References. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp

Similar documents
CARTEL STABILITY AND THE CURVATURE OF MARKET DEMAND. Luca Lambertini *

Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria", Games and Economic Behavior, 2, 29-46, 1990.

Process RDin Monopoly under Demand Uncertainty. Abstract

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

Process R&D in Monopoly under Demand Uncertainty 1

Relative profit maximization and the choice of strategic variables in duopoly

Price vs Quantity in a Duopoly Supergame with Nash Punishments

Bonanno, G. (1987), Location Choice, Product Proliferation and Entry Deterrence, Review of

Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion

Efficient Horizontal Mergers in Polluting Industries with Cournot Competition

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki

How to simulate the coordinated effect of a merger

Capacity Choice in the Mixed duopoly with Product Differentiation. Abstract

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #9

Collusion. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Collusion February / 31

Price vs. Quantity in Duopoly with Strategic Delegation: Role of Network Externalities

Yasuhiko Nakamura Graduate School of Economics, Waseda University. Abstract

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang *

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

On Collusion and Industry Size

Imperfect Competition

Complementarity between product and process innovation in a monopoly setting. 1

Tacit collusion with price matching punishments

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND CARTEL STABILITY WITH STOCHASTIC MARKET DEMAND

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Solutions to Final Exam

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

Tilburg University. The repeated lake game Brock, W.A.; de Zeeuw, Aart. Published in: Economics Letters. Publication date: Link to publication

Bargaining over managerial contracts: a note

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

R&D Cooperation and Industry Cartelization

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Privatization, Profit and Welfare in a Differentiated Network Duopoly

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Abstract

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 4 pp Introduction

Vertical Integration versus Vertical Separation: An Equilibrium Model

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

Part II. Market power

Evaluating the Competitive Yardstick Effect of Cooperatives on Imperfect Markets: A Simulation Analysis

PRODUCT INNOVATION UNDER VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION AND THE PERSISTENCE OF MONOPOLY

Big fish eat small fish: On merger in Stackelberg markets

Lecture 4: Will profits in reality be higher or lower than under Cournot? Tom Holden

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

Vertical Integration and Competition Policy

Collusion when the Number of Firms is Large

The Profitability of Small Horizontal Mergers with Nonlinear Demand Functions

Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers

Delegation and Firms Ability to Collude: Do Incentive Schemes Matter? Patrick de Lamirande. Cape Breton University, Sydney, Canada. Jean-Daniel Guigou

Incentives for Process Innovation in a Collusive Duopoly

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

OLIGOPOLY: Characteristics

4 Effects of a change in marginal cost (Extra) α β q * 1. The reason is that this is the first-order condition for the firm's choice of quantity.

Optimal degree of privatization in a mixed oligopoly with multiple public enterprises

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

Relative profit maximization and Bertrand equilibrium with quadratic cost functions

The No Surcharge Rule and Card User Rebates: Vertical Control by a Payment Network

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

Process and product innovation in a vertically differentiated monopoly

Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions

Welfare Enhancing Mergers under Product Differentiation

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model

REGIONAL RESTRICTION, STRATEGIC DELEGATION, AND WELFARE

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

Effects of discount factor distribution in repeated games fads, fashion, and novelty fair

4/21/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 21: Game Theory 3 Back to the Firms. The Story So Far. Today. Monopolies. Introduction.

Persuasive Advertising in Oligopoly: A Linear State Differential Game

Working Paper n 07/03

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

Collusion with secret price cuts: an experimental investigation. Abstract

OPTIMAL ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION, R&D SUBSIDIZATION AND THE ROLE OF MARKET CONDUCT* JOANNA A. POYAGO-THEOTOKY

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Cronfa - Swansea University Open Access Repository

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Quality Choice, Fixed Costs and Equilibrium in Models of Vertical Differentiation 1

This is a repository copy of An Elasticity Measure Of Welfare Loss In Symmetric Oligopoly.

