Monopoly Monopoly occurs when there is a single seller of a good or service. Despite this simple definition that is usually given in textbooks, we

Similar documents
Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

CHAPTER NINE MONOPOLY

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Unit 6: Non-Competitive Markets

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 6. I. Choose the correct answer (each question carries 1 mark)

Refer to the information provided in Figure 12.1 below to answer the questions that follow. Figure 12.1

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION.

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

iv. The monopolist will receive economic profits as long as price is greater than the average total cost

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 27 Monopoly

All but which of the following are true in the long-run for a competitive firm that maximizes profits?

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

CH 14: Perfect Competition

Lecture 12. Monopoly

Monopoly and How It Arises

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

Short run and long run price and output decisions of a monopoly firm,

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

- pure monopoly: only one seller of a good/service with no close substitutes

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

COMPETITION AND MARKETS BEFORE YOU BEGIN. Market Structures. Looking at the Chapter. Date Period. Chapter

Market structures Perfect competition

Chapter 10 Pure Monopoly

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

CH 15: Monopoly. Lecture

CH 14. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter Summary and Learning Objectives

2007 Thomson South-Western

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2004

Coffee is produced at a constant marginal cost of $1.00 a pound. Due to a shortage of cocoa beans, the marginal cost rises to $2.00 a pound.

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Monopoly and How It Arises

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

Chapter Eleven. Monopoly

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

Three Rules and Four Models

Three Rules and Four Models

Some of the assumptions of perfect competition include:

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

23 Perfect Competition

Lecture 11. Firms in competitive markets

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Quiz 10. For questions 1-9, consider firms using a technology with cost and marginal cost functions:

MARKET STRUCTURES. Economics Marshall High School Mr. Cline Unit Two FB

Micro Monopoly Essentials 1 WCC

Chapter Eleven. Topics. Marginal Revenue and Price. A firm s revenue is:

Syllabus item: 42 Weight: 3

Principles of Economics. January 2018

ECON 260 (2,3) Practice Exam #4 Spring 2007 Dan Mallela

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic Markets. Causes of Monopolies

Chapter 13 Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

ECON 102 Brown Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2008 Professor John Parman.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

c) Will the monopolist described in (b) earn positive, negative, or zero economic profits? Explain your answer.

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

Study Guide Final Exam, Microeconomics

2) A production method that relies on large quantities of labor and smaller quantities of capital equipment is referred to as a: 2)

Week One What is economics? Chapter 1

Chapter 1- Introduction

ECON 202 2/13/2009. Pure Monopoly Characteristics. Chapter 22 Pure Monopoly

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Perfect Competition CHAPTER 14. Alfred P. Sloan. There s no resting place for an enterprise in a competitive economy. Perfect Competition 14

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Econ Microeconomics Notes

Pure Competition in the Short Run

Unit 7. Firm behaviour and market structure: monopoly

Monopoly CHAPTER 15. Henry Demarest Lloyd. Monopoly is business at the end of its journey. Monopoly 15. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Other examples of monopoly include Australia Post.

CHAPTER 8: SECTION 1 A Perfectly Competitive Market

INTRODUCTION ECONOMIC PROFITS

FINAL EXAMINATION. Special Instructions: Date: DECEMBER 15, 2000 School Year: Course and No.: ECON1006EA Time: 1:30 PM- 3:30 PM

ECON 101 Introduction to Economics1

COST OF PRODUCTION & THEORY OF THE FIRM

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives. Economics Today Twelfth Edition. Chapter 24 Monopoly

Economic Analysis for Business Decisions Multiple Choice Questions Unit-2: Demand Analysis

AP Microeconomics Review Session #3 Key Terms & Concepts

CH 13. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

MONOPOLY. Characteristics

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

Agenda. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 1. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 2. Marginal Revenue. 3. Profit Maximization Exercise

2007 Thomson South-Western

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 14 Perfectly competitive Market

ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics

11.1 Monopoly Profit Maximization

A few firms Imperfect Competition Oligopoly. Figure 8.1: Market structures

NB: STUDENTS ARE REQUESTED IN THEIR OWN INTEREST TO WRITE LEGIBLY AND IN INK.

