The Unilateral Conduct Working Group: You Be the Judge Scrutinizing a Loyalty Discount & Rebate Case

Similar documents
ICN Unilateral Conduct Workshop Remedies Breakout Session Guide

Unless otherwise stated, the questions concern unilateral conduct by a dominant firm or firm with significant market power.

Agency Name: Office of Competition and Consumer Protection, Poland Date: December 16, 2008 Tying & Bundled Discounting

Session on International Enforcement Perspectives Federal Trade Commission and Antitrust Division Hearings on Section 2 of the Sherman Act

The Abuse of a Dominant Market Position. Mihail Busu, PhD Romanian Competition Council

Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

Single-Product Loyalty Discounts and Rebates

Predatory Pricing. 2. Please list your jurisdiction s criteria for an abuse of dominance/monopolization based on predatory pricing.

ICN Unilateral Conduct Workshop

ABUSE OF DOMINANCE. John Pheasant Lecture to National Law University, Jodhpur 24 January 2014

FORDHAM CORPORATE LAW INSTITUTE

Price-Cost Tests in Unilateral Conduct Cases. Presented by ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group

Exclusionary Conduct. Joseph Kattan Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP Washington, DC

Types of abuses and anti- competitive agreements in regulated sectors

Agency Name: The Office for the Protection of Competition, Czech Republic Date: 17 th October 2008 Tying & Bundled Discounting

CRESSE 2019 Lawyers Course

Agency Name: Superintendencia de Industria y Comercio Date:

THE TETRA PAK CASE: ARE LOYALTY REBATES TREATED DIFFERENTLY BY THE CHINESE ANTITRUST REGULATOR?

Plenary Session #2: Presentation of the UCWG vertical restraints project

Antitrust Trouble Through Aggressive Pricing: Let s Count the Ways

Report on the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry

THE E.C. GREEN PAPER ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS: OPTION IV DEFENDED. Trinity Economic Paper Series Paper 99/8 JEL Classification: L42

ONLINE RESTRAINTS EFFECTS, ANALYSIS AND ENFORCEMENT

The Reform of Article 82: Reactions to the DG-Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses

CPI Antitrust Chronicle November 2013 (1)

Bundling And Monopoly Leveraging: Implications For Antitrust And Innovation

Vertical Restraints, Exclusive Dealing, and Competition on the Merits

Abuse of Dominance Under Art 102 Towards multiple standards?

How Antitrust Agencies Analyze M&A

Abuse of dominance From a form-based approach to an effect-based approach. Gautier DUFLOS, Chief Economist Team French Competition Authority

The law and economics of rebates

Re: Draft Anti-Pricing Monopoly Regulation

The 10th ASCOLA Conference Abuse Regulation in Competition Law Past, Present and Future at Meiji University, Tokyo, May 2015

The Reform of Article 82: Comments on the DG-Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 to Exclusionary Abuses

INTERNATIONAL SECURITIES ASSOCIATION FOR INSTITUTIONAL TRADE COMMUNICATION ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE POLICY

Exclusivity rebates vs. predation: different paradigms?

Prohibition of the abuse of a dominant position

Some remarks on pricing abuses

National Judicial Academy National Conference for Newly Elevated High Court Justices

Measuring exclusionary effects under Article 82

DRAFT COMMISSION GUIDELINES ON THE ASSESSMENT OF NON- HORIZONTAL MERGERS

Rebates, Bundling and Tying

On the Art 82 enforcement priorities Effects on consumer welfare

Report on the Analysis of Loyalty Discounts and Rebates Under Unilateral Conduct Laws

ARNOLD PORTER (UK) LLP

First impressions on the Revised US and UK Merger Guidelines

What makes unilateral conduct abusive? An economic perspective

(Text with EEA relevance) (2009/C 45/02) I. INTRODUCTION

CPI Antitrust Chronicle July 2013 (2)

Suspected anti-competitive conduct investigation related to the market for locksmith wholesale services

Taiwan. Predatory Pricing

CPI Antitrust Chronicle February 2011 (2)

Vertical restraints, digital marketplaces, and enforcement tools

Abuse of Dominance: New Developments in the Tetra Pak Decision

Guidance On Enforcement Priorities Regarding Exclusionary Abuses: A Comparative Overview

Towards an effects based approach to price discrimination. Anne Perrot «Pros and Cons 2005» Stockholm

CPI Antitrust Chronicle June 2014 (2)

