Misleading Congress about Drug Development: Reply

Similar documents
New estimates of drug development costs

Publicly Funded Clinical Trials: A Route to Sustained Innovation with Affordable Drugs

Assessing the Economics of Single-Source vs. Multi-Vendor Manufacturing

WITA/GWU TRADE SEMINAR September 29, 2016 Washington D.C. RICHARD KJELDGAARD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND TRADE CONSULTANT

The Economics of New Drug Development: Costs, Risks, and Returns

Recent Studies of Follow-On Biologics Are Based on Seriously Flawed Assumptions:

P. Ranganath Nayak. James A. Bolognese. Chief Executive Officer, Cytel Inc. Senior Director, Biostatistics, Cytel, Inc. Shaping the Future

Research and Development of Dasatinib. Research and Development Related to dasatinib (Sprycel TM ) KEI Research Note 2008:3

ERM and the Pharmaceutical Industry

40. Food and Drug Administration

Cowen and Company 34 th Annual Health Care Conference

Challenges and Solutions in Clinical Supply Management. Pamela Osborne Sr. Clinical Supply Chain Mgr

Access, Affordability and Innovation Focus on High Cost Medicines: Facts and Potential Options

Chapter. The Implications of Patent-Term Extension for Pharmaceuticals

1 Table of Contents 1.1 List of Tables 1.2 List of Figures 2 Drug Discovery and Development Market in Asia - Introduction 3 Drug Discovery and

FDA Critical Path Initiative: Closing Productivity Gap in Medical Product Development. October 4, 2004

A NATIONAL SURVEY OF EMERGENCY ROOM PHYSICIANS REGARDING THE FOOD AND DRUG ADMINISTRATION

Submitted to the United States Postal Regulatory Commission, September 12, 2018

Bringing an Excipient to Market

B : Topics in Investments - Financial Analysis in Healthcare

Regulatory scene setting - benefits and risks of seamless Phase II / III trials

Benefits of Adaptive Trials The benefits of adaptive trials fall into three categories: commercial, ethical, and budgetary.

Updated trends in US brand-name and generic drug competition

Toxicology - Problem Drill 24: Toxicology Studies in Pharmaceutical Development

Rx R&D Myths: The Case Against The Drug Industry s R&D Scare Card

CORPORATE NEWS FINANCIAL RESULTS 2017 PAION AG REPORTS ON FISCAL YEAR 2017 AND FINANCIAL RESULTS

BREAKTHROUGH INNOVATION: LESSONS FOR PHARMA R&D

DEMAND CURVE AS A CONSTRAINT FOR BUSINESSES

INVESTOR PRESENTATION FULL YEAR 2007 RESULTS. February 2008

Jefferies TMT Conference

Good Clinical Practice (GCP) & Clinical Trial Registries

5/23/2016. The Drug Development Process and Design of Clinical Trials. Clinical Trial Design Guidance. Regulatory Definitions

B : Topics in Investments - Financial Analysis in Healthcare

Yes, You Can Teach an Old Drug New Tricks: Regulatory Pathway for Repurposed Drugs

The Drug Development Process and Design of Clinical Trials

The Essential Guide To Managing Biotech Labs

McKinsey Center for Government What's Driving the Recent Surge in New Drug Approvals?

Best Buy Political Activity &

Amgen GLOBAL CORPORATE COMPLIANCE POLICY

Issue Review. Do Voters Understand Super PACs? March Jason M. Farrell Center for Competitive Politics

Jefferies 2015 Global Healthcare Conference June 3, 2015

PRICING MANAGEMENT. The Reservation Price

UNLOCK Profit Potential

The Middle East. 15 Countries*, 5 Time Zones. Population > 333 millions** GDP: $3.13 Trillions*** 58% of world oil reserves

Pediatric Exclusivity and Drug Development Requirements in the Overall Pediatric Population. Prepared by Beckloff Associates, Inc.

