The hypothetical world with which the concept of perfect competition is concerned is one in which markets have the following characteristics:

Similar documents
Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002

Neoclassical Political Economics

Year 1 Term 6 AQA Spec Additional AQA guidance Specification Section(s) The objectives of firms

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

Perfect Competition. Chapter 7 Section Main Menu

Week One What is economics? Chapter 1

Market structures Perfect competition

ECONOMICS CHAPTER 9: FORMS OF MARKET

Joven Liew Jia Wen Industrial Economics I Notes. What is competition?

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002

INTRODUCTION TO MICROECONOMICS

The Model of Perfect Competition

Economic Foundation. Dr. Christoph Stork. Monday, 2 July 12

Objective. Sessions on Economics. Types of Economic Analysis. Session 2

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON

Perfect Competition Chapter 7 Section 1

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

ECONOMICS FOR HEALTH POLICY SPECIAL FEATURES OF HEALTH CARE FROM COSTS OF PRODUCTION TO MARKET SUPPLY CURVES

CHAPTER 8: SECTION 1 A Perfectly Competitive Market

Crossword, Econ 121, Chs. 7-10, Summer 2009

The economics of competitive markets Rolands Irklis

AQA Economics A-level

Domain 3 MICROECONOMICS

Economics for Business. Lecture 1- The Market Forces of Supply and Demand

Economics for Educators

Power Plants Don t Fly And Other Non-Artificial Barriers to Competition in Wholesale Power Markets

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

Economics 110 Final exam Practice Multiple Choice Qs Fall 2013

Economics for Educators

PWNI I'IHITIIBIFI UNIVERSITY EXAMINER(S) INSTRUCTIONS FACULTY OF MANAGEMENT SCIENCES QUALIFICATION: BACHELOR OF ACCOUNTING

AQA Economics A-level

COMPETITION AND MARKETS BEFORE YOU BEGIN. Market Structures. Looking at the Chapter. Date Period. Chapter

1.1 Efficiency in economics What is efficiency in economics?

Brown University ECON 1130, Intermediate Microeconomics (Mathematical) Spring 2017 Class meets Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30 p.m.

Market Failure 24 SEP 2009

Chapter 14 Oligopoly and Monopoly

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education Economics Assessment Unit A2 1. assessing. Business Economics [AE211] MONDAY 11 MAY, MORNING

4. A situation in which the number of competing firms is relatively small is known as A. Monopoly B. Oligopoly C. Monopsony D. Perfect competition

Come & Join Us at VUSTUDENTS.net

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

ECO 2023 Principles of Microeconomics Fall 2013 Practice Test #2. 1. Which of the following are factors of production?

Principles of Microeconomics Assignment 8 (Chapter 10) Answer Sheet. Class Day/Time

Consumer Behavior & Public Policy. Lecture #3 Microeconomics

Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002

THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION: COMPETITIVE ACTIVITIES

CIPS Exam Report for Learner Community:

S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key. Instruction:

Economics Chapter 8 Competition and Markets

Economics Chapter 8 Competition and Markets

Lecture 11 Imperfect Competition

Unit 6: Non-Competitive Markets

The Handbook of Competition Economics

Use the following to answer question 4:

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

Market Structure - Oligopoly

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Econ Microeconomics Notes

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry

The Evolution of Contestable Markets: A Computing Simulation

ENERGY ECONOMICS. 28 March - 05 April MICROECONOMICS part 2

WJEC (Wales) Economics A-level

full file at

Economics: Introduction

Some remarks on pricing abuses

WJEC (Eduqas) Economics A-level

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

Economic Profit. Accounting. Profit. Explicit. Costs. Implicit costs (including a normal profit) Accounting. costs (explicit costs only) T O T A L

FIRM SUPPLY: MARKET STRUCTURE & PERFECT COMPETITION

23115 ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS Lecture 1: Market forces of supply and demand

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

Business Economics. Introduction: Market Structure and the Equilibrium:

Microeconomics Exam Notes

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2010 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

BA5101 ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS MBA/IYear/ I Semester 2 Marks Questions & Answers

MANAGERIAL MODELS OF THE FIRM

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 6. I. Choose the correct answer (each question carries 1 mark)

Environmental Economic Theory No. 2

1 Which of the following is the best description of a monopolistically competitive industry?

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 33 Oligopoly (Contd )

CHAPTER 3. Economic system Market structure Consumer price index

Economics. Monopolistic Competition. Firms in Competitive Markets. Monopolistic Competition 11/22/2012. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

Practice Test for Final

Economics. Monopolistic Perfect Competition. Monopolistic Competition. Monopolistic Competition 11/29/2013. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

AQA Economics AS-level

Introduction Question Bank

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

SEMESTER Examination Paper (COVER PAGE) Time : pm Reading Time : Nil

AS Economics: ECON1 Economics: Markets and Market Failure 2009/10

NB: STUDENTS ARE REQUESTED IN THEIR OWN INTEREST TO WRITE LEGIBLY AND IN INK.

