If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an to

Similar documents
(Text with EEA relevance) (2009/C 45/02) I. INTRODUCTION

On the Art 82 enforcement priorities Effects on consumer welfare

A GUIDELINE FOR CONDUCTING MARKET REVIEWS

Vertical restraints, digital marketplaces, and enforcement tools

ABUSE OF DOMINANCE. John Pheasant Lecture to National Law University, Jodhpur 24 January 2014

Abuse of dominance Evidentiary issues: European overview. Maarten Schueler Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM)

Prohibition of the abuse of a dominant position

The Abuse of a Dominant Market Position. Mihail Busu, PhD Romanian Competition Council

Non-horizontal mergers

Gathering, handling and assessing evidence EU-China Competition Week Beijing, 14 March 2014

Green Paper on Unfair Trading Practices (UTPs) in the business-to-business food and non food supply chain in Europe

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

THE TETRA PAK CASE: ARE LOYALTY REBATES TREATED DIFFERENTLY BY THE CHINESE ANTITRUST REGULATOR?

Big Data and Competition Law Preliminary thoughts

Review of the 2002 SMP Guidelines. Anthony Whelan WIK workshop Revising the SMP Guidelines 27 March 2018

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

Some remarks on pricing abuses

DRAFT. Mike Walker A brief survey of the economic thinking on bundling and tying

October Your Business and Competition Law. How it helps you & what you need to know

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

Edexcel Economics A-level

Buyer-Related Vertical Restraints (Upfront access payments and category management) - Proposed sections in the EC Guidelines on Vertical Restraints

DRAFT COMMISSION GUIDELINES ON THE ASSESSMENT OF NON- HORIZONTAL MERGERS

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

Vertical Restraints, Exclusive Dealing, and Competition on the Merits

How Antitrust Agencies Analyze M&A

Safeguarding Competition in the Hong Kong Telcommunications Market

Promoting Competition

Economics and Regulation Anti-trust and Competition services

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin

THE EU MERGER REGULATION: SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES

COMPETITION LAW AND STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES Contribution from Sweden

Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

AQA Economics A-level

How big worldwide is yearly unconventional gas production today? 50 bcm. 250 bcm. 450 bcm. 900 bcm. Source: Stanisław Rychlicki PGNiG S.A..

Samson Esayas, NRCCL

An economic approach to exclusionary rebates?

Jet-Kingfisher Merger Competition Issues

Remedies to the adverse effects of. Myriam Vander Stichele SOMO

ICN Merger Working Group: Analytical Framework Sub-group THE ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK FOR MERGER CONTROL

What makes unilateral conduct abusive? An economic perspective

Joven Liew Jia Wen Industrial Economics I Notes. What is competition?

Towards an effects based approach to price discrimination. Anne Perrot «Pros and Cons 2005» Stockholm

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

Competition law aspects of distribution in the online world

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

The University of Oxford Centre for Competition Law and Policy

Anti-competitive exclusionary conduct in EU antitrust practice

Entry analysis in merger investigations ICN Merger Working Group Workshop

Honesty pays. How to detect and prevent bid-rigging cartels INFORMATION FROM THE SWEDISH COMPETITION AUTHORITY

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE U.S. AND THE EU: WHY THEY DIFFER?

Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39

SAA cases and the emphasis on the economic impact of the abusive conduct

Introduction. The findings. The wider context ANTITRUST

2. Facebook is a US American company. Why does the Bundeskartellamt have competence to investigate in this case?

Oligopolies in electronic communications: more concentration, more regulation?

Limited distribution: a self-assessment exercise

Agency Name: Office of Competition and Consumer Protection, Poland Date: December 16, 2008 Tying & Bundled Discounting

ICN Recommended Practices for Merger Analysis and Model ICN Guides. MICHELE PACILLO, AGCM ITALY MWG Workshop Washington DC February 16, 2017

Session on International Enforcement Perspectives Federal Trade Commission and Antitrust Division Hearings on Section 2 of the Sherman Act

antitrust complying with and using competition law

Long-term. energy contracts. Building Markets through Antitrust. MIT- EDF Conference in Paris July Adrien De Hauteclocque

Collusion and horizontal agreements

Competition Issues in Aftermarkets - Note from Italy

Predatory pricing. Cédric Argenton. March Tilburg University. CA (Tilburg University) Predatory pricing 03/15 1 / 18

Most Favored Nation Clauses: Is It the End of the Road?

How to Asses the Impact of Uses of IP on Competition

Measuring exclusionary effects under Article 82

Regulating Competition in the Malaysian Communications Industry

Market analytic toolkit For assessing public service markets. Interactive

PAYMENT SERVICES DIRECTIVE 2 WHAT IS ALL THE FUSS ABOUT ANYWAY?