The Economics of EC Competition Law: Concepts, Application and Measurement

INTERNATIONAL DIGITAL PUBLISHING FORUM ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE POLICY AND GUIDELINES

Quantification of Damages in Exclusionary Practice Cases. Paolo Buccirossi 1

Brian Henry, ABA Antitrust Section Vice Chair Long Range Planning Committee

Andrew Christopher, Partner, Baker & McKenzie, Australia. Predatory Pricing

DISCRIMINATORY CONDUCT GUIDELINES. December 2014

Product Distribution in the United States and Canada The Same but Different

4/13/2018. Evolving Standards on Resale Price Maintenance, Tying and Other Vertical Restraints. Program Overview

COMPETITION LAW AND STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES Contribution from Sweden

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

Anti-competitive exclusionary conduct in EU antitrust practice

DRAFT. Mike Walker A brief survey of the economic thinking on bundling and tying

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

Product design in EU competition law

Taking advantage of market power

The Intel Judgment: Practical Implications. Jean-François Bellis

... University of Deusto School of Law

If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an to

WHAT COMPANIES DON T KNOW CAN HURT THEM: MONOPOLIZATION OFFENSES 1

GUIDE TO COMPETITION LAW FEBRUARY 2014

ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE GUIDELINES

Article 102 TFEU. Assessing the dominance: the relevant market. A necessary precondition The product market The geographic market

An Economic Approach to Article 82

WHAT EVERY BUSINESS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT PRICE DISCRIMINATION

ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE POLICY

Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation

STATEMENT OF ACHIEVEMENTS

Hearing But Not Listening: Comparative Competition Law and the DOJ Monopoly Report

Chinese Antitrust Enforcement Against Tying, Exclusive Dealing, and Loyalty Discounts

Anti-competitive exclusionary conduct in EU antitrust practice

Article 102 TFEU. Assessing the dominance: the relevant market. A necessary precondition The product market The geographic market

EDITORIAL THE ARTICLE 82 DISCUSSION PAPER: A MISSED OPPORTUNITY SIMON BISHOP AND PHILIP MARSDEN

Merger trends in innovation markets. Pablo Ibanez Colomo London School of Economics

Abuse of dominance Evidentiary issues: European overview. Maarten Schueler Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM)

An economic approach to exclusionary rebates?

Leveraging Non-Contestability: Exclusive Dealing and Rebates under the Commission's Article 82 Guidance

Plenary #4: Assessing price parity agreements

FERRELLGAS ANTITRUST LAW COMPLIANCE HANDBOOK

Economics and Regulation Anti-trust and Competition services

Revised rules for the assessment of horizontal cooperation agreements under EU competition law

Monopoly Building Why the Justice Department Must Block the Ticketmaster/LiveNation Deal

Buyer-Related Vertical Restraints (Upfront access payments and category management) - Proposed sections in the EC Guidelines on Vertical Restraints

CEMEX. Global Antitrust Compliance Policy

Transcription:

CPI Antitrust Chronicle July 2011 (1) The Unilateral Conduct Working Group: You Be the Judge Scrutinizing a Loyalty Discount & Rebate Case Cynthia Lagdameo (FTC) & Charles Webb (Baker Botts) www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy International, Inc. 2011 Copying, reprinting, or distributing this article is forbidden by anyone other than the publisher or author.

The Unilateral Conduct Working Group: You Be the Judge Scrutinizing a Loyalty Discount & Rebate Case Cynthia Lagdameo & Charles Webb 1 Pricing has never been more complex for companies operating across national borders. In addition to considerations arising from local supply and demand conditions and factors such as national tax laws and exchange rates, companies operating internationally must also take into account the potential effects that different countries competition laws may have on their pricing practices. And over the past two decades, competition laws have proliferated to more than one hundred countries around the world, from micro-states such as Jersey and the Faroe Islands to rising economic superpowers such as Brazil, India and China. The competition laws in virtually all of these countries potentially apply to the unilateral pricing conduct of firms found to have a dominant position. The standards for judging pricing conduct such as loyalty or bundled discounts, predatory pricing, excessive pricing, margin or price squeezes, and discriminatory pricing differ across jurisdictions, sometimes substantially. Even standards within individual jurisdictions can be unsettled or in a state of transition. Likely in no other area of competition law are standards so unsettled. One of the reasons for the widely differing views on a dominant firm s pricing conduct is that pro-competitive and anticompetitive behavior often look the same conduct that may be efficiency enhancing may look the same as conduct that excludes potential entry and forecloses rivals. Virtually all antitrust practitioners would agree that conduct such as competitors agreeing to set prices or divide markets is harmful to consumer welfare and thus must be prohibited. But what about a dominant firm providing discounts or rebates on the sale of its products or services? Consumers and customers, of course, benefit from reduced prices, which are exactly the type of behavior one would expect to see in a competitive market. 2 However, can a dominant firm s prices be too low even if not necessarily below its own costs in a way that results in harm to competition? In such circumstances, how is competitive harm measured? These types of difficult questions involving a dominant firm s discounting practices were recently analyzed by members of the Unilateral Conduct Working Group ( UCWG ) at the 10th Annual Conference of the International Competition Network ( ICN ) in The Hague, Netherlands in May 2011. They were analyzed through the use of a hypothetical abuse of dominance case concerning a company called Cerveja. In this hypothetical, Cerveja has long been the largest supplier of beer in a country called ICNland, with a market share above 70 percent over the past several years and annual sales of approximately $1 billion. It now faces 1 Cynthia Lagdameo is counsel for international antitrust at the U.S. Federal Trade Commission and is the current co-chair of the ICN s Unilateral Conduct Working Group. Charles Webb is a Partner at Baker Botts LLP and a non-governmental advisor to the ICN s Unilateral Conduct Working Group. The views expressed here are those of the authors alone. 2 See, e.g., Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986) ( [C]utting prices in order to increase business often is the very essence of competition. ). 2

