The Economic Benefits of Generation Revenue Assessment in Pool-Based Market Model for Restructured Electricity Supply Industry

Similar documents
Enhanced Time of Use Electricity Pricing for Industrial Customers in Malaysia

CHAPTER 5 SOCIAL WELFARE MAXIMIZATION FOR HYBRID MARKET

MOHAMED A. M. ALMAKTAR

Seminar on African Electrical Interconnection. Module 7 - Market Operational Structures

The Effect of Water Cement Ratio on Cement Brick Containing High Density Polyethylene (HDPE) as Sand Replacement

An Evaluation of the Proposed Procurement Auction for the Purchase of Medicare Equipment: Experimental Tests of the Auction Architecture 1

3.2 Market Buyers Spot Market Energy Charges.

Cost of Service and Public Policy. Ted Kury Director of Energy Studies, PURC

3.2 Market Settlements.

ENERGY FORUM Consumers Perspective on Energy Issues By Philip Tan Representing FMM August 9, 2010 Sheraton Imperial Hotel, KL

Pay-As-Bid versus Uniform Pricing Mechanism in Restructured Power Systems. Mohammad Sadegh Javadi 1, Amin Javadinasab 2

Markets run by ISO New England

Engineering, Economics and Regulation of the Electric Power Sector TERM PAPERS

Price Formation Education Session Day 1 Economic Dispatch

BRIEF POLICY. Enhancing flexibility and ensuring efficiency and security: Improving the electricity market in Brazil

A Brief Introduction to EIM Bidding and Market Design 9/7/2017

Frank A. Wolak Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford, CA March 30, 2005

Recovering fixed costs in electricity markets

RTP and demand-side bidding in restructured electricity markets

EPCC 11. HASHIM A. ALZAHRANI Saudi Electricity Company System Operation and Control Department Market Management Experts

Economics & Markets: Capacity Markets (Presentation to the CIAC) April 17 th, 2018

Power Markets and Renewables Deployment in Developing Countries

Monopoly Power : Social Consequences

Renewable sources of energy, dispatching priority and balancing the system, facts and options: Part I

Introduction: from regulated to liberalized markets in electricity

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power

Market Responsive Pricing Policy Mechanism Brief

Competitive Markets 1

All details of the opportunity must be entered and submitted on the online form.

IB Economics Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply 1.4: Price Signals and Market Efficiency

Variously Worldwide Types of Deregulated Electricity Markets and Their Respective Transmission Congestion Management Schemes

Testing The Effects Of Price Responsive Demand On Uniform Price And Soft-Cap Electricity Auctions

Challenges of implementing Sustainability in Malaysian Housing Industry

Committed Offer: Offer on which a resource was scheduled by the Office of the Interconnection for a particular clock hour for the Operating Day.

Assessment Of Market Clearing Price And Social Welfare In A Competitive Electricity Market

Competitive Markets. Jeffrey Ely. January 13, This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 License.

Analysis of Electricity Markets. Lennart Söder

International Competitive Bidding For New Generation Capacity: The Malaysia s Experience

Sustainable Energy Management Practices and Its Effect on EEI: A Study on University Buildings

1. First of all, the CREG analysed the way in which the market operates. Its conclusions are as follows:

PJM Markets. Energy and Ancillary Services. PJM State & Member Training Dept. PJM /29/2014

Corporate Sourcing of Renewable Energy Cillian O Donoghue, Climate & Energy Manager, Eurometaux - European Non-Ferrous Metals Association

Better Markets, Better Products, Better Prices

Financial Transmission Rights

LMI Workshop on Regulation and Regional Coordination Bangkok - Thailand

Mexican Electricity Reform

Performance of Copper, Copper Tungsten, Graphite and Brass Electrode on MRR, EWR and SR of Aluminium LM6 in EDM Die Sinking

Monte-Carlo Optimization Framework for Assessing Electricity Generation Portfolios

Summary of 2016 MISO State of the Market Report

Modelling Transitions to Robust High-VRE Systems

Uniform Price vs. Differentiated Payment Auctions

The Development of Condition Assessment for Heritage Building

Market design for large shares of renewables: time and space

COMMENTS ON ERGEG POSITION PAPER ON SMART GRIDS

Design Criteria for Energy Market Prices

BRIEF OUTLOOK ON MALAYSIAN ELECTRICITY SUPPLY INDUSTRY, TNB & MALAYSIA NATIONAL COMMITTEE OF CIGRE (MNC-CIGRE)

