Attitude of Flemish Farmers Towards Alternative Business Governance Structures

Similar documents
The succession effect within management decisions of family farms Calus M. 1 and Van Huylenbroeck G. 1

Impact of the Family-firm life cycle on the Management Processes Involved in Sustainable Glasshouse Horticulture

Explaining the Changing Institutional Organisation of Dutch Farms: The Role of Farmer's Attitude, Advisory Network and Structural Factors

KS4 Business Studies Year 10

The Effects of Employee Ownership in the Context of the Large Multinational : an Attitudinal Cross-Cultural Approach. PhD Thesis Summary

Master of Business Administration Course Descriptions

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 3: THE AGRICULTURAL POLICY PROCESS

Learner Guide. Cambridge O Level Economics. Cambridge Secondary 2

Business Course Descriptions

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

Learner Guide. Cambridge IGCSE Economics. Cambridge Secondary 2

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2012 series 9708 ECONOMICS

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2012 series 9708 ECONOMICS

Accounting (ACCT) Courses. Accounting (ACCT) 1

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2015 series 9708 ECONOMICS

Week Marking Period 1. Week Marking Period 3

Economics Revision Pack

INSTITUTE OF CHARTERED ACCOUNTANTS OF NIGERIA FINANCIAL REPORTING COMPONENT B: ETHICS

Currently offered as an international partner program and open only to students affiliated with the international partner institution.

The guide describes what you need to know about your IGCSE Economics examination.

Entrepreneurs and leaders. Chapter (December, 2018)

UNITY HOUSING ASSOCIATION - Board Member

CHAPTER 2. Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 9, 10, 11, 30 6, Basic assumptions. 12, 13, 14 5, 7, 10 6, 7

The Fundamentals of Economic Management and Governance in the Drive for Economic Transformation. Omotunde E. G. Johnson

CGC statement Annex to the Report of the Board of Directors 2016

Successful Business Continuation and Management Succession Require a Comprehensive Exit Strategy. By Ben M. Brahinsky

CHAPTER 2. Conceptual Framework Underlying Financial Accounting ASSIGNMENT CLASSIFICATION TABLE (BY TOPIC) Brief. Concepts for Analysis

Lesson:-02 DIFFERENT APPROACHES AND SYSTEMS OF MANAGEMENT, SKILLS, ROLES AND MODERN CHALLENGES

GCSE BUSINESS (8132) Specification For teaching from September 2017 onwards For exams in 2019 onwards. Version August 2016

GACE Economics Assessment Test at a Glance

LIVESTOCK MARKETING IN NORTHERN NAMIBIA: CULTURAL VERSUS ECONOMIC INCENTIVES. Gustav H. Düvel

HOMEWORK ECON SFU

THE CORPORATE GOVERNANCE CODE FOR MAURITIUS (2016) VOLUME 4: Scorecard

Introduction to Economics

GACE Business Education Assessment Test I (042) Curriculum Crosswalk

BCS THE CHARTERED INSTITUTE FOR IT BCS HIGHER EDUCATION QUALIFICATIONS BCS Level 5 Diploma in IT PROFESSIONAL ISSUES IN INFORMATION SYSTEMS PRACTICE

After your registration is complete and your proctor has been approved, you may take the Credit by Examination for MONEY 1A.

Natalie Uhrová 1, Petr Skalka 2

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

Syllabus Snapshot. by Amazing Brains. Exam Body: CCEA Level: GCSE Subject: Business

University of Groningen. Corporate social responsibility and financial markets Dam, Lammertjan

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education. Published

Course Description: Objectives: Grading:

REPORT ON CANDIDATES WORK IN THE CARIBBEAN ADVANCED PROFICIENCY EXAMINATION MAY/JUNE 2008 ECONOMICS (REGION EXCLUDING TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO)

Agricultural Business Systems Pathway

9708 ECONOMICS. Mark schemes should be read in conjunction with the question paper and the Principal Examiner Report for Teachers.

