Nominal rigidities without literal menu costs: evidence from E-commerce

Similar documents
CAN COMPETITIVE FORCES REINFORCE NOMINAL WAGE RIGIDITIES?

Menu Costs, Posted Prices, and Multiproduct Retailers*

September 2006 REAL RIGIDITIES * David Romer University of California, Berkeley

A Multi-Level Theory Approach to Understanding Price Rigidity in Internet Retailing*

End of 9-Endings and Price Perceptions

Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment*

Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment*

Does Consumer Price Rigidity Exist in Barbados?

Dynamic Pricing and the Economic Paradigm Shift A Study Based on Consumer Behaviour in the E-commerce Sector

THE CYCLICAL BEHAVIOR OF PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM SEVEN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Business Cycles. Business Cycles. Bilgin Bari

Working Paper Series. On Implications of Micro Price Data for Macro Models. No 960 / November by Bartosz Maćkowiak and Frank Smets

Asymmetric Price Adjustment In a Menu-Cost Model *

SHOULD WE EXPECT LESS PRICE RIGIDITY IN THE DIGITAL ECONOMY?

real rigidities The definition of real rigidities Real rigidities and business cycles

Choosing between time and state dependence: Micro evidence on firms price-reviewing strategies

Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1

Beyond the Hype of Frictionless Markets: Evidence of Heterogeneity in Price Rigidity on the Internet

The Relation between Inventory Investment and Price Dynamics in a Distributive Firm

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Modeling occupancy in single person offices

Pricing Behavior of Multiproduct Firms

Beyond the Cost of Price Adjustment: Investments in Pricing Capital

Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment*

Shattering the Myth of Costless Price Changes: Emerging Perspectives on Dynamic Pricing

Course on Data Analysis and Interpretation P Presented by B. Unmar. Sponsored by GGSU PART 1

Central European University Department of Economics. 2. Lecturer Attila Ratfai (Part 2 of the course is taught by Alessia Campolmi)

Twas four weeks before Christmas: Retail sales and the length of the Christmas shopping season

Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China

A Survey of the Price-Setting Behaviour of Canadian Companies

Holiday Non-Price Rigidity and Cost of Adjustment*

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

A STUDY ON CUSTOMER PERCEPTION TOWARDS ONLINE SHOPPING FACILITIES PROVIDED BY SELECT WEBSITES

Internet Based Supply Chain Strategies

[Rajeswari, 4(9) September, 2017] ISSN: IMPACT FACTOR

The concept of sticky prices has been one of the most common explanations

Economics for Managers. Paul G. Farnham Second Edition

A Tale of Two Rigidities: Sticky Prices in a Sticky-Information Environment. Edward S. Knotek II * Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City December 2007

INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF RESEARCH SCIENCE & MANAGEMENT

Proven Strategies for Finding Profitable Seller Carryback Notes

Government Debt and Demand for Money: A Cointegration Approach

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Journal of Monetary Economics

A Study of Consumer Behavior of Online Shoppers towards e-stores with Especial Reference to Pune. * Dr. S.G. Walke

Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment

Consumer s buying behavior towards online shopping. *Balamurugan K and Munish Kumar M. Abstract

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture

Price Setting Behaviour of Pakistani Firms: Evidence from Four Industrial Cities of Punjab

JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL ACADEMIC RESEARCH FOR MULTIDISCIPLINARY Impact Factor 1.393, ISSN: , Volume 2, Issue 3, April 2014

STAGGERED PRICE AND WAGE SETTING IN MACROECONOMICS *

Antitrust Law Update

Eyal Carmi. Google, 76 Ninth Avenue, New York, NY U.S.A. Gal Oestreicher-Singer and Uriel Stettner

Asymmetric price adjustment in the small*

Running head: Internet Auctions and Frictionless Commerce

Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI)

Exit from regional manufacturing markets: The role of entrant experience

Are Prices Procyclical? : A Disaggregate Level Analysis *

Jersey Competition Regulatory Authority ( JCRA ) Decision M266/08. Proposed Acquisition

ONE of the popular theories of price rigidity is the

Online Appendix for Are Online and Offline Prices Similar? Evidence from Multi-Channel Retailers

Management Competencies and SME Performance Criteria: A Pilot Study December 2003

Study Guide For Macroeconomics, Fourth Canadian Edition By Olivier Blanchard;David W. Johnson

Dynamics of Price Adjustments: Evidence from Micro Level data for Chile

Technological Diffusion News

International Journal of Interdisciplinary Research in Arts and Humanities (IJIRAH) Impact Factor: 5.225, ISSN (Online):