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

The Unilateral Conduct Working Group: You Be the Judge Scrutinizing a Loyalty Discount & Rebate Case

Buyer-Driven Vertical Restraints

Anti-competitive exclusionary conduct in EU antitrust practice

EDITORIAL THE ARTICLE 82 DISCUSSION PAPER: A MISSED OPPORTUNITY SIMON BISHOP AND PHILIP MARSDEN

THE E.C. GREEN PAPER ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS: OPTION IV DEFENDED. Trinity Economic Paper Series Paper 99/8 JEL Classification: L42

GOVERNMENT OF MALAWI MINISTRY OF COMMERCE AND INDUSTRY COMPETITION POLICY FOR MALAWI

The value of future damages claims in energy: proven, probable or possible?

Innovation Management. Innovation Strategies Francesca Cabiddu 25-27/05/2015

KOREA FAIR TRADE COMMISSION

ROMANIA S EXPERIENCE ON THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE COMPETITION AUTHORITY AND THE SECTOR REGULATORS

Mergers: Commission clears proposed merger between Telefónica Deutschland (Telefónica) E-Plus subject to conditions-frequently asked questions

Information exchanges and joint negotiations EU position. Keith Jones (London)

WJEC (Wales) Economics A-level

FORDHAM CORPORATE LAW INSTITUTE

Market studies. Guidance on the OFT approach

WJEC (Eduqas) Economics A-level

How to strengthen competition advocacy through competition screening Geraldine EMBERGER, Directorate-General Competition, unit A-5

How will you manage the impact of the Payment Services Directive 2?

Discussion Points. Presented by the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) to the OECD Competition Committee

Rebates: Formalism, Effects and the Real World

Predatory Pricing. 2. Please list your jurisdiction s criteria for an abuse of dominance/monopolization based on predatory pricing.

Competition Law & Policy in India

Competition and personal data protection

Information Exchange and Hub & Spoke Cartels

EU and Swedish Competition policy in practice

BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation. Questions to stakeholders

Key principles of market regulation in telecommunications

Transcription:

1/5 June 2016

Introduction The Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM) creates opportunities and options for businesses and consumers. By fighting against unfair competition and making it easier for new entrants to enter markets, ACM improves competition. Competition leads to innovation and more choice for consumers. New players and technologies may have the potential to change the competitive landscape. ACM therefore strives to improve the likelihood that these new developments will have a positive and lasting impact on competition. The financial sector is currently witnessing the emergence of technologies that can offer new and innovative financial services ( FinTech ). It has been widely recognized that FinTech may be an important driving force for competition, consumer choice and innovation in the market. However, it may also bring new risks for competition. ACM is keen to help FinTech to reach its full potential. Engaging with parties involved with FinTech will enable ACM to focus its activities on what really matters for the further development of FinTech. If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an e-mail to FinTech@acm.nl. FinTech and competition 2/5 ACM has done extensive research into competition in several markets in the financial sector. Although there are large differences within the sector, a picture that often emerges is that of an oligopoly with significant barriers to entry. For many financial services, a few large firms have the lion s share of the market. The studies have also shown that competition does not always work effectively in these markets. FinTech may have the potential to improve this. There are many views on how FinTech will ultimately change the financial sector. This document is not about trying to pick the right long term view of the future. In order to focus its activities, ACM is especially interested in barriers that prevent FinTech from reaching its full potential. This means that ACM pays special attention to barriers that hinder the development of FinTech. For example, certain behaviour of established market parties may undermine the chances of new entrants to successfully enter a market. There may also be risks involved with rapid technological change. Changing market structures may have adverse effects on competition and innovation. ACM s role in FinTech ACM enforces Dutch and EU competition law. Among other things, this includes detecting cartels and abuses of a dominant position. ACM can and has imposed large fines on parties involved in these practices. ACM receives a large number of signals concerning possible infringements of competition law. The choice of which cases to pursue is for an important part based on the impact of the possible infringement on consumers. This means that ACM would pursue a FinTech related case if it involves a significant harm to competition and hence consumers.