Regulatory Environments for Compensation Programs

Introduction to CUSTOMER ANALYSIS

Idaho PTE Business Education Course with Essential Learning Outcomes and Learning Indicators

THE FLEMISH MANURE POLICY AS A CASE OF ECO- NOMIC MANAGEMENT OF ECOLOGIC PROBLEMS

MBA (International Student Pathway) Course Descriptions

Accounting Subject Outline Stage 2

111 EAAE-IAAE Seminar Small Farms: decline or persistence. University of Kent, Canterbury, UK. 26 th -27 th June 2009

Agricultural Business and Management

Module One: Review and Assessment of Economic Census Tools. Session 1.3: Fundamental Principles of Questionnaire Design Economic Census / Surveys

Contents in Brief. Preface

Chapter 1: What is Economics? A. Economic questions arise because we face scarcity we all want more than we can get.

SC BERMAS SA Suceava Str. Humorului nr. 61 Şcheia

SUBJECT KNOWLEDGE AUDIT PGCE Business and Economics (for use across Stages 1, 2 and 3)

Level 3 Cambridge Technical in Business 05834/05835/05836/05837/05878 Unit 1: The business environment

Year 11 Business Studies Unit A292 Revision guidance

COMPANY S FINANCIAL STATEMENTS. ANALYSIS AND DECISIONS. Resume

Skills Mismatch and Firm Dynamics:

UNIVERSITY OF NIGERIA, NSUKKA FACULTY OF AGRICULTURE DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS. M.Sc. AND Ph.D DEGREE PROGRAMMES

3. Hourly compensation costs for manufacturing workers are higher in than the U.S.

SUMMARY CONCESSIONING OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN COMMUTER RAIL SUBSYSTEM

The following key should help you understand the different types of activities students engage in during the course:

Chapter One: Economic Basics

CFAMN2 Set and monitor financial targets for your business

REPORT WRITING & INDEPENDENT REVIEW

ECONOMICS 2281 O LEVEL 2006 ECONOMICS. GCE Ordinary Level/School Certificate

Syllabus. General Certificate of Education Ordinary Level ECONOMICS For examination in June and November

Curriculum Standard One: The students will understand common economic terms and concepts and economic reasoning.

DMACC Review. Spring 2013

BUSINESS MANAGEMENT (230)

UNIT 1 - STARTING A BUSINESS. AQA GCSE Business Studies

Downloaded for free from 1

Chapter 2 Functions and Types of Transfer Prices

CHAPTER 8: SECTION 1 A Perfectly Competitive Market

Delivering Local/Municipal Services

Organizational Diagnostic for Market Facilitation

IoD Code of Practice for Directors

University of International Business and Economics International Summer Session. ECO 110: Microeconomics

The Business Environment. Unit Level Level 3 Guided Learning Hours 60. Unit Credit Value Business Management

University of Groningen. Milieu en innovatie Krozer, Yoram

1 TEN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS

List outcomes, by accredited program. Many of the program outcomes should be used as part of a student learning assessment plan and be measurable.

Economics Bingo from tutor2u (

Personalised Learning Checklist for GCSE Business Studies

GCSE EXAMINERS' REPORTS

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

ABSTRACT OF THE DOCTORAL THESIS THE PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIP: AN INSTRUMENT FOR THE EFFICIENCY OF THE FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT OF LOCAL COMMUNITIES

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education. Published

KS5 Business & Economics

1. Which agency is responsible for estimating the percentage of family-owned businesses in the North American business enterprise?

A Correlation of. To the. Pennsylvania Academic Standards Economics Grades 9 & 12

A Review of the Research on Perceived Organizational Support

RULES OF PROCEDURE FOR THE AUDIT & CONFLICTS OF INTEREST COMMITTEE VALOREM S.A.

John Lewis Partnership. ORT Consulting Group

Transcription:

Attitude of Flemish Farmers Towards Alternative Business Governance Structures Mieke Calus and Guido Van Huylenbroeck Department of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University (Belgium) Paper prepared for presentation at the 94 th EAAE Seminar From households to firms with independent legal status: the spectrum of institutional units in the development of European agriculture, Ashford (UK), 9-10 April 2005 Copyright 2004 by [Mieke Calus and Guido Van Huylenbroeck]. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.

