marriage market and other matching markets by focusing on the nature of the gain from match and the mechanism of the market force of competition. A simple framework to illustrate the economic approach to sorting in matching markets is a two-sided marriage market with an equal number of men and women, who differ in one-dimensional characteristics called type and have common preferences for higher types over lower types. In positive assortative matching, the highest type man mates the highest type woman, and the second highest type man mates the second highest type woman, and so on. Negative assortative matching is the highest type man with the lowest type woman, and the second highest type man with the second lowest type woman, and so on. We assume transferable utility and zero reservation utility from remaining single for each market participant. Then, the gain from match can be represented by an increasing, positive-valued function f, which gives the match output f(x, y) of any pair of type x man and type y woman. Consider two men, with types x H > x L, and two women, with types y H > y L. If type x H and type x L command the same price in terms of the utility transfer they demand from the wife for the match, then both type y H and type y L would prefer the higher type man because f is increasing in male type. Competition for type x H naturally leads to a higher price for type x H than for type x L. Whether the higher female type y H can outbid type y L for type x H or vice versa depends on whether male type and female type are complements or substitutes in the match output function f. If f(x H, y H ) f(x H, y L ) > f(x L, y H ) f(x L, y L ), (1) then male type and female type are complementary, because the marginal product of female type is greater when matched with a higher male type (the left-hand-side of inequality 1) than with a lower male type (the right-hand-side of 1). In this case, type y L is willing to offer type x H at most f(x H, y L ) f(x L, y L ) more than what she offers type x L, but by inequality (1) this difference is smaller than f(x H, y H ) f(x L, y H ), which is the most type y H is willing to offer. Thus, type y L will be outbid by type y H for type x H when male type and female type are complements. Since the argument is valid for any two pairs of men and women, the competition for spouse must lead to positive assortative matching. Conversely, if inequality (1) is reversed, male type and female type are substitutes. A lower female type can outbid a higher type for any male type, and the competition for spouse leads to negative assortative matching. The differentiable version of inequality (1) is 2 f(x, y) x y > 0. (2) 1

Conditions (1) and (2) are commonly referred to as the (strict) supermodularity condition of the match output function f. See Topkis (1998) for a comprehensive mathematical treatment of supermodularity, and Milgrom and Roberts (1990) and Vives (1990) for applications in game theory and economics. Inequality (1) can be rewritten as f(x H, y H ) + f(x L, y L ) > f(x L, y H ) + f(x H, y L ). (3) Condition (3) suggests that positive assortative matching maximizes the sum of match outputs in the marriage market when male type and female type are complements in the match output function. This result is a direct application of Koopmans and Beckmann s (1957) theorem of equivalence between the efficient matching, which maximizes the sum of match outputs among all feasible pairwise matchings, and the competitive equilibrium matching, which obtains when each woman y takes as given a schedule of utility transfers u(x) to men and chooses the male type that maximizes her utility. The competitive equilibrium matching can also be obtained as each man x takes as given a schedule of utility transfers v(y) to women and chooses the female type that maximizes his utility. Shapely and Shubik (1972) model the marriage market with transferable utilities as a cooperative game. They show that a pair of transfer schedules that support an equilibrium matching corresponds to the core of the game, so that no pair of a man and a woman not matched in equilibrium can form a blocking coalition that produces a match output greater than the sum of their respective transfers. The results of Koopmans and Beckmann (1957), and Shapley and Shubik (1972) are obtained in a matching market without any hierarchical ordering of types. By introducing one-dimensional, heterogeneous types, Becker (1973) seeks to explain why sorting of mates by wealth, education and other characteristics is similar in the marriage market. He constructs a household production function and derives condition (1) for each of the characteristics separately by considering how the characteristic affects the household output while holding other characteristics fixed. Becker s model can accommodate dissimilar sorting of mates by some characteristics as well; for example, negative assortative matching by wage rates may arise because the benefits from the division of labor within a household can make the earning abilities of the man and the woman substitutes for each other. Sattinger (1980) uses condition (2) to explain why the distribution of earnings of workers is skewed to the right relative to the distribution of their measured skills. In a market that matches a continuum of workers with different skills to a continuum of positions of different capital investment, the distribution of earnings would have the same shape as the distribution of skills if matching is random. In Sattinger s theory of differential rents, positive assortative matching of worker skill and job capital investment occurs because skill and capital investment are complements. In this case, the distribution of earnings will not resemble the distributions of outputs at a job with the average capital investment. Instead, workers with higher skills are paid more than those with lower skills both because they are more productive at any job and because they occupy positions with greater capital investments. Formally, in equilibrium the wage schedule u satisfies the first order condition of type y s maximization problem of choosing x to maximizing f(x, y) u(x) f(x, m(x)) x 2 = u (x),