Principles of Microeconomics ECONOMICS 103. Topic 8: Imperfect Competition. Single price monopoly. Monopolistic competition.

Transcription:

Monopoly Monopoly occurs when there is a single seller of a good or service. Despite this simple definition that is usually given in textbooks, we must criticize it a bit. Monopoly occurs when there is a single seller of a good or service and there are no close substitutes. Even here we must be careful since consumers can always elect to save. Thus, saving may easily serve as the substitute good sapping a monopoly of its strength. Strong and long lasting monopolies are those that sell products that have no good substitutes and for which saving is not a long-term option. How do monopolies become a single seller with no close substitutes? There are three possible ways this can happen. First, it may be that a firm owns an extremely scarce resource for which there are few substitutes. Its exclusive ownership of the resource makes it a monopoly. Second, it may be that the government grants the firm monopoly rights (either by preventing competition from domestic and foreign sources or by granting patents, copyrights, etc. or by nationalizing the industry) Third, monopolies may occur if the LRAC is profoundly downward sloping and possible competitors face very high startup costs. In most cases, monopolies occur because of government action. Therefore, it is extremely important for government to guard against providing such protection to a single business and instead ensure there is sufficient competition in the economy. Clearly, using outside firms to open markets and provide competition will be controversial and unpatriotic to the domestic audience. This patriotic excuse is often given to protect a domestic monopoly from foreign competitors. But, providing competition is done precisely to protect consumers from a potentially anti-social domestic monopoly. Monopoly may at times be beneficial to society, even though we strongly believe that competition leads to lower prices-larger quantities, whereas monopoly leads to higher prices-lower quantities. Still, monopoly might be good, if it manages a scarce exhaustible resource like oil. The relatively higher prices and lower quantities due to monopoly will leave more oil in the ground for future consumers and therefore may increase society s total utility, where we are measuring utility both now and in the future. Monopolies may also be beneficial if there is an overwhelming national security issue at stake. A market with many producers may be one that is relatively easy to penetrate by hostile foreign entities. Having one producer substantially reduces the policing costs of the government and its immediately control in the time of war may be important. Despite these benefits, most economists do not like monopolies and feel competition is essential for an industry to grow and innovate. Because there is no competition in a monopolized industry, the firm can experience long run above normal profitability. It does this by securing a barrier to entry by other firms. Thus, monopolies are certainly more profitable than firms facing competition. This is an important reason why that industries having a few firms tend to collude and "act" as though they are one firm. The lure of higher profits (even when shared) is always a strong incentive to conspire and cheat by reducing competition and price fixing. When several firms collude

together we call this a cartel. It is not a monopoly, but its behavior can seem very close to that of a monopoly. Usually, monopolies do not need to advertise their product. They do not need to have a brand name, but they may engage in public relations to maintain good standing with the public. The monopoly may only extend to a particular geographic area, say a state or a city. Often the government will grant a monopoly to a private company and then regulate its rate of return in order to protect the interests of the public. This is especially true of public utilities. Utilities have very high fixed costs (laying wires, gas pipes, water pipes, etc.) that act as a natural barrier to entry and eliminate competition. Seeing this, the government may go ahead and grant monopoly status to one private company and then regulate the rate of return on capital. The rate of return on capital for any company is merely the after-tax profit divided by the invested capital or funds in the firm. A special commission setup by the government will decide the appropriate level for the regulated rate of return accorded the monopoly. This will not be too high, but it will be steady. Because of this, investors usually think of utilities as a safe place to place their funds during times of trouble. The commission is charged with watching the monopoly and guaranteeing that the monopoly does not use its special status to price gouge the public. Figure 1 Demand for a Monopolist is the Industry Demand In Figure 1 above we see the demand curve that the monopolist faces. This is not controlled by the monopolist. The monopolist must accept whatever is the demand for its product. It is the only seller, but it cannot force people to buy its product. The demand curve is determined by the public, not by the monopolist. This demand is also the average revenue curve and it is the price line. However, for a linear demand, the marginal revenue will lie