THE RESPONSE OF FINANCIAL AND GOODS MARKETS TO VELOCITY INNOVATIONS: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION FOR THE US*

Senior Exam Spring 2011

Shattering the Myth of Costless Price Changes

Osaka University of Economics Working Paper Series. No Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path

Price Points and Price Rigidity

Online versus In-Store: Price Differentiation for Multi-Channel Retailers

Discussion of Currency Choice and Exchange Rate Pass-Through by Gopinath, Itskhoki and Rigobon

The Pricing Behavior of Firms in the Euro Area: New Survey Evidence

A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, Paper by: Robert H. Porter

BSc. (Hons) Entrepreneurial Management. Cohort: BENM/06/PT Year 3. Examinations for / Semester 1

1 Pricing objectives and strategies: a cross-country survey Vithala R. Rao and Benjamin Kartono*

Operations. The value of hotel-direct bookings is measured by more than numbers. sign up SIGN UP FOR THE NEWSLETTER. Revenue Management

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

DRAFT FOR DISCUSSION AND REVIEW, NOT TO BE CITED OR QUOTED

A Planned Course Statement for. Economics, AP. Length of Period (mins.) 41 Total Clock Hours: 123. Periods per Cycle: 6 Length of Course (yrs.) 1.

Business Design for e-commerce. Schedule. Date Topic Readings

No Bernd Hayo and Matthias Neuenkirch. Bank of Canada Communication, Media Coverage, and Financial Market Reactions

Measuring the Benefits to Sniping on ebay: Evidence from a Field Experiment

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

The New Keynesian Approach to Business Cycle Theory: Nominal and Real Rigidities

3) Confidence interval is an interval estimate of the population mean (µ)

Syllabus for M.Com. Programme. Semester I & II

Research Methodology

Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and. Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping *

Multiproduct Firms and Price-Setting: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Producer Prices

Thomas Bittmann, Patrick Holzer and Jens-Peter Loy

Kristin Gustavson * and Ingrid Borren

Behavioural Economics

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 11. Classical and Keynesian Macro Analyses

Asymmetric Price Adjustment in the Small: An Implication of Rational Inattention*

Volume Author/Editor: W. Erwin Diewert, John S. Greenlees and Charles R. Hulten, editors

ENVIRONMENTAL UNCERTAINTY AND CIOS' ASSESSMENTS OF INFORMATION SYSTEMS ISSUES

Price setting problem: Rigidities

Asymmetric Price Adjustment in the Small*

Transcription:

Economics Letters 86 (2005) 187 191 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Nominal rigidities without literal menu costs: evidence from E-commerce Rajesh Chakrabarti a, *, Barry Scholnick b a College of Management, Georgia Institute of Technology, 800 West Peachtree Street, Atlanta, GA 30332, USA b University of Alberta, School of Business for funding, Canada Received 5 December 2003; received in revised form 21 April 2004; accepted 16 June 2004 Available online 10 November 2004 Abstract Using price data from online book retailers, Amazon.com and Barnes and Noble.com, we show that nominal rigidities persist in an environment that is free from literal menu costs. Menu costs, therefore, are not the prime reason for nominal rigidities. D 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Menu costs; Price rigidities JEL classification: E30 1. Introduction Keynesian theorists have argued that menu costs induce nominal price rigidities that can cause business cycle dynamics (see Gordon 1990 for a review). Taken literally, dmenu costst refer to the cost of implementing price changes. Levy et al. (1997) and Dutta et al., 1999 have sought to measure such literal menu costs using store and product level data and found them to be considerable. Others, like Gordon, (1990), Ball and Mankiw (1994) and Mankiw and Reis (2002), have argued that bmenu costsq should be interpreted more broadly and should include decision-making costs as well. * Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 404 894 5109; fax: +1 404 894 6030. E-mail address: rajesh.chakrabarti@mgt.gatech.edu (R. Chakrabarti). 0165-1765/$ - see front matter D 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2004.06.016

