A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

Similar documents
Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

The Sports Product Market ECONOMICS OF SPORTS (ECON 325) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

AN ASCENDING AUCTION FOR INTERDEPENDENT VALUES: UNIQUENESS AND ROBUSTNESS TO STRATEGIC UNCERTAINTY. Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris

Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm.

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Resale and Bundling in Multi-Object Auctions

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

Selling methods by a monopolist

Existence of Nash equilibria in sporting contests with capacity constraints

GAME THEORY: Analysis of Strategic Thinking Exercises on Repeated and Bargaining Games

Harvard University Department of Economics

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013

EconS Bertrand Competition

Employee Initiative and Managerial Control

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Incentives, Wages, and Promotions: Theory and Evidence

Labeling Regulation or Product Liability? Managing Product Risks When Consumer Label-Reading E orts Count

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy

Revenue Sharing in Professional Sports Leagues 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Employee Incentives, and Teamwork in Human Capital Intensive Firms

Performance Pay, Trade and Inequality

Efficient Horizontal Mergers in Polluting Industries with Cournot Competition

Product versus Process: Innovation Strategies of Multi-Product Firms

E ciency Wages. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

Beef Up Your Competitor: A Model of Advertising Cooperation between Internet Search Engines

Labor Economics, Lectures 9 and 10: Investments in General and Speci c Skills

Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1

Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations

New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering

Appendix 1: Agency in product range choice with di erent

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy

Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers

A Simple Auction Mechanism for the Optimal Allocation of the Commons

Market Design: Theory and Applications

Speculation and Demand Reduction in English Clock Auctions with Resale

Pricing Services Subject to Congestion: Charge Per-Use Fees or Sell Subscriptions?

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Reciprocal dumping with Bertrand competition

Competition in Two-Sided Markets

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms

TV Revenue Sharing as a Coordination Device in Sports Leagues

NET Institute*

Managing Price Promotions. Within a Product Line

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Legal Unbundling can be a Golden Mean between Vertical Integration and Ownership Separation

Nonlinear pricing of a congestible network good. Abstract

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Faculty & Research. Working Paper Series. Strategic Segmentation Using Outlet Malls. by A. Coughlan and D. Soberman

Toward a Contract Theory of Strategy: Contracting, Bargaining. and the Strategic Management of Human Capital (PRELIMINARY DRAFT)

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2

TARGETING IN ADVERTISING MARKETS: IMPLICATIONS FOR OFFLINE VS. ONLINE MEDIA. Dirk Bergemann and Alessandro Bonatti. March 2010

The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly

Volume 30, Issue 1. Policy Reforms and Incentives in Rice Production in Bangladesh

The dynamics of personal norms and the emergence of an organizational culture

Who Gain and Who Lose on International Outsourcing?

Are Incremental Bidders Really Naive? Theory and Evidence from Competing Online Auctions

Wage and Employment Determination through Non-Cooperative Bargaining 1

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Should Speculators Be Welcomed in Auctions?

EconS Asymmetric Information

A note on acquisition of complements in a vertically differentiated market

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

Incentives for environmental R&D

Flexibility as an Instrument in Digital Rights Management

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Inferring the strategy space from market outcomes. Authors: Flavio Menezes, John Quiggin. Working Paper: R13_1

Price Regulation and Parallel Imports of Pharmaceuticals

IO Experiments. Given that the experiment was conducted at a sportscard show, the sequence of events to participate in the experiment are discussed.

The Power of Di erentiation? - An Empirical Investigation on the Incentive E ects of Bonus Plans

Which Social Cost of Carbon? A Theoretical Perspective

In uence Activities and The Dark Sides of Decentralization: Evidence from A Chinese Newspaper

THEORY OF THE FIRM. Number of Workers Bread Loaves (thousands) :

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS*

A Competitive Facility Location Game with Traffic Congestion Costs

Motivating Information Acquisition through Organization Design

THE ECONOMICS OF MEDIA AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

The Direction of Innovation over the Product Life Cycle

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

On Quantity Competition and Transmission Constraints in Electricity Market

Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations

Introducing Managerial Attention Allocation in Incentive. Contracts

Coordination in Two-Sided Markets: Open Networks in the TV Industry

TARGETING IN ADVERTISING MARKETS: IMPLICATIONS FOR OFFLINE VS. ONLINE MEDIA. Dirk Bergemann and Alessandro Bonatti. March 2010 Revised August 2010

Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market. Richard J. Gilbert University of California

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Transcription:

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues Matthias Kräkel, University of Bonn Abstract We discuss the optimal sharing of broadcasting revenues given a central marketing system. The league s sports association wants to maximize the joint pro ts of the sports clubs owners. The results show that a winnertake-all scheme should be used, if the teams are homogeneous. However, if teams are su ciently heterogeneous, equal sharing will be optimal. Keywords: broadcasting revenues, equal sharing, sports leagues, revenue sharing, winner-take-all scheme. I would like to thank Oliver Gürtler and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Financial support by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG), grants KR 2077/2-3 and SFB/Transregio 15 Governance and the E ciency of Economic Systems, is gratefully acknowledged. Matthias Kräkel, BWL II, University of Bonn, Adenauerallee 24-42, D-53113 Bonn, Germany, tel: +49 228 733914, fax: +49 228 739210, e-mail: m.kraekel@uni-bonn.de. 1

1 Introduction In the theoretic literature on sport contests, clubs are typically assumed to buy playing talent in order to win matches. These expenditures for talent lead to a certain winning probability according to the well-known logitform contest success function. Implicitly, the models abstract from incentive problems among the teams players, i.e. given a certain talent, each player is automatically assumed to fully use his talent. This paper departs from the literature by assuming that players need to be given incentives to play hard. It focuses on endogenous incentives for players within a central marketing system in which the sport league (i.e. the respective sports association) chooses a sharing rule for distributing the league s broadcasting revenues among the league s sport clubs. We assume that a player s income is positively related to the individual revenues a club receives from the league. 1 In particular, we assume that a club s individual revenues are divided between the club owner and the team according to their bargaining powers. Within this framework, we will analyze which kind of sharing rule is optimal for the league. The results of the model show that the league will choose a winner-take-all scheme (i.e. the winner of the 1 Hall et al. (2002) empirically test the causality between team performance and payment. At least for the free agents in Major League Baseball pay for performance seems to be an appropriate assumption. However, in the model described in the next section we do not assume strict pay for performance. We only assume that a player participates in the revenues of his club and that these revenues depend on the club s success in the league. 2

league gets all the broadcasting revenues), if the teams are homogeneous. However, if teams are su ciently heterogeneous, the league will optimally choose equal sharing so that each club receives the same fraction of the revenues independent of the club s performance. There is some work related to this paper. Szymanski (2003a) as well as Kesenne (2005) also consider the case of sharing broadcasting revenues. However, in both papers clubs invest in playing talents which then determine a team s winning probability via the logit-form model; there is no modelling of players incentives. Szymanski (2003a, p. 22) tries to discuss revenue sharing on the basis of performance which would create incentives for clubs. Unfortunately, even within the standard logit-form setting an analytical solution cannot be derived. Palomino and Sakovics (2004) and Falconieri et al. (2004) also discuss the sharing of broadcasting revenues by a league which wants to maximize the clubs joint pro ts, but both papers abstract from the problem of incentives for individual players. Palomino and Sakovics show that competitive bidding for talent leads to an equal-sharing scheme in an isolated-league context, but in the case of inter-league competition for talent leagues may choose winner-take-all schemes. In the model of Falconieri et al. the league never chooses a winner-take-all scheme. The problem of individual incentives for players is addressed by Palomino and Rigotti (2000), Szymanski (2003b, pp. 1140 1146) and Gürtler (2006). In the Palomino-Rigotti paper, teams or clubs are modeled as collective players, i.e. the authors do not di erentiate between owners and players of a sport club so that there is no distributional con ict. If the sport league wants to 3