There are also other ways in which ACM may get involved to unlock FinTech s potential. For example, ACM could engage more actively in the national implementation of European regulation, such as the revised Payment Services Directive (PSD-2). In this role, ACM would try to make sure that the competition perspective stays in focus. Another possibility would be for ACM to perform a market study. ACM has performed several market studies into competition in the financial sector. Most of these studies uncovered barriers to competition. Where appropriate, ACM made recommendations to lower these barriers. A good example is a study into barriers to entry in the Dutch retail banking sector that ACM performed in 2014. This study made a number of recommendations to the Minister of Finance on how to lower barriers for new entrants. ACM could perform a similar study to uncover possible barriers to competition in FinTech. This could again lead to concrete recommendations to policy makers, aimed at improving competition. It should be clear that ACM focusses on improving competition by stimulating pro-competitive effects of FinTech, while trying to prevent possible risks FinTech may bring for competition. Other supervisory authorities may have a (slightly) different focus and objective, but ACM is convinced that cooperation among supervisory authorities will assist in reaching each of these objectives. Factors that ACM is especially interested in 3/5 Many parties involved in FinTech are well aware of ACM s role and powers. However, other parties may not. To provide more guidance for the latter group, this section lists some hypothetical examples of factors where ACM may play a role. These are not the only factors that will determine the success or failure of FinTech. For example, regulatory barriers may also be important. These factors have not been included because they have already been well identified and/or do not directly require attention from ACM, but from government or other supervisory authorities. There is an abundance of (economic) literature that identifies factors that either stimulate or hinder competition. This is not the place for an extensive overview of these factors. However, it may be useful to give an idea of typical factors that have an impact on competition. ACM has grouped these in three categories. 1. Anti-competitive behaviour of firms Firms can try to defend or improve their position by engaging in anti-competitive behaviour. This should not be confused with normal pro-competitive behaviour (harm to competitors), which is a common and necessary element of a market economy. Anti-competitive behaviour leads to harm to competition and ultimately to consumers. There are a lot of different forms of anticompetitive behaviour. Two of the main examples are foreclosure and collusion. Foreclosure means that a large firm tries to drive a competitor from a significant part of the market. This can be achieved by, e.g., refusing a competitor access to a necessary input, a

refusal to deal with a competitor, setting predatory prices or bundling/tying products. Collusion occurs when two or more firms engage in cooperative behaviour with the goal of improving their position to the detriment of competition and consumers. Collusion can be both explicit or tacit, but the effect on market outcome is basically the same. Examples of anti-competitive behaviour in a FinTech context may be: - Banks refuse FinTechs access to the bank account or transaction/customer data, e.g., by non-compliance with the goals of the PSD-2; - BigTechs such as Apple and Google and/or banks foreclose efficient financial services providers by leveraging their strong position in other markets; - Stronger collaboration between new and existing market players leads to (tacit) collusion at the expense of consumers; - Setting standards in a way that leads to potential foreclosure of new market players. 2. High concentration and entry barriers It is generally accepted that a market that is characterised by high concentration and high entry barriers tends to be less competitive. In a highly concentrated market, one or a few firms supply a (very) large part of the market. When existing competitors or potential entrants are not capable to exert a competitive constraint on these large firms, this may lead to harm to competition and consumers. For example, capacity constraints can make it difficult for competitors to respond to a price increase of a large firm. Entry barriers, such as authorisation procedures and capital requirements, make the competitive constraint from potential entrants less effective. 4/5 Examples where FinTech may increase concentration or entry barriers in financial markets are: - FinTech leads to markets in which economies of scale are so large that there is only room for one or two big players: the market tips to dominant positions of, e.g., BigTechs keeping smaller FinTechs out of the market; - Market fragmentation causes dominant positions of (possibly relatively small) companies that have specialised in a niche; - Existing players take over new maverick entrants in order to prevent a change in the competitive landscape; - Authorisation regimes favour existing players, thereby denying new players the possibility of constraining competition effectively. 3. Consumer inertia A key driver of effective competition in a market is the consumer s ability to exercise choice. Consumers need access to information in order to compare different offerings and, once they have chosen the one that best satisfies their needs, they must be able to act on this choice. Furthermore, the threat of consumers switching to a competitor provides incentives for firms to improve the products and services they offer, for example by lowering prices, improving quality and investing in

innovation and product development. Competition suffers when consumers do not exert this competitive constraint. There can be a variety of reasons for this. Search costs make it more difficult for consumers to obtain sufficient information on the products that are offered. These costs will be higher when there are a lot of different products on the market and when transparency on product features is low. Switching costs occur when a consumer faces costs that are directly caused by his decision to change supplier. These costs can be avoided by sticking with the same supplier. Examples of consumer inertia in a FinTech context are: - An ever-increasing number of new services leaves large groups of consumers confused and unable to make an informed choice; - BigTechs and/or banks successfully develop must-have products and bundle them with other products; - Firms try to lock in clients with long term contracts. Do you have input for ACM? It is very useful for ACM to receive input of parties involved in FinTech. This will enable ACM to focus its activities on what really matters for the further development of FinTech. 5/5 If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an e-mail to FinTech@acm.nl.