5.1 Transmission Congestion Charge Calculation Calculation by Office of the Interconnection.

PÖYRY POINT OF VIEW - NOVEMBER Solar in the Middle East - How to realise the benefits

Introduction. Section One: Good Auctions Exist

Testing Alternative Market Designs for Energy and VArs in a Deregulated Electricity Market

Quick Guide to the I-SEM

Fundamentals of Markets

PowerWeb Testing of Various Auction Clearing Mechanisms for Electricity

Rules on Initiation of Power Procurement and Review of Power Purchase Agreements. Eng. Anastas Mbawala, EWURA

Locational Marginal Pricing II: Unlocking the Mystery

Competitive Markets. Facilitated Dialogue: Market Restructuring & Renewable Energy. June 10-12, 2013 Mexico City, Mexico. Hisham Choueiki, Ph.D., P.E.

Continuous Improvement and its Barriers in Electrical and Electronic Industry

Bidding Strategy I Day-Ahead Market 8 th February 2017 I New Delhi

Renewable Energy Auctions Overview

Analytical hierarchy process (AHP) approach to the selection of heritage building element

Nuclear Energy and Renewables: System Effects in Low carbon Electricity Systems

Forecasting low-cost housing demand in Pahang, Malaysia using Artificial Neural Networks

For clarification, or to submit additional questions and feedback, please contact

Pricing of RES in the EU

Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Working Paper on Standardized Transmission Service and Wholesale Electric Market Design

(4 November 2016 to date) ELECTRICITY REGULATION ACT 4 OF 2006

Recent Development in Reliable Energy Market in the US and Singapore

FERC Docket EL Fast-Start Resources

LECTURE February Thursday, February 21, 13

Alberta Capacity Market

VALUE OF SHARING DATA

Methodology for calculating subsidies to renewables

Regulating Power Market (RPM) Review Study

MEDICAL APPOINTMENT APPLICATION

Electricity Generation

Source: Shell Extended Policy Scenario and IEA historical data Source: Shell The Role of Electricity in a Lower CO 2 World In a world where lower emis

NORDENERGI SECRETARIAT

OEM Customer Management for Automotive Suppliers

JLL Energy & Infrastructure Advisory. Corporate PPAs: The Devil s In The Detail

Notes on the Role of Regulation in the Management of New Zealand s Electricity

LMP Calculation and Uplift

Design Alternatives Sheet (DAS) 18 Physical Bilateral Procurement

Day-Ahead Price Forecasting of Electricity Market Using Neural Networks and Wavelet Transform

Welfare economics part 2 (producer surplus) Application of welfare economics: The Costs of Taxation & International Trade

Price Formation. Eric Ciccoretti Attorney-Advisor Office of Energy Policy and Innovation Federal Energy Regulatory Commission June 13, 2017

Memorandum. This memorandum requires EIM Governing Body action. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Standard Market Design in the Electric Market: Some Cautionary Thoughts. June 20, Prepared by: Philip Hanser Metin Celebi Peter Fox-Penner

Reforms of Power Sector & Liberalisation. The Indian Perspective

The Relationship between TQM Practices with TQM Tools and Techniques in Small and Medium Enterprise (SMEs)

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ) ) )

Transcription:

The Economic Benefits of Generation Revenue Assessment in -Based Market Model for Restructured Electricity Supply Industry Zuraidah Ngadiron 1, *, N.H Radzi 1 and M.Y. Hassan 2 1 Faculty of Electrical and Electronic Engineering, Universiti Tun Hussein Onn Malaysia, Batu Pahat, Malaysia 2 Centre of Electrical Energy Systems (CEES), Faculty of Electrical Engineering, Universiti Teknologi Malaysia, Johor Bahru, Malaysia Abstract. The electricity supply industry had undergo deregulation and restructuring toward becoming a more transparent and competitive electricity market environment. The pool market model is amongst the most preferred electricity market model. Even though it is a safe option to be more competitive and transparent electricity supply industry, there are issues on the welfare of the generators involved. This paper addresses the pricing issue in the pool market by extending the capacity payment mechanism in the single auction power pool. In the proposed model, the approach of minimum capacity payment involving the efficiency of the generators is introduced. A case study is conducted to illustrate the proposed model. An economic analysis is performed to highlight the merits of the proposed model with the pure pool in term of generation revenue. 1 Introduction In the competitive electricity market, participation of generation companies and large consumers in bidding methodologies is for their own advantages. By strategically bidding, the electricity generating companies expect to maximize their profits and control the market price. Even though, they will suffer in great losses of market efficiency because their offers will deviate from the true marginal costs. Furthermore, incur much more payments from the consumers than really required. In order to achieve a maximum return, it is very important for the generation companies to formulate optimal bidding strategies with risk terminology before step into the electricity market, as the market clearing price (MCP) in this landscape is flexible [1]. The pool market model is a standout amongst the most preferred power market model actualized in many developing countries. Regardless of being the sensible and safe choice for a more competitive and straightforward power supply industry, there are issues on the welfare of the generators included. As reported by Zou et al. [2], which utilized of the analytical paradigm of economic mechanism design theory is to deduce and design a customized pool-based market mechanism, in order to fulfill three major properties; incentive compatibility, individual rationality, and payment cost minimization. * Corresponding author: zuraidahn@gmail.com The Authors, published by EDP Sciences. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0 (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