Transcription:

Competition From Citizendium, the Citizens' Compendium Competition is a means by which limited resources can be allocated among rival bidders. The degree to which it is present in a market has a strong influence upon pricing in that market. Unrestricted or perfect competition is a hypothetical condition in which no-one is able to influence the market price of a product. At the other extreme, absolute monopoly, or the total absence of competition in the supply of a product, would give its holder the sole ability to influence the market price of that product. Perfect competition and total monopoly are conditions which can readily be analysed to give definite and straightforward answers, and for that reason they provide a valuable starting-point to the study of the microeconomics of market behaviour. Competition theory, is concerned with economic behaviour in markets whose characteristics lie between those hypothetical extremes. Its practical importance lies in the fact that competition or its absence can have a major influence upon the welfare of a community. Contents 1 Perfect Competition 1.1 Definition 1.2 Efficiency implications 1.3 Externalities 1.4 The second-best 1.5 Contestability 2 Monopoly and oligopoly 2.1 Pure monopoly 2.2 Market power 3 Policy Implications 3.1 Competition policy implications 3.2 Dissenting views 4 References Perfect Competition Definition The hypothetical world with which the concept of perfect competition is concerned is one in which markets have the following characteristics: (a) All market shares are small. No supplier enjoys a share of the market which is large enough to enable him to influence the price of that category of product. (b) No collusion. Each supplier acts independently.

(c) No barriers to entry. There is nothing to prevent any new supplier from entering the market for any category of product. (d) Homogeneity of product. All suppliers of each category of product are known to all buyers to supply identical products. Suppliers are assumed to maximise their products and buyers are assumed to seek value for money. After a settling-down period, a market price emerges for each category of product. A supplier who attempts to sell a product above that price will find no buyers and a buyer who attempts to buy a product at below that price will find no sellers. Those characteristics define the conditions for perfect competition among suppliers of products. They may similarly be defined in relation to suppliers of labour. And for pure competition to apply to the market as a whole, conditions analogous to (a) and (b) must also be satisfied by buyers: there must be no dominant buyers, and buyers must not collude. Efficiency implications According to the theorems of welfare economics a market which is in equilibrium in a state of perfect competition is "Pareto-efficient" [1], which is a condition from which no change could make anyone feel better-off without making someone else feel worse-off. The term optimal resource allocation is used to describe the theoretical outcome for the community as a whole. In non-technical language, this can be taken to mean the efficient allocation of resources as between different categories of product. Perfect competition ensures that the community's resources are used efficiently in the sense of making people feel well-off. If resources are allocated optimally, then people would not, for example, feel better off if they were able to afford more meat and less fish, nor vice versa. It cannot, however, be concluded that perfect competition maximises total economic efficiency. Competition theory,as outlined above, says nothing about productive efficiency, which is a component of economic efficiency. Nor is it strictly correct to say that perfect competition maximises economic welfare [2]. That concept encompasses the way in which wealth is distributed as between different members of the community, and it cannot be claimed that perfect competition necessarily leads to an ideal distribution of wealth. The propositions which emerge from the concept of perfect competition are to do with the way in which resources are allocated between products, and not with how the product is manufactured, or to whom it is distributed. Externalities The outcome will not necessarily be efficient if any supplier can impose costs on others. In economics terminology these are termed externalities. The conventional example is a supplier who pollutes the environment. The allocation of resources need not then be efficient because of the possibility that some people would feel better off with fewer goods in exchange for a cleaner atmosphere. Other examples include traffic congestion and mining subsidence. The theoretically ideal solution is for the polluter to compensate those affected. The second-best If universal perfect competition were taken as the starting-point, there would be strong presumption that any departure from it will lead to a loss of economic efficiency. But, if the starting-point were one in which some markets are not perfectly competitive, it cannot be concluded that efficiency would be increased by restoring any one of them to perfect competition. This is a matter of some practical importance. For example it might be better from the consumer's standpoint to deal with a monopoly supplier of gas that is faced with a monopoly supplier of