maximize the teams total pro ts, then it unambiguously has to choose equal sharing. Szymanski and Gürtler analyze incentives for players, but they do not consider the connection of a player s income, his club s revenues and the league s optimal sharing rule. The note is organized as follows. In the next section, the model is introduced. The formal results on optimal sharing are given in Section 3. The last section concludes. 2 The Model We consider a professional sports league which consists of two teams A and B. All individuals in the model are assumed to be risk neutral. In order to abstract from special team e ects (e.g. free riding) we assume that each team is held by one owner and has exactly one player. 2 When competing, team i (i = A; B) can either be successful and generates a high outcome i = 1, or be unsuccessful and realizes a low outcome i = 0. Let a i 2 [0; 1] denote the activities or e orts which are chosen by player i to win the match against the other team j (i; j = A; B; i 6= j). These activities may be short term (e.g. direct e orts during the match) but also long term (e.g. training intensity, eating discipline). We assume that player i realizes i = 1 with 2 This simplifying assumption is typically used in the theoretic models on professional team sport. An alternative interpretation would be that a team collectively decides on the activity level so that players should be interpreted as collective players. Two papers explicitly model teams that consist of at least two players: Gürtler and Kräkel (2003), Gürtler (2006). Of course, in both papers the well-known free-rider e ect applies. 4

probability a i, and i = 0 with probability 1 a i. In other words, each activity level a i 2 (0; 1) leads to a di erent lottery (1; a i ; 0; 1 a i ), with (1; a 00 ; 0; 1 a 00 ) dominating (1; a 0 ; 0; 1 a 0 ) within the meaning of rst-order stochastic dominance if a 00 > a 0. It is assumed that spending activities a i leads to a disutility or costs (e.g. opportunity costs for time consuming training) for player i which are described in monetary terms by the convex function c (a i ) = a2 i 2t i. 3 Here, t i denotes player i s talent; the higher a player s talent the lower will be his costs c (a i ). As pointed out in the introduction, the model focuses on the sharing of a league s broadcasting rights between both teams. We assume that broadcasting revenues can be described by a function of both teams performances: 4 B ( i ; j ) = i + j x ( i j ) 2 : (1) Eq. (1) shows that broadcasting revenues increase in the league s aggregate performance and in competitive balance: 5 The higher both teams outcomes (e.g. the larger the number of overall goals) and the closer the match (i.e. 3 This cost function can be either interpreted as disutility of e ort or as opportunity costs of time. As usual in principal-agent models, the cost function is assumed to be convex. The quadratic form is used for simpli cation. Since it is easier for more talented players to choose a high activity level, the function monotonically decreases in talent. Division by 2 is used as a normalization so that this number disappears when calculating the rst-order condition. 4 For a similar objective function see Falconieri et al. (2004). 5 Typically, competitive balance is measured via the teams winning probabilities. For reasons of analytical tractability, here we use a slightly di erent approach. Note that considering outcomes instead of probabilities does not make a great di erence. 5

the less the di erence between teams performances), the higher will be the league s revenues from selling broadcasting rights. The parameter x measures the impact of competitive balance. We assume x 2 (0; 1) so that revenues cannot become negative. In the following, we consider the distribution of broadcasting revenues B ( i ; j ) within the league. Let 2 1 2 ; 1 denote the share of the league winner in B ( i ; j ), whereas 1 describes the share of the loser in B ( i ; j ). 6 If both teams perform identically (i.e. i = j ), each team will receive B ( i ; j ) =2. Therefore, expected revenues of club i are given by i + j x ( i j ) 2 R i () = B (1; 0) a i (1 a j ) + (1 ) B (0; 1) a j (1 a i ) + B (1; 1) B (0; 0) a i a j + (1 a i ) (1 a j ) 2 2 = (1 x) a i (1 a j ) + (1 ) (1 x) a j (1 a i ) + a i a j = (1 x) (a j + (a i a j )) + xa i a j : (2) We assume that is chosen by the league in order to maximize the team owners pro ts. 7 For example, if the league chooses = 1 the teams will face a winner-take-all distribution scheme which is highly competitive. However, by choosing equal sharing = 1, the broadcasting revenues of a club are 2 independent of the club s performance within the league. It is assumed that a player s income is signi cantly in uenced by the success of his club and his bargaining power. In particular, we assume that 6 See also Palomino and Sakovics (2004), p. 788; Falconieri et al. (2004), p. 840. 7 The same assumption can be found in Palomino and Sakovics (2004) and Falconieri et al. (2004). Owners pro ts are de ned in the next paragraph. 6