188 R. Chakrabarti, B. Scholnick / Economics Letters 86 (2005) 187 191 Table 1 Descriptive statistics Amazon Barnes and Noble Number of books 3124 3124 Number of weeks 56 56 Total number of changes 7759 7160 Average proportion of books changing prices per week 0.04 0.04 Avg. number of changes per book 2.48 2.29 Standard deviation of number of changes 0.21 0.20 Maximum number of changes (in a particular book price in 56 weeks) 16 17 Minimum number of changes 0 0 Because different reasons for nominal price rigidities (e.g. menu costs or managerial or customer costs) can result in very different macroeconomic dynamics (Mankiw and Reis, 2002), it is important to differentiate between them. Empirically, however, it is difficult to distinguish between the literal menu costs and managerial and customer costs in their effect on nominal rigidities as they generally occur together. The Internet, however, provides an environment where literal bmenu costsq are almost wholly absent with price changes being implemented with a few keystrokes. For instance, the largest element of menu costs, according to Levy et al. (1997), consists of blabor cost of price changesq followed by blabor cost of sign changesq. These are precisely the kinds of costs that are altogether absent in the online environment. Here, we examine the price change behavior of two leading e-retailers Amazon.com and Barnes and Noble.com to study if the absence of such costs removes all nominal rigidities. We find strong evidence that nominal price rigidities revealed by synchronization of price changes persist even in the absence of literal menu costs. Blinder (1991) and Blinder et al. (1998) list many other reasons why prices are sticky. Several of them, like varying delivery lags (service rather than price) and coordination failure, carry over to the internet and cannot be ruled out by our study. We only establish that nominal rigidities persist in the absence of literal menu costs, so the latter cannot be their prime cause. 2. Data Our data comprises weekly price observations for 3124 books from Amazon and Barnes and Noble for a period of 57 weeks March 20, 2000 to April 22, 2001 obtained entirely from the respective web sites. We extract price information for a sample of 3124 books for which a price is available at each store for all 57 weeks by constructing a set of International Standard Book Number (ISBN) 1 obtained from an online book-selling site beven better.comq and using a dbott a web-based program. The prices recorded do not include any frequent buyer or other discounts. Following the extant literature on measuring nominal rigidity (see Lach and Tsiddon, 1996; Fisher and Konieczny, 2000), we create a panel of zeros (no price change over a week) and ones (some price change over a week) for each book, for each store for 56 weeks. Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics of the data. 1 From a site originally called www.evenbetter.com. During our study, it was acquired by a more general comparison shopping site, DealTime.com (www.dealtime.com).

R. Chakrabarti, B. Scholnick / Economics Letters 86 (2005) 187 191 189 3. Analysis We largely follow the methodology used in Lach and Tsiddon (1996) and Fisher and Konieczny (2000). These authors develop tests for the extent to which synchronization occurs when multi-product stores change the price of their products. If there were no nominal rigidities, then price changes across products would be distributed across time i.e. no synchronization. Alternatively, if all prices where changed at the same time (i.e. synchronization), this would imply significant nominal rigidities. The results of the various tests used here not only corroborate one another but also indicate the robustness of our findings. In 43 of the 56 weeks, Amazon changes less than 3% of its book prices while in the three weeks with maximum price changes it changes the prices of over 37% books. For Barnes and Noble, less than 5% of books experience price changes in 49 of the 56 weeks, while in the top 2 weeks prices change for well over 20% of the books. 3.1. Tests of synchronization Our first test is based on Fisher and Konieczny (2000). Since on average there are 2.48 price changes per book at Amazon and 2.29 price changes at Barnes and Noble, a case of perfect synchronization would imply a series of three ones and 53 zeros for either store with the associated standard deviation of 0.225 reflecting perfect synchronization. Perfect staggering will imply a constant series. Thus, the ratio S:D: r ¼ observed S:D: perfect synchronization ; 0VrV1, provides a measure of the degree of synchronization in price changes. For Amazon (S.D.=0.076) r=0.34, while that for Barnes and Noble (S.D.=0.045) it is 0.2. Thus, the degree of price synchronization observed here is at least as high if not higher than that found for Canadian newspapers by Fisher and Konieczny (2000), r=0.21. v 2 tests for both Amazon and Barnes and Noble indicate that the variances are significantly positive at 1% level providing formal evidence of the presence of synchronization. If the price changes were indeed staggered evenly over time, then, during any particular week, the proportion of books changing prices would follow the binomial distribution (with n=3124 and p=4% for both stores). Table 2 shows the distribution of binomial p-values for each store (two-way test, null hypothesis of no synchronization). In the case of Barnes and Noble, 43 out of 56 observations lie in the two 5% level of confidence critical regions. For Amazon the results are even more unequivocal all values fall in the 5% tails, in fact all of them fall in the 1% tails. Once again, this indicates considerable level of synchronization in price changes over weeks in the two online stores. Finally, we consider pair-wise correlation in the timing of price changes as outlined in Lach and Tsiddon (1996). Here, the null hypothesis is that, for any pair of books, the likelihood of price change for one book over the 56 weeks under study is independent from that for the other book. A sufficiently high level of correlation for several pairs would therefore lead to a rejection of the null hypothesis. However, Table 2 Distribution of binomial p-values No. of obs. p-values from binomial distribution Below 5% 5 10% 10 90% 90 95% Above 95% Amazon 56 45 11 Barnes and Noble 56 33 1 12 10