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

3. Cartels and Collusion

Lecture 3 OLIGOPOLY (CONTINUED) 13-1 Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

Networks, Telecommunications Economics and Strategic Issues in Digital Convergence. Prof. Nicholas Economides. Spring 2006

Horizontal Product Differentiation in Bertrand and Cournot Duopoly: the Bertrand Paradox Revisited and Comparative Competitiveness

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012.

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

WORKING PAPER SERIES Judo Economics in Markets with Asymmetric Firms Daniel Cracau Working Paper No. 2/2013

Transcription:

References Chang M. (1991), The Effects of Product Differentiation on Collusive Pricing, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, pp.453-69. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp.37-42. Häckner J. (1994), Collusive Pricing in Markets for Vertically Differentiated Products, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 12, pp.155-77. Jehiel, P. (1992), Product Differentiation and Price Collusion, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, pp.633-41. Majerus, D.W. (1988), Price vs Quantity Competition in Oligopoly Supergames, Economics Letters, 27, pp.293-7. Ross, T.W. (1992), Cartel Stability and Product Differentiation, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, pp.1-13. Rothschild, R.(1992), On the Sustainability of Collusion in Differentiated Duopolies, Economics Letters, 40, pp.33-7. 5

Since ρ * * C =ρ B when r=0.96155, the reverse is true only for r ]0.96155, 1], i.e., when products are very close substitutes. As far as social welfare is concerned, Ross (1992, p.8-9) shows that under Bertrand competition the ratio SW C /SW N decreases as r, i.e., the degree of substitutability, increases. Thus, the larger is product differentiation the less harmful collusion will be. It can be quickly checked that the same holds in the Cournot setting as well. Social welfare is defined as the sum of consumer surplus and industry profits: SW J = i π i J + CS J, i = 1, 2; J = N, C, (9 which in the two cases under consideration yields: SW N = (a c)2 (3 + r) ; SW C 3(a c)2 = (2 + r) 2 4(1 + r). (10 It is straightforward to verify that both SW N and SW C are decreasing and convex in r. Since the same also holds for the ratio SW C /SW N, the above claim is thus proved. 3. Conclusions I have investigated the issue of cartel stability in a quantity-setting duopoly where products are characterized by an exogenous degree of substitutability. The comparison between my results and those derived by Ross (1992) for a price-setting duopoly shows that collusion in quantities is more easily sustained than collusion in prices for a wide range of parameters, while the opposite holds only when the degree of substitutability between products is almost complete. This conclusion differs completely with that reached by Rothschild (1992) while it confirms to a certain extent that of Deneckere (1983). Finally, the level of social welfare associated with the cartel increases as product differentiation increases, independently of whether firms set prices or quantities. 4

π i D =[(a c)(2b + d)] 2 /16b(b + d) 2. By now we are well acquainted with the notion of collusion stability in an infinitely repeated game, so that I can confine myself to recall that the critical discount rate ρ * = πc π N π D π C (6 provides a direct measure of cartel stability. Provided that the model is symmetric, index i can be dropped. On the basis of the above calculations, the critical discount rate in the Cournot case is the following: ρ C * = 4(r + 1) 4(r + 1)+r 2, (7 which is equal to 1 when goods are completely independent (r=0), while it is equal to 8/9 when there is perfect substitutability (r=1). Furthermore, it is easily checked that in the relevant range of parameters both the first and the second derivatives of respect to r are non-positive, so that the critical discount factor is decreasing and concave in the degree of substitutability. The critical discount rate under Bertrand competition (Ross, 1992, pp.7-8) is defined as follows: ρ C * ρ B * = 4(1 + r) r [0, 0.73[; ρ * r 4 (2 r) 2 B = (2 r) 2 (r 2 + r 1) r [0.73, 1]. (8 The discontinuity in ρ B * is due to the fact that for r>0.73 the model ovestates the gain from cheating and violates the constraint that all quantities must be positive. When this constraint is duly accounted for, the second expression in (8) obtains. Thus, under Bertrand behaviour cartel stability initially decreases and then increases as product differentiation shrinks. A comparison between (7) and (8) shows that quantity collusion is generally more stable than price collusion. 3