electricity, rather than an alternative in which the gas supplier would be free to exploit his monopoly power in face of a fragmented electricity supply industry. The theory of the second-best, as this is called, may seem seriously to undermine the application of competition theory, but in practice its implications are often less formidable. There is a clear need to take account of linkages between markets such as exist between the markets for gas and electricity. and there are many instances in which such linkages are so weak that the direct benefits of an increase in competition would clearly outweigh any adverse secondary effect. Cases are bound to arise, nonetheless, in which there is no analytical solution to the problem of the second-best. Contestability Competition theory was augmented in the 1970s by analytical developments [3] in which the concept of perfect competition was replaced as a benchmark by the concept of perfect contestability. This has provided a new way of looking at competition. A perfectly contestable market was defined as one into which entry is absolutely free and exit is absolutely costless. If the initial outlays required for entry to a market were recoverable without loss, then any risk which might otherwise attach to entry could be eliminated. A new supplier who could see a profitable opportunity of entering a market in which prices had previously been raised by the exercise of market power would be aware that those prices would be likely to fall again as a result of his entry. But, given the opportunity of costless exit, that would not deter him from entering. There would be nothing to lose, provided that he remained in the market for only so long as it continued to be profitable to do so. Faced by such a threat, a monopoly supplier in a perfectly contestable market would thus be deterred from setting his prices at above the level which would rule under perfect competition by the knowledge that to do so would be to encourage entry. If successful entry actually occurred, he would eventually be forced to reduce his prices to the level which would rule under perfect competition in order to survive Monopoly and oligopoly Pure monopoly The importance of the concept of perfect competition to the philosophy of competition policy is that it serves as a datum, or baseline, from which the departures which occur in the real world can be measured. It defines one of the polar extremes of possible real-world situations. The other polar extreme is perfect monopoly that is to say, a product market in which the product has only one supplier and into which no other supplier can enter. Like perfect competition, this is a situation which can readily be analysed to produce unequivocal results. The diagrammatic analysis which appears in the standard economic textbooks demonstrates that under these circumstances the profitmaximising supplier would provide smaller quantities of the product, and at a higher price, than would be the case under perfect competition. The mechanism which leads to that unsurprising conclusion is of more interest than the conclusion itself. It rests on the fact that the monopolist always has the freedom to choose between supplying a greater quantity at a lower price and supplying a smaller quantity at a higher price. Market power The existence of such choices is said to confer market power upon the supplier in question. The possession of market power in that sense is not, however, confined to perfect monopolies. There are many markets in the real world in which there are several suppliers, each of which is large enough to enjoy a degree of market power in the sense of having some degree of choice concerning pricing policy. A great deal of theoretical work has been done on the subject but straightforward answers concerning the behaviour of a profit-maximising supplier in such an oligopolistic market are hard to find. The reason is that analysis of such markets is complicated by the need to

postulate how each supplier reacts to the likely behaviour of his competitors, and by the need for a precise understanding of each supplier's cost structure. Policy Implications Competition policy implications Competition theory provides the intellectual foundation for antitrust and competition policy but it does not provide all that is needed to build a serviceable structure upon that foundation. It does not lead to unequivocal prescriptions except where competition is the only question at issue - and even then the questions of externalities and of the second-best may introduce qualifications. Where the issue of gains in productive efficiency also arises, other branches of economic theory must be called in aid. The difficulties which then arise stem not so much from the limitations of the available theory, as from the fact that quantification is then needed in order to draw up a balance between losses of allocative efficiency and gains of productive efficiency. The information requirements for that purpose tend to be demanding, and commercial accounting systems are seldom capable of providing the necessary inputs. In practical terms, therefore, the economic rationale for competition policy is incomplete and, at best, its implementation depends partly upon judgement rather than entirely upon analysis. Dissenting views Critics have argued that the entire rationale of mainstream competition theory is flawed by virtue of its methodology. That methodology, which is termed comparative statics, envisages a system which settles down to a stable equilibrium. The properties of that equilibrium are then analysed as though it were a static situation. In reality, of course, the postulated settling-down process may never end. New techniques and new products may emerge in a continuing stream; new firms may come into existence to turn the resulting opportunities into reality, and other firms may fail. Above all, there are uncertainties; and entrepreneurs are rewarded if successful for taking risks. None of those vital characteristics of the competitive process can be embodied in a comparative statics analysis. Consequently, it is argued, that form of analysis is inappropriate to the problem. The principal proponents of that line of argument are the Austrian School of economists, and their case is more extensively summarised in Littlechild (1986)[4] and Reekie (1979)[5] References 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. The term "Pareto-efficient" is defined in the articles on economic efficiency and welfare economics The concept of economic welfare is explained in the article on welfare economics Baumol Contestable Markets, in The American Economic Review, Vol. 72, No. 1, March 1982 Littlechild The Fallacy of the Mixed Economy, Hobart Paper No. 80, Institute of Economic Affairs 1986 Reekie Industry, Prices and Markets, Phillip Alan 1979. Retrieved from "http://en.citizendium.org/wiki/competition" Categories: CZ Live Economics Workgroup All Content Economics Content Views Page Discussion View source

History Personal tools Log in Search Go To Page Search This page was last modified 01:58, 20 February 2010. CZ is free. All original articles are available under the Creative Commons-Attribution-ShareAlike 3.0 Unported license or any later. Articles that originated in part from Wikipedia are also available under GNU Free Documentation License 1.2. Servers and hosting generously provided by Steadfast Networks