increased competition from Hollandia, a major international supplier of beer with global annual sales of over $10 billion. Hollandia entered the supply of beer within ICNland through the acquisition of a local supplier, and grew its national market share from 13 percent to 18 percent in its first full year of operation. In addition to Cerveja and Hollandia, many smaller regional brewers also sell beer in ICNland. In response to increased competition, Cerveja introduced retailer discounts called the So Hoppy Together Program. Under this program, Cerveja paid retailers quarterly and annual rebates based on the volume of Cerveja-brand beer sold during the period. To qualify, retailers had to at least maintain their existing volume sales of Cerveja-brand beer, and could qualify for greater rebates based on increased volume sales. The evidence provided with the hypothetical showed that the discount levels still left prices above Cerveja s total costs, when measured over its entire annual production volume, and retail prices for beer decreased during the period of alleged abuse. Documents provided with the hypothetical, however, demonstrated an intent by Cerveja to maintain and gain market share through the discount program in the face of increased competition from Hollandia. In addition, Cerveja s discounted prices were below the total costs of many of the smaller competitors, potentially undermining their longer-term viability. After considering this hypothetical case in smaller break-out groups, the UCWG held a mock agency hearing before the plenary session of the ICN s 10th Annual Conference. A caseteam argued the case for abuse and a devil s advocate panel 3 argued the case for the defense, before both a two-judge panel and a jury consisting of the audience, comprising nearly 500 ICN delegates from roughly 90 countries. The case team argued that the So Hoppy Together Program was an abuse of dominance, based on: (i) Cerveja s intent to exclude competition as expressed in its internal documents; (ii) structural effects such as increasing barriers to entry and expansion; and (iii) that the discounts were below Cerveja s cost when attributed to the contestable share of the relevant market. The devil s advocate panel argued that Cerveja s discounted prices were not an abuse of dominance because: (i) they remained above Cerveja s average total cost and thus could not foreclose an equally efficient competitor; (ii) there was no cogent and convincing evidence of consumer harm because retail prices decreased during the period of the alleged abuse; (iii) there was no foreclosure effect because Hollandia s national market share increased; and (iv) that Cerveja s intent to compete aggressively through discounts should be viewed as pro-competitive. 4 At the conclusion of the arguments, and perhaps understandably given the unsettled nature of competition law and unilateral pricing conduct, there was a split decision. The mock judge panel agreed with the case team s arguments concluding that the conduct was an abuse of dominance. However, equipped with hand-held voting devices, the ICN s membership in the audience voted by a margin of 56 percent to 44 percent that there was no abuse and the case should be closed. 3 This term refers to a team within an agency used to test the strength of a case. 4This hypothetical was also considered at a Workshop held by the UCWG in Brussels, Belgium in December 2010, attended by over 150 participants from more than 50 ICN jurisdictions. The importance of articulating a convincing story of harm to competition and consumers was stressed at the workshop. A copy of this hypothetical case and workshop materials are available at http://internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/workinggroups/current/unilateral/workshops-teleseminars/upcoming.aspx 3