One of pool market model major benefits is that it provides a market for generators unable to sell their output via contract to a specific customer. This study is focusing on the economic aspect from the perspective of the generators. Therefore, the proposed model is being designed in order to overcome several disadvantages of the pure pool market such as price fluctuation and market power exercise. 2 Improvement of Based Market Model for Malaysia Electricity Supply Industry (MESI) The reformed of single buyer is reinforced by implementation of competitive bidding, while the Incentive Based Regulation (IBR) will ensure the efficient operation [3]. Yet still single buyer model lack of competition due to long term of Power Purchase Agreements (PPAs). Nevertheless, there are few issues of introducing the pure pool market model such as price fluctuation and market power exercises. Thus, it is important to modify the existing pure pool model, so it can provide a fair market to supplier and user. It is reported at low load condition, the generators would gain more revenue under single buyer model compared to pool market model, whereas at high load demand, the generators would gain more revenue under pool market model [4]. Aifa [5] proposed an alternative electricity market model, hybrid model for MESI, which combines the pure pool market and pro-rata base load profile. In the meantime, Nuryasmin [6] proposed a minimum generation model that guaranteed income for all IPPs, and also generates profit for Tenaga Nasional Berhad (TNB). An improvement of hybrid model by Nurehan et. al [7,8] successfully overcomes the shortcomings of the pool market model, in the context of guaranteed revenue remuneration for the generator with the introduction of based load demand sharing approach known as hybrid model 1 (HM 1), and hybrid model 2 (HM 2). The introduction of the base load sharing is to ensure the expensive generator will get the remuneration, in order to overcome the problem in the pool market model. This is because there is no revenue during low electricity demand for the expensive generator. However, all these models did not consider on the efficiency, and the electricity price offered by generators during base load sharing. Furthermore, the base load power plants are designated based on their low cost generation, efficiency, and safety at rated output power levels. 3 Methodology of Proposed Market Model Malaysia load profile curve in Fig. 1(a) is used to present the pure pool, HM 1, HM 2, and the proposed market model. Fig. 1(b) shows the aggregated generation curve and the system marginal price (SMP) at 30%, 50%, 80%, and 100% demand, which proven the pool market price is extremely high due to high SMP, during high electricity demand. Two load profile curves for Sunday, and Monday are used in this research. Assuming the generators bid the same price for the 24 hours, Table 1 shows the details of the sixteen generators selected around Malaysia. Instead of open cycle gas turbine (OCGT), only combine cycle gas turbine (CCGT) and thermal plant type are chosen due to the efficiency and price offered by the generator. This is because generation costs of OCGT are much higher, and the low load-factor of the peak-load services [9]. As the monetary values involved in this paper are confidential, estimated values in used instead. 2