Attitude of Flemish farmers towards alternative business governance structures Mieke Calus and Guido Van Huylenbroeck 1 ABSTRACT The Flemish agriculture is characterised by family farms in sole ownership. Alternative business governance structures occur in only 7 % of the cases, although they have advantages on fiscal, family and property grounds. The reason why partnerships don t work in Flemish agriculture are mainly situated at the knowledge and perception level of the farmers. The knowledge of the different structures exists only in a limited group of farmers. The subjective perception of governance structures enhances the limitation of transition to alternative business governance structures. Partnerships will be adapted by farmers who have a higher knowledge of alternative business governance structures and accept that the higher administration is compensated by a lower risk. Keywords: agricultural company agriculture Flanders - governance structures - partnership private company with limited liability - sole ownership 1 ir. Mieke Calus is research assistant, Department of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University (Belgium) and prof. dr. ir. Guido Van Huylenbroeck is professor in the Department of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University (Belgium). Contact: Mieke.Calus@UGent.be. Paper presented at the EAAE seminar on Institutional Units in Agriculture, held in Wye, UK, April 9-10, 2005.

1 INTRODUCTION In Flemish agriculture (Belgium), as in most other West European countries, most farms are run as family farms with sole ownership. This evolves from the past were agriculture was seen as a way of life, in which a lot of families found their living. In 2003, 93,5% of the 36 681 Flemish farms had the juridical configuration of sole ownership, although this form has a number of limitations such as high capital outflow of the sector at the moment of succession, personal liability in case of failure or financial problems, high labour pressure, the fiscal consequences and so on. To solve these problems, other legal and juridical possibilities have been developed such as private companies with limited liability and agricultural companies who give more financial certainty and possibilities for a fluent transfer of the family farm. But, notwithstanding the advantages of alternative business governance structures, the continuation of the sole ownership structure in a majority of the cases is observed. In this paper, we try to explain both on theoretical and empirical grounds why this is the case. 2 PROBLEM STATEMENT Juridical forms such as private companies with limited liability and agricultural companies have advantages for the Flemish farm sector both on fiscal, family and property arguments. In the sole ownership, farmers have no limited liability in case of financial problems, and at the moment of farm transfer, they want to preserve the unity of the farm, unless the equal shares between the heirs. Both examples show the financial consequences for the whole family. The main disadvantages of alternative business governance structures cited in literature are the difficulties for control, high transaction and agency costs (Boatright 2004, Van den Berghe and Carchon 2003), although these can be limited in the family based Flemish agriculture. But more important is that complicated fiscal regulations discourage these governance structures. In order to know why alternative business governance structures, such as private companies with limited liability and agricultural companies, don t break through in Flemish agriculture although for a number of family farms it should be a good solution, different hypothesis can be posed: A limited knowledge of alternative business governance structures is a major obstacle to implement such structures in agriculture The fiscal regulations in Flanders limit the transition to alternative business governance structures For most farmers, the net balance of sole ownership characteristics is better than the net balance of alternative business governance structures Transaction and administrative cost of adopting an alternative structure are an important element in the decision to keep sole ownership 3 ALTERNATIVE BUSINESS GOVERNANCE STRUCTURES In general, the governance structure of a firm is based on ownership, decision making power and control which can vary from sole ownership to corporate governance (Figure 1). But in all governance structures, the family business has an important role to play. Family firms distinguish themselves in terms of ownership, leadership and evolutionary dynamics. The governance structures that are current in the general economic landscape, can also be 2