Institute of Pharmaceutical Technology and Biopharmacy University of Pécs szeptember 22. 1

MAXIMIZING THE VALUE OF CLINICAL TRIALS DATA: A COLLABORATIVE FRAMEWORK FOR DATA STANDARDS GOVERNANCE FROM DATA DEFINITION TO KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT

August 25, Dockets Management Branch (HFA-305) Food and Drug Administration 5630 Fishers Lane, Rm Rockville, MD 20852

Biowaivers and Harmonization Guidelines for Class I and 3 Drugs: Biowaiver Case Studies

SPHERIX ANNOUNCES 2009 FINANCIAL RESULTS

Strategic vision of Pharma Market

Introduction to the Generic Drug Supply Chain and Key Considerations for Policymakers

Acquisition of Vtesse Inc. Increased Focus on Orphan and Pediatric Diseases

CDER Perspective: Challenges in Clinical Trials and the Path Forward

Comments Submitted to the Federal Trade Commission on. the Pfizer-Wyeth and Merck- Schering Plough Mergers

Can We Transfer FDA Experience Into Latin America To Improve The Interaction With Health Authorities?

Drug development is a lengthy, expensive, and complex process, and clinical development is

Pricing with Market Power

Clinical Trials Roadmap: A Go-To-Market Guide for Probiotics

'Safe Harbor' For Preapproval Information Exchange To Get Legislative Push

News For Immediate Release

Jefferies 2018 Global Healthcare Conference. June 7, 2018

KPI ENCYCLOPEDIA. A Comprehensive Collection of KPI Definitions for PHARMACEUTICALS

Discussion Questions. Chapter 1

Streamlining Development and Approval Processes for 505(B)(2) NDAs

CONCEPT OF 505 (b) (2) APPLICATION: BENEFITS AND CHALLENGES

Urban Transportation Planning Prof Dr. V. Thamizh Arasan Department of Civil Engineering Indian Institute Of Technology, Madras

Statement of Stephen A. Smith, DVM Executive Director Southern Alliance for Clean Energy

R&D Portfolio Planning In- and Out-licensing of Medicines

Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run

Invited Researcher : VivianeYumy Mitsuuchi Kunisawa (**) Introduction

CORPORATE NEWS EARNINGS PAION AG PUBLISHES GROUP QUARTERLY STATEMENT FOR THE FIRST NINE MONTHS OF 2016

This is the midterm 1 solution guide for Fall 2012 Form A. 1) The answer to this question is A, corresponding to Form A.

September 12, Division of Dockets Management (HFA-305) Food and Drug Administration 5630 Fishers Lane, Room 1061 Rockville, MD 20852

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

BioCryst Reports Fourth Quarter and Full Year 2017 Financial Results. Updates Investors Regarding Proposed Merger with Idera Pharmaceuticals, Inc.

Can better design save biopharma?

Common Compliance Challenges with Speaker Programs

Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?

Jefferies 2014 Global Healthcare Conference June 3, 2014 NYSE: Q

How Have User Fees Affected the FDA?

Drug Delivery Evolution. Akan Oton Director of Business Development Board Member, Applied Drug Delivery Institute

Technical Report No. 63 Quality Requirements for the Extemporaneous Preparation of Clinical Trial Materials

WORKSHOP B Monitor MSL and Field Force Compliance

Better Portfolio Decisions through Predictive Analytics

About Clinical Trials

Impact of Patient Engagement on Project Valuation

MANAGING MATURE PRODUCT PORTFOLIOS - KEY CHALLENGES AND BENEFITS

HEALTH CARE PROVIDER TOOLKIT

R&D Costs and Productivity in Biopharmaceuticals Faculty Research Working Paper Series

Chin Koerner Executive Director US Regulatory and Development Policy

State of the Clinical Trials Industry

Sec Short title; finding. Sec Authority to assess and use drug fees. Sec Reauthorization; reporting requirements.