(a) 200 Energy Bid Price SMP at 100% demand Energy Bid Price (RM/MWh) 180 160 140 SMP at 30% demand SMP at 80% demand SMP at 50% demand 120 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000 12000 14000 16000 Installed Capacity (MW) Fig. 1. (a): Diagram of Malaysia load profile curves; (b): The aggregated generation curve and the SMP at 30%, 50%, 80%, and 100% demand. This proposed model is an improvement of the pool based marketing model. It comprises of electricity demand sharing and capacity payment approaches, in order to educate the generators to apply low prices for electricity generated. Thus, Independent Power Producers (IPPs) can contribute power to the power purchaser at all times. In addition, the efficiency of the generators is taken into account. This proposed market model has categorized the electricity demand into two areas, identified as a high demand area and low demand area. The low and high demand areas are determined from the daily electricity demand curve, constructed using the demand forecasting data. A line is drawn on the (b) 3

hourly electricity demand curve at 80% of the peak demand, which is used as the reference line to distinguish the low demand and high demand areas on the electricity demand curves. The electricity demand sharing is applied under high demand area. Meanwhile, the capacity payment is added for low demand area. Table 1. Details on plant types, MW installed capacity, bid price, capacity price, and efficiency of 16 generators in Malaysia. Gen Plant Type Installed Capacity (MW) Energy/Bid Price (RM/MW/h) Capacity Price (RM/MW/month) Efficiency (%) 1 CCGT 720 120 30000 46.91 2 CCGT 640 130 30000 40.82 3 CCGT 334 130 35000 43.64 4 CCGT 650 140 35000 43.64 5 CCGT 350 145 35000 43.64 6 Thermal 2420 150 20000 39.03 7 CCGT 1170 150 30000 45.62 8 CCGT 762 150 45000 44.22 9 CCGT 1136 160 30000 40.74 10 Thermal 2100 160 30000 20.91 11 CCGT 440 165 35000 43.64 12 CCGT 100 175 35000 43.64 13 Thermal 100 175 30000 35.99 14 CCGT 1303 180 40000 42.09 15 Thermal 1400 190 25000 35.91 16 Thermal 2100 200 55000 25.82 3.1 The Low Demand Area. The low demand area consists of the hourly electricity demand below the 80% of the peak demand value, and will be traded through bidding competition as in the pool market. Nevertheless, pool market cannot guarantee continuous remuneration for IPPs when the electricity demand is low. Consequently, numerous of high costs IPPs will experience low or even zero revenue during low demand period. Therefore, capacity payment with minimum generation is added during low electricity demand, in order to ensure continuous remuneration for all IPPs regardless their submitted energy bid prices and the fluctuating electricity demand. This minimum generation is based on the efficiency of the generator generates the electricity. Under the same bidding system as applied in the pool market model, the payment for power generated will depend on the SMP, which determined from the last IPPs being dispatched at that period of time. The purchasing price in low demand area, C PP is paid to the IPPs for the power generated in an hour. 3.2 The High Demand Area. The electricity demand under high demand area will be traded through demand sharing and bidding competition. The 80% reference line will separate electricity demand in the high area into two parts; i) the electricity demand below the 80% reference line will be traded equally among the IPPs through demand sharing approach, and ii) the IPPs will compete against each other to supply the remaining demand in the area above the 80% reference line. The distribution of the shared electricity demand depends on the IPPs available capacity. IPP with the highest capacity will have the biggest share of the sharing electricity 4

demand. The payment during electricity demand sharing will be determined by two factors; the SMP of the sharing demand and the amount of electricity demand shares of each IPP. C PP80 is the sharing price with the SMP value at the total shared demand (80% of peak electricity demand). The upper part of the high demand area will be put under bidding competition using the energy bid prices submitted by the IPPs. During this time, all IPP are involved, from the cheapest to the expensive generators. 4 Results and Discussion In order to be selected in the generation dispatch, IPPs must win in the energy bidding. The IPPs with the lower energy bid price compared to the hourly SMP will be selected to fulfil the electricity demand for that hour. The SMP at 100% demand was RM200 followed by RM190, RM160 and RM150 at 80%, 50%, and 30% demand respectively. All participated IPPs in the electricity dispatch are paid according to the pool price which is determined from hourly SMP. In this case study, the power contribution is chosen at 80% from the peak demand for the load demand sharing, reducing the SMP to RM190. Consequently, the production cost of electricity will be lower, in order to control the price fluctuation during high demand. Therefore, the non-participated IPPs are exposed to the risk of losing their revenue, because only at 100% demand, all IPPs received the revenue. It means that, more IPPs will lose their revenue as the electricity demand keeps reducing. However, the IPPs revenue in the pool market continues to strike as the demand keeps increasing due to most IPPs are paid at a higher price compared to their own bid price. For example, IPP 1 is paid with RM190 for every MW power produced at 80% demand, which is RM70 higher compared to its initial bid price. Fig. 2 (a) and (b) illustrate the comparison of generator s revenue on Sunday, and Monday respectively. The figures indicate that from low to middle price, the generators received the highest revenue under pure pool, but the revenue decreased for the expensive generator. This is because the generators were stacked from the lowest to the highest prices offered by generator. Furthermore, a cheaper generator will get the chance to win in the bidding competition. The generator s revenue of the proposed model is increasing compared to HM 1 and HM 2 during low to medium price generator. 1 10000000 Sunday _min. gen. CP 8000000 6000000 4000000 1 10000000 8000000 6000000 4000000 Monday _min. gen. CP 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Generator (a) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Generator (b) Fig. 2. (a) and (b): Comparison of generator s revenue for Sunday and Monday. It is reasonable to introduce minimum generation capacity payment based on the generator efficiency, instead of paying full capacity payment as compensation to the generators, because the possibility of expensive generators not selected in the bidding competition is high. Nonetheless, as a reward, this same type of capacity payment also will be given to the IPPs which have won in the bidding competition as an incentive, in order to 5