where m(x) is the capital investment of the job occupied by the worker with skill x in equilibrium. It can shown that condition (2) and positive assortative matching imply that f(x, y) u(x) is concave in x at x = m 1 (y), so the second order condition is satisfied for each y. The first order condition implies that worker s wage increases at the rate of marginal product of the worker s skill x at his equilibrium job, so that the rate of increase of u is augmented by the complementarity (condition 2) and positive assortative matching (m (x) > 0). Thus, with positive assortative matching, the distribution of earnings will therefore be positively skewed relative to the distribution of skills. Kremer (1993) highlights the role of positive assortative matching in economic development. In his model of one-sided, many-to-many matching market, each firm consists of a fixed number of workers each employed for a production task. Workers have different skills, with a higher-skilled worker less likely to make mistakes in performing his task. Condition (1) is assumed to capture the complementarity among worker skills that the production process of a firm requires completion of each task without mistakes. Self-matching obtains in equilibrium where each firm employs workers of identical skills. Kremer uses this form of positive assortative matching to explain the large wage and productivity differences between developing and developed countries that cannot be accounted for by their differences in levels of physical or human capital. Self-matching will generally be inefficient and will not occur in equilibrium if production tasks in a firm differ in skill requirements. In Kremer and Maskin (1996), a firm consists of two workers with a match output function f(x, y) that satisfies the supermodularity conditions (1) and (2) but is asymmetric in that f(x, y) > f(y, x) for any x > y. The interpretation of the asymmetry is that the first argument in f represents the skill of the worker who does the manager s job while the second argument represents the skill of the worker who performs the assistant s job. In any given firm, it is optimal to make the higher-skilled worker the manager and the lower-skilled worker the assistant, but it is no longer generally true that self-matching maximizes the total match outputs. Indeed, we can have 2f(z H, z L ) > f(z H, z H ) + f(z L, z L ) (4) for some z H > z L, so that two firms each with the higher type z H as the manager and the lower type z L as the assistant produce more in total than two firms with the manager and the assistant having the same skill level. Note that inequality (4) does not contradict inequality (3) due to the asymmetry in f. Mixed matching may do better than selfmatching because it can be more important to exploit the asymmetry in the match output function and have each high-skill worker as the manager of a firm than to exploit the complementarity in f and have one high-skill worker as the assistant to the other highskill worker. Kremer and Maskin find that the efficient matching in their model depends on the skill distribution in the matching market, because the trade-off between the asymmetry and the complementarity in the match output function depends on the relative scarcity of high-skilled workers. Assortative matching may be hindered by the presence of frictions in the matching market. For example, if there is a moral hazard problem in producing the match output by each matched pair, transferability of utilities will be restricted by incentive compatibility constraints. Legros and Newman (2002) discuss this and other examples of transaction 3

costs, and find that equilibrium matching in these examples can be inefficient. Frictions can also arise due to incomplete information about type. Roth and Xing (1994) provide detailed descriptions of labor markets for entry-level professionals (e.g., lawyers, medical interns) in which early matches are sometimes made before complete information about matching characteristics such as qualifications of job candidates and desirability of job positions becomes available. The complementarity in the match output function between the type of the applicant and the type of the job implies that there will be matching efficiency loss if matches are formed before the uncertainty about types is resolved. If all market participants are risk-neutral, this efficiency loss is sufficient to rule out early matches as applicants compete for job positions. However, when some participants are riskaverse, early matches provide them with some insurance against the payoff risks associated with late matches formed after complete information about types becomes available. Li and Suen (2000) apply competitive equilibrium analysis to the early matching market to determine the pattern of early matching, the terms of early matches, and the distribution of benefits in the early market. Early matching need not be positive assortative in terms of expected type. Higher expected types of workers may face greater payoff risks from late matches due to the complementarity in the match output function. In this case, they may be willing to match with lower expected types of jobs to insure against the risks, while owners of higher expected types of jobs are content with waiting for late matches if they are risk-neutral. Private information about type may also result in frictions in the matching market. For example, many users of Internet dating agencies complain about the problem of misrepresentation and exaggerations by some users in the information they provide to the agencies. This problem arises because current matching services adopt the uniform pricing policy, and this in practice results in almost random matching. Damiano and Li (2004) point out that the complementarity in the match output function implies a version of the standard single-crossing condition in mechanism design problems, and an intermediary can use price discrimination to improve matching efficiency and generate greater revenue. They consider the problem of a monopoly matchmaker that uses a pair of fee schedules to sort different types of agents on the two sides into exclusive meeting places. The revenuemaximizing sorting need not be positive assortative (i.e., efficient in the first-best sense). Conditions necessary and sufficient to recover positive assortative matching require that the complementarity in the match output function to be sufficiently strong to overcome the incentive cost to the matchmaker of eliciting private type information. Matching frictions can arise also because finding type information about potential partners takes time or involves costly effort. In the search and matching framework, each market participant randomly meets a currently unmatched agent from the other side of the market, decides whether to form a match or to search again in the next period. Search is costless, but agents must trade off the benefit from starting to produce with the encountered partner right away and the opportunity cost of waiting for a better partner. With an exogenous probability of separation of matched agents who then reenter the market, Shimer and Smith (2000) characterize the stationary search and matching equilibrium where the matching decisions of each type and the type distributions of unmatched agents are time-invariant. Types x and y in an agreeable match are assumed to use the Nash 4