found within the agricultural economic landscape: especially sole ownership and different forms of partnership (agricultural company, private company with limited liability) exist. Governance structure Several Decision making power Ownership Control Corporate governance Number of people involved in management partnership - Agricultural company - Private company with limited liability - One Sole ownership Input Hired capital Hired knowledge Own labour, capital and knowledge Hired labour Family farm Corporate governance FIGURE 1 Components of Governance Structure and Input Depending on the input of capital, knowledge and labour, different juridical structures can be distinguished: the variation in hired and own input will determine which kind of governance structure can be established. In corporate governance, own capital will be available within the firm, and this makes it possible to hire labour to produce. The shareholders are equity capital providers with a claim on a firm s residual revenues, and their governance rights are safeguards for this kind of investment. Labour, which is provided by employees, is as important as capital as a factor of production, and employees also need governance rights to protect their stake in a firm, which is largely a claim for wages. If ownership and decision making power are separated, knowledge can also be hired by means of an employed manager (Boatright 2004). This governance structure is rare in Flemish agriculture. Sole ownership, e.g. as family farm, has in general the required labour and knowledge available. Both are supplemented with hired capital, in order to be able to produce. According to Pollak (1985) the main disadvantages of the family as a production unit are conflict spillovers from non-production into production activities, a propensity to forgive inefficient or slack behaviour, access to a restricted range of talents, and possible diseconomies of small scale. On the other side family farms benefit from their ability to withstand hard times, flexibility, low transaction costs and the opportunity cost of family labour (Gasson et al. 1988, Schmitt 1991). When agricultural tasks can be monitored easily in terms of inputs or outputs, family farms are often overshadowed by other forms of agricultural organisation (Schmitt 1991). In between corporate governance and sole ownership, different forms of partnerships can be distinguished. Partnerships within the family farm can be seen as a form of employee governance. The term employee governance covers various proposals for increasing the 3

control of employees over matters that affect them. This control may be exercised either directly through participation in decision making or indirectly through representation in decision-making bodies, such as a seat on the board of directors (Boatright 2004). Most important partnership structures in Flemish agriculture are the agricultural company (landbouwvennootschap) and the private company with limited liability (BVBA) (Table 1). In general, partnership is the most common form of organisation in fields that involve highly specialized skills and knowledge (Boatright 2004) like is often the case in agriculture and horticulture. Differences between sole ownership and partnerships are situated on fiscal, family and property basis. An important difference on fiscal grounds is the system of taxation in which partnerships have a fixed tax rate. This is profitable for larger companies, compared to the graduated tax rates for sole ownership. Another positive aspect is that profit and loss can be transferred to the next fiscal year. The remaining of the profit within the company will create a stable income and money is available for investments. In contrary, there is no reduction on tax rates of agricultural subsidies and, except for agricultural companies, accounting is obligatory. On family grounds, there is a safeguard for the continuity of the farm because there will be no crumble after the decease of the farm manager. There is the possibility to divide the farm by means of blocks of shares in which all the heirs are treated in the same way. The free transferability of shares is limited and partnerships can structure cooperation. The difference between sole ownership and partnerships on property basis is situated in the liability. The sole ownership has unlimited liability of both private and company property at present but also in the future. Partnerships have limited liability on property, except for the active partner in the agricultural company who has also unlimited liability. The agricultural company is a less strict form of partnership, compared to the private company with limited liability, but has also less advantages on fiscal and property grounds. TABLE 1 Basic Characteristics of Private Company with Limited Liability (BVBA) and Agricultural Company (LV) Private Company with Limited BVBA Besloten Vennootschap met Beperkte Liability aansprakelijkheid In a BVBA the partners are only liable for the company assets. The capital is tied up in registered and not freely marketable shares. This way it is avoided that shares are transferred to outside parties without approval of the joint partners and that the family character of the company is lost, for example. A BVBA is set up by notarial deed and has to comply with a number of accounting and administrative obligations Agricultural Company LV Landbouwvennootschap The agricultural company is a very specific type of organisation for the purpose of operating an agricultural or horticultural business. An agricultural company is automatically subject to the personal income tax if: it counts fewer than three partners or if its capital is below 30.950 In other instances, the company may select to pay personal income tax or, conversely, corporation tax. 4