player i receives the fraction i 2 (0; 1) of club i s broadcasting revenues R i (), whereas owner i obtains the fraction 1 i. Hence, player i s objective function is given by EU i (a i ) = i R i () a 2 i 2t i = i ((1 x) (a j + (a i a j )) + xa i a j ) a 2 i 2t i (3) and the objective function of owner i by i = (1 i ) R i () = (1 i ) ((1 x) (a j + (a i a j )) + xa i a j ) : (4) The timing of the game is as follows: At the rst stage, the league determines the revenue-sharing scheme by choosing in order to maximize the club owners joint pro ts A + B. At the second stage, the teams or players compete by choosing their respective activities a i. 3 Results We start by considering the second stage. Here, each player i chooses a i in order to maximize his expected net income according to Eq. (3). The rst-order condition yields the following reaction function: 8 a i = i t i ((1 x) + xa j ) : 8 Note that the second-order condition is always satis ed since player i s objective function is strictly concave. 7

Together with j s reaction function a j = j t j ((1 x) + xa i ) we obtain the Nash equilibrium 9 a i = (1 x) it i (1 + x j t j ) 1 x 2 i j t i t j and a j = (1 x) jt j (1 + x i t i ) 1 x 2 i j t i t j : (5) Obviously, each activity level monotonically increases in the sharing parameter in equilibrium. In other words, the league can directly in uence incentives by choosing an appropriate value of. Furthermore, comparative statics immediately show that @a i @ i t i > 0 and @a i @ j t j > 0. The intuition is the following one: Broadcasting revenues and, therefore, players incomes are determined by overall performance so that we have a kind of team production in which both players activities are complements. In this situation, increased bargaining power and increased talent do not only enhance one s own incentives but also the incentives of the other player. At the rst stage, the league maximizes owners joint pro ts i + j. According to (4), we have i + j = (1 i ) ((1 x) (a j + (a i a j )) + xa i a j ) + (1 j ) ((1 x) (a i + (a j a i )) + xa i a j ) = (1 x) (a i (1 j ) + a j (1 i ) ( i j ) (a i a j )) + (2 i j ) xa i a j : (6) By inspection of (6) we obtain the rst result: We have to assume that parameter values guarantee a i ; a j 2 [0; 1]. Hence, we assume x 2 i j t i t j < 1 and (1 x) i t i (1 + x j t j ) < 1 x 2 i j t i t j and (1 x) j t j (1 + x i t i ) < 1 x 2 i j t i t j. 8

Proposition 1 If players are homogeneous in bargaining power and talent (i.e. t i i = t j j ), then the league will choose a winner-take-all scheme = 1. Proof. If t i i = t j j, according to Eq. (5) both players will choose the same activity level in equilibrium so that ( i j ) (a i a j ) cancels out in the league s objective function. The remaining part (1 x) (a i (1 j ) + a j (1 i )) + (2 i j ) xa i a j strictly increases in both players activity levels. The league then chooses the upper bound for since activities are monotonically increasing in. Given homogeneity among the players, the sharing parameter only has an impact on players incentives. Since broadcasting revenues depend on joint performance, the club owners and, hence, the league prefer to induce maximum incentives to the players. 10 It seems somewhat natural that the owners and the league are interested in high incentives for the players. Hence, the question remains whether there are any situations, in which the league does not choose a winner-take-all scheme in the given setting. The following proposition gives an answer to this question: Proposition 2 If players are su ciently heterogeneous in bargaining power and talent, then the league will choose equal sharing = 1 2. Proof. Let player i be a very strong player (i.e. i and t i are very large) and player j be very weak in the sense of j! 0 and t j! 0. According to 10 Note that homogeneous players always receive a positive expected utility: EU i (a i ) = a i > 0 since x it i < 1 so that equilibrium e orts are positive. i(1 x)((2 ) 2x it i(1 )) 2(1 x it i) 9