p i = a bx i dx j, i, j = 1, 2, i j. (2 The ratio r = d/b [0, 1] measures the degree of exogenous differentiation between the two goods. If r=0 they are completely independent, while if r=1 they are perfect substitutes. Both firms produce at the same constant marginal cost c. Thus, the profit function of firm i is the following: π i =(p i c)x i, (3 from which firm i s reaction function in the quantity space can be derived: π i x i = a c 2bx i dx j = 0. (4 Solving (4), we obtain x N i =(a c)/(2b + d) and π N i = b(a c) 2 /(2b + d) 2 as the optimal quantity and equilibrium profit for firm i in the simultaneous noncooperative duopoly game. Let us now focus on cartel behaviour. The objective of the cartel is to maximize joint profits Π C =π C i +π C j. The generic first order condition is: Π C x i = a c 2bx i 2dx j = 0, (5 from which we can easily obtain firm i s optimal collusive output x C i =(a c)/2(b + d) and then equilibrium profits π C i =(a c) 2 /4(b + d). We are finally able to investigate firm i s cheating behaviour, provided firm j sticks to the collusive agreement. By substituting x C j =(a c)/2(b + d) into (4) and solving for x i, we get x D i =(a c)(2b + d)/4b(b + d) as firm i s deviation output, while deviation profits are 2

1. Introduction The issue of cartel stability has received wide attention in the recent oligopoly theory. In this short note, I want to focus on the influence exerted by product differentiation on firms ability to collude. Within the address approach, this question has been tackled in several papers (Chang, 1991; Jehiel, 1992; Ross, 1992 and Häckner, 1994). Within the non-address approach, the main contributions are those of Deneckere (1983), Majerus (1988), Ross (1992) and finally Rothschild (1992). Ross confines his attention to the interplay between product differentiation and price collusion, showing that the critical discount rate is initially decreasing and then increasing in the degree of substitutability between products. Deneckere, as well as Rothschild, compares cartel stability under price and quantity competition, though resorting to different models. The first author claims that collusion is better sustained in price setting games when substitutability is high, while the reverse holds when substitutability is low; on the contrary, the second author finds that a high degree of substitutability fosters collusion in quantity, and viceversa. Finally, Majerus has shown that the latter result does not hold as the number of firms increases. In the following pages, I am going to investigate collusive behaviour in a differentiated quantity-setting duopoly adopting the same modelization as in Ross (1992). On the basis of my own and Ross results it is possible to claim that quantity collusion is generally more stable than price collusion, except when goods are very close substitutes. This conclusion is in sharp contrast with Rothschild (1992) while it is partially in line with Deneckere (1983). 2. The model The model I adopt relies on a quadratic utility function for the representative consumer, as in Dixit (1979), Singh and Vives (1984) and Ross (1992). Individuals derive utility from the consumption of two substitute goods, x 1 and x 2, and a numeraire y, according to U = ax 1 + ax 2 1 2 (bx 2 1 + 2dx 1 x 2 + bx 2 2 )+y (1 that, given p y =1, yields the following inverse demand function for good i: 1

EXOGENOUS PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND THE STABILITY OF COLLUSION Luca Lambertini * Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche # Strada Maggiore 45 40125 Bologna tel 39-51-6402600 fax 39-51-6402664 e-mail LAMBERTI@boph01.cineca.it and Linacre College Oxford OX1 3JA e-mail ECONLLA@vax.ox.ac.uk JEL classification number: L 13 Keywords: cartel stability, product differentiation Abstract The stability of collusion in quantities in a differentiated duopoly is analised, and the result is compared to that emerging in the case of price-setting behaviour. It turns out that quantity collusion is generally better sustained than price collusion, unless products are almost perfect substitutes. Under both quantity and price competition, the social damage associated with collusion is increasing in the degree of substitutability. * Acknowledgements I am grateful to Gianpaolo Rossini for helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies. # Please send correspondence to the Italian address.