4 METHODOLOGY The empirical data for the research of the attitude of Flemish farmers towards alternative business governance structures, are the result of a questionnaire that was hold at the Flanders agriculture fair at the beginning of January 2005. Participants of this fair were asked to complete a questionnaire related to their governance structure. More then 280 farmers completed the form, but only 268 questionnaires were restrained of which 11,6% was partially filled in. The sampling technique was based on non probability sampling in which the participants of the fair where asked in the first place if they are farmer or not. In case of a positive answer on the first question, they were asked to fill in the questionnaire. Approximately 70% of the approached farmers were willing to do so. Due to distance to the fair, farmers from Flemish Brabant, Antwerp and Limburg are less represented in the survey, then in the general distribution of the farms in Flanders (Figure 2). Segmentation of Flemish farms Total number of farms (n = 36 681) Farms in survey (n = 268) 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Flemish Brabant Antwerp Limburg West-Flanders East-Flanders not known FIGURE 2 Segmentation of Flemish Farms in Survey and in General The questionnaire consists of three parts. In the first part, some general information of the farm is asked, related to the farming type, labour, education, succession and the aims of the farm. The second part assesses the knowledge about different juridical forms of farming with a focus on the sole ownership, the agricultural company (LV) and the private company with limited liability (BVBA). These three forms are most common in Flemish agriculture. The last part of the questionnaire is oriented towards the own juridical form of the farm. In the first place, the questionnaire is analysed on basis of descriptive statistics. In the second part of the research, discriminant analysis is used to explain the difference between sole ownership and alternative business governance structures. 5 RESULTS The sole ownership is the most important governance structure in Flanders. In the questionnaire, 89,3% of the farmers works under sole ownership, 7,3% has an alternative business governance structure and 3,4% does not know the juridical configuration. If farmers 5

don t know their governance structure, it will probably be the sole ownership. A total of 92,7% sole ownership in the survey approaches the 93,5% of the 36 681 Flemish farms that had in 2003 the sole ownership as juridical configuration. 5.1 Limited knowledge of alternative business governance structures The attitude towards alternative business governance structures is related to the knowledge of the different governance structures. The information towards farmers about the different possibilities of juridical forms in Flanders is very limited. Extension services give no priority to this information which is reflected in the knowledge level of the existence of the governance structure (Figure 3): 24% of the farmers has no idea of the existence of alternative business governance structures in agriculture. Approximately 40% knows that the juridical forms exist in Flemish agriculture and horticulture, but their information about the economic farm size on which the juridical form is applicable is not correct. The correct knowledge is available in 58% (sole ownership), 35% (LV) and 24% (BVBA) of the cases. This shows that information about the existence of alternative business governance structures in Flanders is limited. Knowledge level of existence of governance structures in Flemish agriculture and horticulture 150 number of farmers 100 50 0 sole ownership LV BVBA no idea no complete knowledge no correct knowledge correct knowledge FIGURE 3 Knowledge Level of Existence of Governance Structures The knowledge of the different governance structures in agriculture is relatively low for farmers in sole ownership: they do not search for information about other juridical forms, and even the knowledge of their own farming structure is limited. In the private company with limited liability (BVBA) the level of knowledge is relatively high. These farmers have selected the governance structures that suited best their needs, and are ably to compare the different structures on an objective basis. Within the agricultural company (LV) the knowledge of the own governance structure is high, but contrary to the BVBA, their knowledge of other juridical forms is low (Table 2). 6