(5), we then have a j! 0 so that the league s objective function reduces to i + j = (1 x) (1 i ) a i (7) and player i s equilibrium activity to a i = (1 x) i t i : (8) Inserting a i into (7) yields the function () = (1 x) 2 (1 i ) i t i which describes a parabola open to the bottom with a global maximum at = 1 2 i : Since player i is very strong in the sense of i! 1 we obtain = 1 2. An intuition can be given by inspection of the league s objective function i + j = (1 i ) ((1 x) (a j + (a i a j )) + xa i a j ) + (1 j ) ((1 x) (a i + (a j a i )) + xa i a j ) : Very strong heterogeneity is detrimental for the league, because the positive externalities due to team production i.e. a j a i decrease in players heterogeneity. If player j becomes very weak in the sense of a j! 0, externalities even completely diminish so that i + j = (1 i ) (1 x) a i + (1 j ) ((1 x) (1 ) a i ) : Note that the rst term describes expected pro ts of club owner i whereas the second term stands for club owner j s expected pro ts. When player i is very 10

strong (i.e. i! 1) and player j very weak (i.e. j! 0), the league s pro ts become identical with club owner j s pro ts: (1 x) (1 ) a i. Hence, we have a distribution e ect in the sense that the sharing parameter should be xed at its lower bound 1 2 in order to give club j as much as possible from the broadcasting revenues. However, there is also an incentive e ect of since players activities monotonically increase in the sharing parameter. This trade-o becomes clear by comparison of Eqs. (7) and (8). Since the distribution e ect dominates the incentive e ect, the league optimally chooses equal sharing. 4 Conclusion In this paper, we have analyzed the connection of revenue sharing and players incentives within professional team sports. For this purpose, we assumed that a player s income is positively related to the broadcasting revenues which his sport club receives from the league via central marketing. Alternatively, we could assume that a player directly receives bonuses that depend on team success or failure. However, note that the model used in this paper can also be interpreted in this direction, because it would be strategically equivalent whether a player receives certain lump-sum payments dependent on team performance or he receives a certain fraction of the club s revenues which depend on success/failure. 11 The results of the model show that the optimal sharing arrangement 11 See, in analogy, Pepall and Richards (2001), p. 492. 11

crucially depends on the degree of homogeneity among the sports teams. In this paper, we have assumed that the spectators are especially interested in aggregate performance of the teams (e.g. in the number of goals) and in competitive balance (i.e. in a close match). These interests explain the positive relation to the amount of broadcasting revenues. However, there may be other possible speci cations of the league s objective function. For example, spectators may be interested in maximum performances of single players, but this aspect should be more important in connection with individual sports (e.g. beating a world record) and not with team sport. Finally, the two-team model could be extended to competition between more than two teams. In this case, competition for becoming the league winner would be stronger compared to the two-team case. Of course, the strength of competition in uences players incentives but the qualitative results of this paper concerning the impact of homogeneity and heterogeneity of the players should remain the same. 12

References Falconieri, S., Palomino, F., & Sakovics, J. (2004). Collective versus individual sale of television rights in league sports. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(5), 833 862. Gürtler, O. (2006). A rationale for the coexistence of central and decentral marketing in team sports. German Economic Review (forthcoming) Gürtler, O. and Kräkel, M. (2003). Who is Declared Dead Lives Longer. Applied Economics Letters, 10, 995 997. Hall, S., Szymanski, S., & Zimbalist, A.S. (2002). Testing causality between team performance and payroll. Journal of Sports Economics, 3(2), 149 168. Kesenne, S. (2005). Revenue sharing and competitive balance. Journal of Sports Economics, 6(1), 98 106. Palomino, F. & Rigotti, L. (2000). The Sport League s Dilemma: Competitive Balance versus Incentives to Win. Discussion Paper E00-292, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Palomino, F. & Sakovics, J. (2004). Inter-league competition for talent vs. competitive balance. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22, 783 797. Pepall, L.M. & Richards D.J. (2001). Reach for the stars: a strategic bidding game. Economica, 68, 489 504. 13

Szymanski, S. (2003a). Incentives and competitive balance in team sports. European Sport Management Quarterly, 3, 11 30. Szymanski, S. (2003b). The economic design of sporting contests. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 1137 1187. 14