Towards(a(Just(Solar(Radiation(Management(Compensation(System:((( A(Defense(of(the(Polluter(Pays(Principle(!! Robert(K.(Garcia(

Glossary of Abbreviations

Canadian Cancer Clinical Trials Network Portfolio Eligibility Criteria and Guidelines

ImmunoGen, Inc. Reports Fourth Quarter and Fiscal Year 2013 Financial Results and Provides Fiscal Year 2014 Financial Guidance and Corporate Update

A Review of the PA-824 Patent Landscape

Introduction to Drug Development

Invisible Ink in GLP and GCP Research

Transcription:

Commentary Misleading Congress about Drug Development: Reply Joseph A. DiMasi Tufts University Ronald W. Hansen University of Rochester Henry G. Grabowski Duke University Abstract The review essay by Donald Light about a Congressional Budget Office report on pharmaceutical research and development (R&D) (Light 2007) contains factual errors, leaves the reader uninformed about rebuttal responses to criticisms made in the review about studies of R&D costs, and draws erroneous conclusions about the nature of industry economics. The review essay by Donald Light about a Congressional Budget Office report on pharmaceutical research and development (R&D) (Light 2007) contains factual errors, leaves the reader uninformed about rebuttal responses to criticisms made in the review about studies of R&D costs, and draws erroneous conclusions about the nature of industry economics. We briefly address these problems. Nearly all of what Light writes in his section on development costs in relation to our study of pharmaceutical R&D costs (DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski 2003) has been published in two comments in the journal in which our study appeared (Light and Warburton 2005a, 2005b). Light, however, does not inform readers that we have rebutted all of these points in two responses in that journal (DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski 2005a, 2005b). Since we have already published detailed responses to the criticisms, here we simply direct readers to those publications. Light does reference one of our responses, but he makes no mention that it contains rebuttals to his criticisms. Instead, he cites it, incorrectly, as indicating that we are working on estimates of R&D costs for what he calls me-too Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, Vol. 33, No. 2, April 2008 DOI 10.1215/03616878-2007-063 2008 by Duke University Press JHPPL332_07C_DiMasi.indd 319 2/24/08 3:38:58 PM

320 Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law derivative products. Other factual misstatements in Light (2007) include the claim that the CEO of Merck hosted and launched the first public presentation of our study of pharmaceutical R&D costs (his role was only that of an invited guest speaker at the forum in which we presented our results) and the implication that F. M. Scherer s (2001) study on the relationship between pharmaceutical industry profits and R&D expenditures was supported by the Merck Foundation and the National Pharmaceutical Council (Scherer did not receive any financial support for his study). R&D Costs In his section on pharmaceutical R&D costs, Light also touts the alternative estimates offered in a report by the Congress Watch division of the advocacy group Public Citizen (2001). However, the Public Citizen analysis is deeply methodologically flawed in ways that make their estimates seriously biased downward. Since we have already written about the report s flaws in detail, we direct readers to our paper (DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski 2004). One flaw in the Public Citizen report is echoed several times in Light (2007) and so is worth addressing in some detail here. Light maintains that our estimate of the cost to get a new molecular entity (NME) to market is not representative of new drug development costs because our sample excluded the (presumably lower) costs associated with all of the other new drug application (NDA) approvals made by the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) for a drug after it had obtained initial marketing approval (i.e., NME approval). These approvals, for the most part, are line extensions. Firms in this and in many other industries fill out their product lines for a basic product to better serve varied consumer needs and desires (e.g., oral solutions for children or adults who have difficulty swallowing tablets or capsules, more convenient dosing regimens, or different side-effect or efficacy profiles). In the case of drugs and the FDA statistics on NDA approvals, many of the approvals, in fact, are obtained long after the drugs have lost patent expiration by firms other than the sponsor of the original NME (often by small, specialty pharmaceutical firms or generic drug companies). Even leaving aside this substantive point about the makeup of the approval statistics, it is not appropriate to treat the incremental costs of later regulatory approvals associated with an active ingredient as though they were independent of the costs of obtaining the original approval. This would make no more sense than it would to take all of the R&D costs associated with developing a new automobile model and dividing that by JHPPL332_07C_DiMasi.indd 320