TABLE 2 General Knowledge of Governance Structures farmers in juridical farm structure: sole ownership LV BVBA F-value (n = 205) (n = 9) (n = 5) knowledge of sole 5,63 ab 3,56 a 7,00 b 3,456 * ownership knowledge of BVBA 4,35 4,14 6,40 0,857 knowledge of LV 3,96 a 7,29 b 4,60 ab 3,802 * (scale 0 10: 0: no knowledge of governance structure 10: perfect knowledge of governance structure) (*: significance < 0,05) There is only a limited group of farmers that has a broad view of the different farming systems, and their knowledge is covering. On bases of their available information, they are able to choose the governance structure that suited best their farming needs. Nevertheless, there is a large group of farmers that has only a limited knowledge of the different possibilities and consequences of alternative business governance structures in agriculture and horticulture. Out of ignorance, they continue farming in sole ownership. 5.2 Limitation of transition to alternative business governance structures Alternative business governance structures can be considered for fiscal, family and property reasons (see chapter 3). The perception of characteristics for both sole ownership and partnership, will reveal the significant differences in perception between different juridical forms (Table 3). TABLE 3 Perception of Farming Characteristics by Sole Ownership Farmers average paired -3 0 3 sole partnership T-test sampled ownership limited administration extensive 1,29 1,68-3,298 ** administration management less important management important 1,44 1,49-0,361 non flexible form of farming flexible form of farming 1,08 0,47 3,702 ** legally complex legally not complex 0,76-0,11 4,436 ** not tax profitable tax profitable 0,29 0,74-2,702 ** capital intensive capital extensive 0,14 0,10-0,218 high capital risk low capital risk -0,18 0,40-2,921 ** (**: significance < 0,01) According to farmers working in sole ownership, there is no difference in the importance of management between sole ownership and forms of partnership. Management is important in every juridical form. In average there is no explicit need for capital in the different governance structures. Extra capital in alternative business governance structures is not necessary in the perception of farmers under sole ownership. Explanations of the limited transition to alternative business governance structures can be found in a higher administration, the legal complexity and the less flexible form of farming. In the perception of farmers, forms of partnership are more tax profitable and have a lower capital risk. The fiscal and property reasons to adapt alternative governance structures are acknowledged by farmers working in sole ownership, but the complexity of these forms, both 7

in administration and legislation, limit the transition to alternative business governance structures. 5.3 Motivation of own governance structure The knowledge and the perception of farmers towards the different governance structures can be set against the own juridical form of the farm. This reveals the reason way farmers are working in their current governance structure, with respect to the opportunities and threats of this form. The farms that work under the sole ownership configuration, continue this form because they were used to do so. Also the government support for investments is an incentive to continue the current management. On the other side, alternative business governance structures are on average more adapted for the fiscal advantages and the limitation of risk, although limitation of administration seems to be not at all suitable. For alternative business governance structures in agriculture and horticulture, the farm transfer can occur in theory in a more fluent way then in sole ownership, but in comparison with partnership, more farmers in sole ownership indicate that a fluent transfer of the farm is an incentive to stay in this structure (Table 4). TABLE 4 Reason of Adaptation of Own Juridical Structure # sole ownership partnership F-value governance structure already existing 1,44 0,40 4,262 * easy to receive government support 1,16-0,07 6,501 * limited administration 0,29-0,87 3,947 * fiscal advantages 0,39 0,73 0,723 fluent transfer of the farm 0,70 0,47 0,662 limitation of risk - 0,13 0,80 3,471 * ( # score: -3: not at all applicable; 0: neutral; 3: totally applicable - *: significance < 0,05) An important aspect of the motivation of the own governance structure is also the intensity of information collection about alternative business governance structures. Significant more farmers with an alternative business governance structure attend workshops about other governance structures (Pχ² < 0,05) and they discuss this subject more with extension officers. Although the change of governance structure is not always obvious, 29,9% of the farmers has already considered to a smaller or larger extent the possibility of adopting another governance structure. Especially the farmers who have considered it to a larger extent, are not working under the current governance structure because of the easiness of receiving government support. They are also not continuing in sole ownership because this governance structure already exists. 5.4 Discriminant analysis The underlying reasons of choosing for a particular juridical form, can be analysed by means of a discriminant analysis. This analysis gives the explanation why farms are choosing for sole ownership or partnership, based on the objective knowledge and the subjective perception of the different juridical forms. 8