exactly 1/2 the distance between the vertical axis and the demand. We can call this the "1/2 rule". This is shown in Figure 1 by the two arrows. 1 Let's now add the average cost curves to figure of the monopolist's demand. This is shown below in Figure 2. Maximum profit for the monopolist occurs where MR = MC, the golden Figure 2 Short Run Equilibrium for the Monopolist rule for profit max. The profit, given by the blue color, is where TR TC is largest. The monopolist will operate (not shutdown) and will make a positive, above normal profit. Because the monopolist does not face competition, this profit can be earned even in the long run. The short run is where the monopolist cannot change the scale of his factories. But, in the long run, the monopolist can buy more equipment and expand the size of the firm. This will be reasonable if the rate of return on capital is above the long-term interest rate. Then it makes sense to borrow money, invest in new equipment, produce and make a profit, all while covering the interest charges on the money borrowed. Note that we are not regulating the monopolist's prices and profit in Figure 2. The graph makes it look like the monopolist is making much more profit than its costs. This is just the way we have drawn 1 Suppose (inverse) demand is equal to P = α-βq. Then TR = PQ = αq-βq 2. Therefore, MR = ΔTR/ΔQ = α- 2βQ. Now, at P = MR we have α-βq AR = α-2βq MR which implies at P = MR we must have Q AR = 2Q MR.. This proves that for a linear demand curve the marginal revenue curve lies half way between the demand and the vertical axis, as shown in Figure 1. We should also point out that there is no general rule for demands that are not linear. For example, if demand is Q = Ae αp then QAR = eqmr and even more unusual cases are possible for other types of nonlinear demands. Therefore, apply our "1/2 rule" above only when talking about linear demands.

things. We could easily draw the graph so that total cost is many times larger than profit. Do not be fooled by this drawing. For most monopolists, profit is a small fraction of the total costs of producing that output. Also, we have drawn the diagram so that the monopolist earns a positive profit. It may be that it earns a loss. In fact, it can be the case that the monopolist must shut down. You are asked to show these two cases in the exercises below. It is easy to understand why that some economists claim that a monopolist will never operate where point price elasticity is less than 1. That is, it will never operate in the inelastic region of demand. This is because in that region of demand, the marginal revenue curve becomes negative. For such a case, it will always be possible to lower quantity and raise price so that costs fall and revenue rises. Profits must be maximized in the elastic region of demand. This assertion assumes (i) that there is no government regulation of the monopoly and (ii) that the monopoly has the single goal of maximizing profit. Economist believe that monopolies are inefficient (i.e. monopolies are wasteful). This is because society values the cost of the resources being used to produce the very last unit of output at MC * whereas the monopolist is charging the public P * > MC *. The public is paying more for the last unit of output than it values it. In fact, it is paying more than the marginal cost over the whole range of output, Q *. When price is greater than marginal cost we know that the public wants and expects more output to be produced and sold at a lower price. Moreover, it is actually possible to produce it and sell it at a lower price. The monopolist can restrict output and sell it at a higher price because there are no competitors who are willing to produce additional output and sell at a lower price. As we have pointed out, if competition were opened up, prices would fall and more would be produced. This is one of the big problems of monopolies. Another big problem is that monopolies become complacent. They do not strive to improve their product. They are content to distribute their profits to the stockholders and ignore research and innovation. Monopolies are slow to change with the times. Problems (P1) Is it true to say that monopolies are always very large firms? (P2) Do monopolies always sell nationally or can they be local? (P3) Why is the monopoly's demand the same as industry demand? (P4) How are monopolies created? (P5) Why don't monopolies have brand names and advertise? (P6) Why is MR = MC so important to the monopoly? (P7) The monopolist can choose price or quantity, but not both. Explain why this is true. (P8) What does it mean to regulate a monopoly?

(P9) Are all monopolies private or can the government run a monopoly? (P10) Monopolies are thought to be inefficient. Explain why economists believe this. (P11) Formosa Plastics is many times bigger than Taiwan Power Co. Yet, Taiwan Power is a monopoly and Formosa Plastics is not. Explain why.