Commentary 321 the number of trim lines of that model that the manufacturer happens to offer for sale and then use that as a measure of the R&D cost of developing a new automobile model. Light incorrectly claims that we are currently working on cost estimates for individual line extensions and will then add them later to preoriginal approval costs. In fact, our published study of R&D costs (DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski 2003) already contains an estimate of the average cost for all postoriginal approval R&D, which was then appropriately added to preapproval costs to get an estimate of full life-cycle R&D cost per approved new drug ($897 million in year 2000 dollars on a capitalized basis taken at the point of original marketing approval). 1 Light (2007) also repeatedly makes the claim that $300 million is the median R&D cost per approved new drug for our data. There is no such figure in our study, nor does Light indicate how such a figure can be derived. In fact, it is impossible to construct a meaningful overall median value for these data because the R&D expenditures include costs for the bulk of new drugs that fail in testing at some point in the preclinical or clinical development process and therefore do not have costs for all development phases and because some of the early expenditures cannot be allocated to individual compounds. Light (2007) also questions the data that we had on clinical trial sizes by comparing our average number of subjects per approved new drug to much lower figures given in Love (2003) and later updated on the Listserv belonging to the same group (Consumer Project on Technology, now called Knowledge Ecology International [KEI]). Light portrays these alternative averages as though they had been reported by the FDA itself. In fact, what KEI did was to treat whatever sample sizes they found reported in the Clinical Studies sections of the labels for FDA-approved drugs as if they represented the total number of subjects that had been included in industry clinical trials for the drug. What the FDA generally discusses in these sections of the label are the results for a few efficacy trials that were considered pivotal for the indication that was approved. The section does not necessarily note all phase 3 trials and typically excludes phase 1 and phase 2 trials. The result is that the KEI averages substantially underestimate the total number of subjects in industry trials. In a posting on the same Listserv that contained the KEI averages, one of us made these points and provided illustrative examples, using information in other 1. If one then wants to compare these costs to net sales, then one should look at total lifecycle sales for all product presentations containing the active ingredient. JHPPL332_07C_DiMasi.indd 321

322 Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law parts of the FDA-approved label, that demonstrate unequivocally that the KEI numbers can be substantially off the mark (DiMasi 2006). Light also notes the clinical trial sizes postulated in a report on the development of a hypothetical drug for tuberculosis (Global Alliance for TB Drug Development 2001). However, this is a special case that was never meant to represent drug development as a whole, and there are numerous reasons why it should not be used to imply anything about clinical trial sizes or development costs in general. Our report critiquing the Public Citizen report also discusses the Global Alliance for TB Drug Development report (DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski 2004). In addition, as noted in our study (DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski 2003), our data on clinical trial sizes were consistent with those from another source whose estimates are not subject to the same methodological errors made by KEI (PAREXEL 2002). Profitability In his discussion of industry profitability, Light (2007) argues that the standard economic treatment of R&D costs as investment expenditures that create intangible assets is wrong simply because R&D expenditures are expensed on tax returns. One has nothing to do with the other. It is widely recognized that a more appropriate tax structure would require that R&D expenditures be capitalized and amortized over the life cycles of the products created as a result of that R&D. However, in light of the substantial uncertainties and arbitrariness that would arise in making a forward-looking assessment of the benefits that might be linked to current R&D expenditures, Generally Accepted Accounting Principles and other accounting guidelines take the most conservative route and allow for expensing of R&D expenditures. The desire of accounting guideline setters to be practical with regard to the tax treatment of R&D expenditures says nothing about how a proper economic analysis of past R&D expenditures should be conducted. Finally, Light misconstrues industry data when he argues here and originally in Light and Lexchin (2005) that lower prices in the United Kingdom and Canada have no negative impact on R&D and that these countries cannot be called free riders because local R&D expenditures as a share of local sales is purportedly greater in these countries than in the United States. 2 The markets for pharmaceuticals are typically global, 2. Foreign free-rider arguments are more accurately referred to as cheap-rider arguments (Scherer 1993). JHPPL332_07C_DiMasi.indd 322