The differing outcomes between the judges and jury reflect the difficult challenges remaining for the UCWG in building greater convergence among different jurisdictions in the analysis of loyalty discounts and rebates. However, the simple fact that challenges exist does not mean that they are insurmountable, as the UCWG s 2009 Report on Loyalty Discounts and Rebates showed a reasonable degree of consensus on the central aspects of the analysis of such conduct. In that Report several agencies indicated that loyalty discounts and rebates are considered a legitimate form of price competition and are generally pro-competitive. But, when employed by dominant firms, they have the potential to cause anticompetitive harm in certain circumstances. Given the potential benefits to consumers through lower prices, however, several responses expressed a cautious approach to enforcement. 5 Many agencies said this cautious approach was necessary because loyalty discounts and rebates were common forms of business practice within their jurisdictions, and low prices in general are a hallmark of competition. As with the ICN more generally, the primary objective of the UCWG is to promote convergence towards sound analysis and enforcement with respect to the application of competition law to unilateral conduct. The UCWG has taken several steps to promote convergence. 6 Most notably, the Working Group developed Recommended Practices (ICN Recommended Practices) to assist agencies with the assessment of dominance and substantial market power. 7 The ICN Recommended Practices recognize that the concept of dominance or substantial market power limits the scope of application of most unilateral conduct laws. Making dominance or substantial market power a prerequisite serves as a filter for intervention against specific anticompetitive conduct. 8 The ICN Recommended Practices instruct that a firm should not be found to possess dominance/substantial market power without a comprehensive consideration of factors that affect competitive conditions in the market under investigation. The analysis of dominance/substantial market power includes, but does not stop with, the assessment of market shares. At a minimum, conditions of entry and expansion (affecting the durability of market power) also should be assessed. 9 In addition, according to the ICN Recommended Practices, agencies should, where appropriate, take into account factors such as buyer power, economies of scale and scope, network effects, and vertical integration in a dominance assessment. The Working Group analyzed specific types of unilateral conduct and prepared comparative reports on exclusive dealing (2008), predatory pricing (2008), tying and bundled discounting (2009), loyalty discounts and rebates (2009), and refusal to deal with a rival and margin squeeze (2010). 10 These reports are useful not only to explain what individual ICN 5 ICN Report on the Analysis of Loyalty Discounts and Rebates Under Unilateral Conduct Laws (2009), available at http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/uploads/library/doc357.pdf. 6 ICN Report on the Objectives of Unilateral Conduct Laws, Assessment of Dominance/Substantial Market Power, and State-Created Monopolies (2007), available at http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/uploads/library/doc353.pdf ( ICN Objectives Report ). 7 ICN Recommended Practices on the Analysis of Dominance / Substantial Market Power under Unilateral Conduct Laws, available at http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/uploads/library/doc317.pdf. These Recommended Practices were adopted at the ICN s annual conference in 2008. 8 See also ICN Objectives Report, supra note 5. 9 ICN Recommended Practices I.2, supra note 6. 10 The Working Group gathered information through a questionnaire on agencies approaches to assessing the conduct and the criteria used to distinguish pro-competitive from anticompetitive conduct. The Working Group 4

members are doing, but also create a broader framework for discussion over time to reduce uncertainly and provide a better understanding about how to deal with such conduct. After studying how agencies assess single firm conduct in practice, the Working Group began drafting a Unilateral Conduct Workbook. The Workbook provides a definitional framework and common understanding of terms dominance, market power, and market definition. The first chapter drafted covers the methods used to define relevant markets and to assess the existence of dominance, as well as the data and other evidence that might be useful to obtain in performing these investigational steps. The chapter was adopted at the 10th Annual Conference. The Working Group will decide shortly on next topics to address with predatory pricing a likely candidate. Future chapters on forms of conduct will build up the catalog of work to which ICN members can turn. The next stage is to try to agree on common principles and approaches to particular practices. The Working Group anticipates that the process of developing and drafting the Workbook will lead to identifying further areas in which it could productively develop additional recommended practices or other guidance. However, the UCWG recognizes that different views may make achieving consensus in some areas difficult. But even in these areas, and perhaps mostly in these areas, the ICN provides a valuable forum to discuss different viewpoints and share enforcement experiences. The Working Group held webinars on excessive pricing and discriminatory pricing two areas in which there is a significant degree of divergence as to whether and when the conduct violates competition laws. The webinars stimulated a discussion on exploitative abuses and highlighted differences among member agencies laws, policies, and viewpoints. Participants came away with a better understanding of the issues, of alternative ways of approaching the issues, and perhaps some further questions and ideas regarding members own policies in these areas. 11 In summary, therefore, while pricing in different countries will always be a complex exercise for firms, the UCWG will continue to strive for sound enforcement and, where possible, increased convergence in the application of competition laws to unilateral conduct. summarized the responses received from agencies, as well as responses from Non-governmental Advisors, covering between 35 and 45 jurisdictions. The questionnaires, responses, and reports are available on the ICN website at http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/working-groups/current/unilateral.aspx. 11 For further discussion see Lagdameo & Heimert, The Unilateral Conduct Working Group in The International Competition Network, THE INTERNATIONAL COMPETITION NETWORK AT TEN, (Lugard, ed.) (2011). 5