educate the IPPs to bid and sell their electricity produced at a lower price. For proposed method, the reduction of revenue for expensive generators does happen compared to HM 2, due to this change. 2800000 2600000 2400000 2200000 _min. gen. CP Sunday 1800000 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 (a) hour 3600000 3400000 3200000 3000000 2800000 2600000 2400000 2200000 _min. gen. CP Monday 1800000 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 (b) Fig. 3. (a) and (b): Comparison of hourly generation revenue for Sunday and Monday. Fig. 3 (a) and (b) show the hourly generation revenue. HM 1 and pure pool model is the lowest and the highest revenue, respectively. For HM 2 and the proposed method, the revenue almost the same for the high demand. Meanwhile, revenue during low demand is slightly higher for the proposed method compared to HM 2, due to minimum generation capacity payment execution for participated and non-participated generator in the bidding competition. hour 5 Conclusion Worldwide experience with the single buyer model has raised concern on how this model backfires due to poorly constructed such as lack of transparency and fairness, poor system planning and non-competitive. Several observers also voiced concerns over a profit-seeking single buyer, citing conflict of interest, duplication of cost and tariff hikes. Conversely, the pool market model offers full competitive model and based on uniform price scheme. The most expensive generators might not be able to get any revenue at all. Thus, will force each 6

of them to bid for the cheapest energy price most of the time, and this will create competition. The proposed model seems to be very effective. As it gives the opportunity more to the least cost generators to participate not only in base load demand, but also in peak load demand. However, minimum generation capacity payment also given as an incentive, and compensation for the least cost and expensive generator, which participate and lost in bidding competition respectively. As a result, it creates win-win situations between the generators as the seller and distributor as the buyer. References 1. K. Asokan, R. Ashok Kumar, International Journal of Soft Computing and Engineering (2013) 2. Peng Zou, Qixin Chen, Qing Xia, Chang He, Chongqing Kang, Appl. Energy, 158, 508 (2015) 3. N.Z. Mohd Zamin, N.Z. Zainol Abidin, Joon B. Ibrahim, In TENCON Spring Conference, 2013 IEEE ( 2013) 4. M.Y. Hassan, M.P. Abdullah, A.S. Arifin, F. Hussin, M.S. Majid, IEEE International Conference In Power and Energy ( 2008) 5. A.S. Arifin, IEEE International Conference In Power and Energy ( 2008) 6. Nor Yasmin Binti Ismail, Electricity Market Model For Deregulated Electricity Supply Industry (Diss. UTM, Skudai, 2011) 7. Nurehan Othman, Mohammad Yusri Hassan, Faridah Hussin, Md Pauzi Abdullah, International Journal of Integrated Engineering, 5, 26 (2013) 8. Nurehan Binti Othman, Improving Electricity Market Model For Malaysia Electric Supply Industry (Diss. UTM, Skudai, 2014) 9. J.D. Gifford, IEA, 02 (2011) 10. N. Othman, M.Y. Hassan, F. Hussin, IEEE International Conference In Power and Energy (2012) 11. A. Khalid, N. Jaat, A. Sapit, A. Razali, B. Manshoor, I. Zaman, International Journal of Automotive and Mechanical Engineering, 11, 2447 (2015) 12. A. Khalid, N. Tamaldin, M. Jaat, M.F.M. Ali, B. Manshoor, I. Zaman, Procedia Engineering, 68, 225 (2013) 7