Commentary 323 as is the R&D that creates products for those markets. This renders comparisons between local R&D expenditures and local sales meaningless. 3 A relevant metric would be based on contributions to global quasi rents (revenues minus variable costs). Specifically, the metric would be a country s net sales as a share of global net sales considered on a per capita basis. It is widely thought that the United States contributes most of the pharmaceutical industry s profits in absolute terms, let alone on a per capita basis. Furthermore, Light s arguments suggesting that drug companies could make up for the imposition of European and Canadian level prices in the United States by reducing marketing expenditures while maintaining or increasing R&D expenditures are specious. If firms can increase profits by simply reducing marketing expenditures when prices are lowered, then they could also increase profits by doing so now at current prices. In other words, Light s implication could only be true if firms do not currently set their marketing expenditures so as to maximize profits. We doubt that Light would make that argument. References DiMasi, J. A. 2006. Reply: Size of Trials by Status (S or P) Some 2004 FDA and PAREXEL Data Compared. July 27. lists.essential.org/pipermail/ip-health/2006 -July/009888.html. DiMasi, J. A., R. W. Hansen, and H. G. Grabowski. 2003. The Price of Innovation: New Estimates of Drug Development Costs. Journal of Health Economics 22:151 185.. 2004. Assessing Claims about the Cost of New Drug Development: A Critique of the Public Citizen and TB Alliance Reports. November 1. csdd.tufts.edu/_documents/ www/doc_231_45_735.pdf.. 2005a. Extraordinary Claims Require Extraordinary Evidence: Reply. Journal of Health Economics 24:1034 1044.. 2005b. Setting the Record Straight on Setting the Record Straight: Response to the Light and Warburton Rejoinder. Journal of Health Economics 24:1049 1053. Global Alliance for TB Drug Development. 2001. The Economics of TB Drug Development. New York: Global Alliance for TB Drug Development. Light, D. W. 2007. Misleading Congress about Drug Development. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 32:895 913. 3. Ironically, at later points in both Light (2007) and Light and Lexchin (2005), the authors seem to acknowledge the global nature of pharmaceutical research and development (R&D) and sales, even though this conflicts with their earlier free-rider arguments. JHPPL332_07C_DiMasi.indd 323

324 Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law Light, D. W., and J. Lexchin. 2005. Foreign Free Riders and the High Price of U.S. Medicines. BMJ 331:958 960. Light, D. W., and R. Warburton. 2005a. Extraordinary Claims Require Extraordinary Evidence: Comment. Journal of Health Economics 24:1030 1033.. 2005b. Setting the Record Straight in the Reply by DiMasi, Hansen, and Grabowski. Journal of Health Economics 24:1045 1048. Love, J. 2003. Evidence Regarding Research and Development Investments in Innovative and Non-Innovative Medicines. September 22. www.cptech.org/ip/health/rnd/ evidenceregardingrnd.pdf. PAREXEL. 2002. Emerging Clinical Trial Enrollment Benchmarks: Trial Size Statistics for New Drugs Approved in 2001 (2000, 1999, 1998). In PAREXEL s Pharmaceutical R&D Statistical Sourcebook 2002/2003, ed. M. P. Mathieu, 108 111. Waltham, MA: PAREXEL International. Public Citizen. 2001. Rx R&D Myths: The Case Against the Drug Industry s R&D Scare Card. July 23. www.citizen.org/documents/rdmyths.pdf. Scherer, F. M., 1993. Pricing, Profits, and Technological Progress in the Pharmaceutical Industry. Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (3): 97 115.. 2001. The Link between Gross Profitability and Pharmaceutical R&D Spending. Health Affairs 20 (5): 216 220. JHPPL332_07C_DiMasi.indd 324