Based on the motivation of the own governance structure, and the knowledge of the different juridical forms, 4 variables are restrained for further analysis: - objective knowledge of the governance characteristics of the agricultural company - limitation of risk as reason for adaptation of own juridical form - limitation of administration as reason for adaptation of own juridical form - governance structure already existing as reason for adaptation of own juridical form - easy to receive government support as reason for adaptation of own juridical form The restrained discriminant function (1) has an eigenvalue of 0,221, a χ²- value of 37,61 (Pχ² < 0,01) and 42,5% of the variation is explained by the model. The individual possibility of choosing a governance structure does not allow a higher explanation percentage. (1) Z = -0,551 + 0,211 X 1 + 0,367 X 2 0,281 X 3 0,137 X 4 0,094 X 5 with: X 1 : knowledge of governance characteristics of agricultural company X 2 : importance of limitation of risk X 3 : importance of limitation of administration X 4 : importance of governance structure already existing X 5 : importance of easiness to receive government support TABLE 5 Standardized Canonical Discriminant Function Coefficients Coefficients X 1 : knowledge of governance characteristics of agricultural company 0,650 X 2 : importance of limitation of risk 0,632 X 3 : importance of limitation of administration -0,534 X 4 : importance of governance structure already existing -0,293 X 5 : importance of easiness to receive government support -0,172 Alternative business governance structures will be adapted by farmers who have a higher knowledge of alternative business governance structures, such as the agricultural company. The limitation of risk is also important and they recognize that the characteristics of partnership can lower the risk for both the farmer and the farm family. On the other hand, the limitation of administration is less important than for farmers in sole ownership. The higher administration is compensated by a lower risk. The fact that the governance structure is already existing within the farm is important for sole ownership. They also attach importance to the government support. Farmers working in partnership are not stuck by their juridical form: the partnership is a structure in which they are able to farm, but if other governance structures appear to have better characteristics for their farming situation, they will change it for the well-being of their farm and farming family. 6 CONCLUSIONS Alternative business governance structures play a marginal role in the Flemish agriculture and horticulture. Only 7 % of the agricultural and horticultural farms in Flanders is managed through different forms of partnership. These juridical forms have opportunities for farms on fiscal, family and property grounds, but the attitude towards these juridical forms limits the transition from sole ownership to alternative business governance structures. A survey among Flemish farmers reveals that the knowledge of governance structures is limited. There is only a limited group of farmers that has a broad view of the different 9

farming systems, and their knowledge is covering. They are able to choose the governance structure that suited best their farming needs. Nevertheless, there is a large group of farmers that has only a limited knowledge of the different possibilities and consequences of alternative business governance structures in agriculture and horticulture. Out of ignorance, they continue farming in sole ownership. The fiscal and property reasons to adapt alternative governance structures are acknowledged by farmers working in sole ownership, but the complexity of these forms, both in administration and legislation, limit the transition to alternative business governance structures. Farmers already working in partnership are not stuck by their juridical form: the partnership is a structure in which they are able to farm, but if other governance structures appear to have better characteristics for their farming situation, they will change it for the well-being of their farm and farming family. Alternative business governance structures will be adapted by farmers who have a higher knowledge of alternative business governance structures and accept that the higher administration is compensated by a lower risk. 7 REFERENCES Boatright, John R. 2004. Employee Governance and the Ownership of the Firm. Business Ethics Quarterly 14 (1): 1-21. Gasson, R., Crow, G., Errington, Andrew, Hutson, J., Marsden, T. and Winter, D. M. 1988. The Farm as a Family Business: A Review. Journal of Agricultural Economics 39 (1): 1-41. Pollak, Robert A. 1985. A Transaction Cost Approach to Families and Households. Journal of Economic Literature 23: 581-608. Schmitt, Günther. 1991. Why Is the Agriculture of Advanced Western Economies Still Organized by Family Farms? Will This Continue to Be So in Future? European Review of Agricultural Economics 18: 443-458. Van den Berghe, Lutgart and Carchon, Steven. 2003. Agency Relations within the Family Business System: An Exploratory Approach. Corporate governance - an international review 11 (3): 171-179. 10