190 R. Chakrabarti, B. Scholnick / Economics Letters 86 (2005) 187 191 since the distribution of the relevant statistic in this case is a non-standard one, we employ Monte-Carlo simulations to generate the distribution and compare our observed values against this distribution. The 99% critical value of the distribution of the test statistic for Amazon and Barnes and Noble are 0.443 and 0.453, respectively, while the observed values are 0.85 and 0.88, respectively. Clearly then, this test, like all others, convincingly rejects the hypothesis of bno synchronizationq for both stores. 2 3.2. Robustness check Next, we check whether our strong within-store price change synchronization results are driven by the weeks with relatively large amounts of price changes. We replicate our different tests dropping the weeks with changes over 15% of books. The percentage difference from staggering (the ratio r) declines to 0.16 for Amazon (S.D.=0.031) and 0.08 for Barnes and Noble (S.D.=0.016) comparable to those in Fisher and Konieczny (2000) who establish synchronization with figures ranging from 0.04 to 0.20. The v 2 tests continue to reject the bperfect staggeringq null hypothesis of no variation. As for the binomial tests, the hypothesis of staggering is rejected in 41 weeks out 52 (over 75%) for Amazon and 35 weeks out of 54 (about 65%) for Barnes and Noble again comparable to the relevant figures in Lach and Tsiddon (1996) that range from around 65% to 95%. As for the pair-wise correlations test, the hypothesis of no correlation is still comfortably rejected at the 1% level for both stores. This confirms that the evidence of synchronicity found in the test is not driven by a few episodes of large changes but is inherent throughout the data. 4. Conclusions Our results indicate that literally construed bmenu costsq are not solely responsible for nominal rigidities. Managerial costs and customer costs therefore appear to contribute heavily to nominal rigidity. Our results corroborate the findings of Zbaracki et al. (2004) who conclude in a very different context that such costs are likely to be several times the physical costs of price changes and may cause price rigidities. To the extent that alternative price adjustment dynamics lead to important differences in our understanding of the macroeconomy, further research should investigate the different causes of nominal price rigidities and the specific price dynamics they cause. Our result, that price rigidities persist in an environment with little or no menu costs, is a step in that direction. Acknowledgements We thank Chris Studholm, Rahul Ravi and Mary Gillespie for technical assistance, Mark Huson, Rasmus Fatum and an anonymous referee for helpful comments, and the University of Alberta, School of Business for funding. The first author thanks the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta and the India Development Foundation, Gurgaon, India for their support and hospitality. All errors are our responsibility. 2 Details of the Monte-Carlo estimation are available upon request.

R. Chakrabarti, B. Scholnick / Economics Letters 86 (2005) 187 191 191 References Ball, Laurence, Mankiw, N. Gregory, 1994. A sticky-price manifesto. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 127 152. Blinder, Alan S., 1991. Why are prices sticky? Preliminary results from an interview study. American Economic Review 81 (2), 89 96. (May). Blinder, Alan S., Canetti, Elie R.D., Lebow, David E., Rudd, Jeremy B., 1998. Asking About Prices a New Approach to Understanding Price Stickiness. Russell Sage Foundation, New York. Dutta, Shantanu, Bergen, Mark, Levy, Daniel, Venable, Robert, 1999. Menu costs, posted prices, and multiproduct retailers. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31 (4), 683 703. Fisher, Timothy C.G., Konieczny, Jerzy D., 2000. Synchronization of price changes by multiproduct firms: evidence from Canadian newspaper prices. Economics Letters 68, 271 277. Gordon, Robert J., 1990. What is new Keynesian economics? Journal of Economic Literature 28 (3), 1115 1171. Lach, Saul, Tsiddon, Daniel, 1996. Staggering and synchronization in price-setting: evidence from multiproduct firms. American Economic Review LXXXVI, 1175 1196. Daniel, Levy, Mark, Bergen, Dutta, Shantanu, Venable, Robert, 1997. The magnitude of menu costs: direct evidence from large U.S. supermarket chains. Quarterly Journal of Economics CXII, 791 825. Mankiw, N. Gregory, Reis, Ricardo, 2002. Sticky information versus sticky prices: a proposal to replace the new Keynesian Phillips curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4), 1295 1328. Zbaracki, Mark J., Ritson, Mark, Levy, Daniel, Dutta, Shantanu, Bergen, Mark, 2004. The managerial and customer dimensions of the cost of price adjustment: direct evidence from industrial markets. Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (2), 514 533.