bargaining solution to split the net surplus, defined as the match output f(x, y) minus sum of the (endogenous) continuation payoffs g(x) to x and h(y) to y as unmatched agents. Shimer and Smith modify the definition of positive assortative matching in the frictionless world to allow for set-valued mutually agreeable matches. The match set of a type x is the intersection of the set of types that type x agrees to match with and the set of types that agree to match with x. In Shimer and Smith s definition, matching is positive assortative if for any male types x H > x L and female types y H > y L such that y H is in the match set of x L and y L is in the match set of x H, then y H is in the match set of x H and y L is in the match set of x L. When match sets are convex, positive assortative matching requires the lowest and the highest type of the match set to be increasing in x. However, match sets need not be convex even though the match output function is supermodular. This is because the net surplus f(x, y) g(x) h(y) is not necessarily quasi-concave in y for fixed x, so one cannot be say anything about how match sets vary across different x. Shimer and Smith provide conditions on f in addition to supermodularity to ensure convexity of match sets and reestablish positive assortative matching in a stationary equilibrium. The stationary search and matching equilibrium does not capture the dynamics of matching in markets where there is no entry of a new cohort in each period and each matched pair receives their match output after the market closes for all participants. For example, many entry-level markets for professionals (e.g., academic economists) are organized around annual recruitment cycles. In these markets, matches are formed sequentially without centralized matching procedures. Damiano, Li and Suen (forthcoming) consider such markets by constructing a two-sided, finite-horizon search and matching model with heterogeneous types and complementarity between types. The quality of the pool of potential partners deteriorates as agents who have found mutually agreeable matches exit the market. When search is costless and all agents participate in each matching round, the market performs a sorting function in that high types of agents have multiple chances to match with their peers. The matching efficiency measured by the total expected match outputs improves as the number of matching rounds increases; positive assortative matching is achieved if there are as many matching rounds as are types. However, this sorting function is lost if agents incur an arbitrarily small cost in order to participate in each round. With a sufficiently rich type space relative to the number of matching rounds, the market unravels as almost all agents rush to participate in the first round and match and exit with anyone they meet. See also assignment problems, matching markets. Bibliography Li, Hao Becker, G.S. 1973. A theory of marriage: part I. Journal of Political Economy 81(4), July/August, 813 846. Damiano, E. and Li, H. 2004. Price discrimination and efficient matching. Working paper, Department of Economics, University of Toronto. 5

Damiano, E., Li, H. and Suen, W. Unraveling of dynamic sorting. Forthcoming Review of Economic Studies. Koopmans, T.C. and Beckmann, M. 1957. Assignment problems and the location of economic activities. Econometrica 25(1), January, 53 76. Kremer, M. 1993. The o-ring theory of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, May, 551-575. Kremer, M. and Maskin, E. 1996. Wage inequality and segregation by skill. National Bureau of Research Working Paper Series W5718. Legros, P. and Newman, A. 2002. Monotone matching in perfect and imperfect worlds. Review of Economic Studies 69(4), October, 925 942. Li, H. and Suen, W. 2000. Risk-sharing, sorting, and early contracting. Journal of Political Economy 108(5), October, 1058 1091. Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. 1990. Rationalizability, learning and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities. Econometrica 45, 101 114. Roth, A. and Xing, X. 1994. Jumping the gun: imperfections and institutions related to the timing of market transactions. American Economic Review 84(4), September, 992 1044. Sattinger, M. 1980. Capital and the Distribution of Labor Earnings. Amsterdam: North- Holland. Shapley, L. and Shubik, M. 1972. The assignment game I: the core. International Journal of Game Theory 1, 111 130. Shimer, R. and Smith, L. 2000. Assortative matching and search. Econometrica 68(2), March, 343 369. Topkis, D. 1998. Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Vives, X. 1990. Nash equilibrium with strategic complementarities. Journal of Mathematical Economics 19, 305 321. 6