ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER. Department of Economics Tufts University Medford, MA (617)

Similar documents
Vertical Mergers. The retailer has marginal cost of Pu+lOO where PU is the price per unit charged by the upstream manufacturer Grapefruit.

The Sports Product Market ECONOMICS OF SPORTS (ECON 325) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

Unit 7. Firm behaviour and market structure: monopoly

4. A situation in which the number of competing firms is relatively small is known as A. Monopoly B. Oligopoly C. Monopsony D. Perfect competition

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

Monopolistic Markets. Regulation

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #9 Chapter 12: Capturing Surplus

Monopoly. Firm s equilibrium. Muhammad Rafi Khan

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 22: Game Theory 4 Not Really Game Theory. The Story So Far. Today. Two Part Tariff.

SAMPLE MULTIPLE CHOICE FINAL EXAM CHAPTER 6 THE ANALYSIS OF COSTS

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

Economics. Monopolistic Perfect Competition. Monopolistic Competition. Monopolistic Competition 11/29/2013. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

ECONS 101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS QUIZ #6 Week 04/19/09 to 04/25/09

A Classroom Experiment on Import Tariffs and Quotas Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition

Industrial Organization 04

Price Discrimination: Exercises Part 2

Economics 361 Assessment

ECON 4100: Industrial Organization. Lecture 1- Introduction and a review of perfect competition versus monopoly

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2009

c) Will the monopolist described in (b) earn positive, negative, or zero economic profits? Explain your answer.

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik)

Durable Goods Monopoly with Endogenous Quality

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3D

MICROECONOMICS SECTION I. Time - 70 minutes 60 Questions

ECON 2100 (Summer 2014 Sections 08 & 09) Exam #3D

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Final Exam December 8, 2006

Introduction Question Bank

ECON 2100 (Summer 2015 Sections 07 & 08) Exam #3C

Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Customer Lifetime Value Analysis

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

Chapter 25: Monopoly Behavior

Economics. Monopolistic Competition. Firms in Competitive Markets. Monopolistic Competition 11/22/2012. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

Deadweight Loss of Monopoly

Export Decisions, Outsourcing, and Multinational Enterprises. Global Economy: Firms in the. Chapter 8

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

Chapter 1: MANAGERS, PROFITS, AND MARKETS

Market Concentration and Power

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion

DO NOT OPEN THE QUESTION PAPER UNTIL INSTRUCTED TO DO SO BY THE CHIEF INVIGILATOR. MICROECONOMICS TWO HOURS (2 Hours)

Part III. Sources of market power. Chapter 6. Advertising and related marketing strategies

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Monopoly. Basic Economics Chapter 15. Why Monopolies Arise. Monopoly

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Introduction. Managerial Problem. Solution Approach

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

Coffee is produced at a constant marginal cost of $1.00 a pound. Due to a shortage of cocoa beans, the marginal cost rises to $2.00 a pound.

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

Bonanno, G. (1987), Location Choice, Product Proliferation and Entry Deterrence, Review of

Test 3 Econ 3144 Fall 2010 Dr. Rupp 31 Multiple Choice Questions Signature I have neither given nor received aid on this exam

CH 14. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Bandwagon Effects and Local Monopoly Pricing In Professional Team Sports Market. J M Kang, Y. J. Ryu, Peng Liu

FINAL EXAMINATION. Special Instructions: Date: DECEMBER 15, 2000 School Year: Course and No.: ECON1006EA Time: 1:30 PM- 3:30 PM

ECON 2100 (Summer 2015 Sections 07 & 08) Exam #3A

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 4 pp Introduction

Econ 8601 Fall 2018 Take-Home Final. You can choose when to work on it, but please work only one

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Process and product innovation in a vertically differentiated monopoly

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2017

Chapter 6. Preview. Introduction. Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade

Chapter 1- Introduction

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

sample test 3 - spring 2013

AQA Economics A-level

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

Economic Analysis for Business Decisions Multiple Choice Questions Unit-2: Demand Analysis

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

1-4. Nash Equilibrium outcome of a game theory model where all players are doing the best they can given the actions of all other players.

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Chapter 10 Pure Monopoly

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Producer Theory - Monopoly

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3C Answer Key

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

Chapter 12. Monopoly. Chapter Outline. Key Ideas. Key Ideas. Introducing a New Market Structure. Evidence-Based Economics Example 11/25/2016

Chapter 10: Monopoly

ECON 1000 D. Come to the PASS workshop with your mock exam complete. During the workshop you can work with other students to review your work.

CH 13. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Mass versus Direct Advertising and Product Quality

5. A Positive Statement A. attempts to explain how the world actually is or how the world actually functions.

MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS. Townley, Chapter 4

Alternative Trade Theories!

Bundling Industrial Organisation Theory

Monopolistic Competition

Transcription:

ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER 2016 Department of Economics Tufts University Medford, MA 02155 (617) 627-3560 http://ase.tufts.edu/economics/

The Veblen Effect, Targeted Advertising and Consumer Welfare By Lynne Pepall and Joseph Reiff 1 ABSTRACT The technology of advertising in the twenty-first century allows for better targeting of consumers and better identification of consumer subgroups in the population. This makes it easier for firms to create in their advertising a desire to belong to the group identified with a product. We explore this kind of advertising in a monopoly model. The firm has an incentive to target this kind of advertising to the most lucrative segment of a particular social grouping and while advertising does create value for the consumer, it leads to an outcome where less output is sold at a higher price in a narrower or more segmented market than in the standard monopoly model. As a result even though consumers value the identification effect they are worse off. This is because the firm uses advertising to exploit a form of price discrimination and appropriate more surplus. KEYWORDS: Targeted Advertising, Peer Effects, Monopoly. JEL CODES: L12, M3 1 Department of Economics, Tufts University; Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; The authors would like to thank Laura Gee, John Kwoka, Dan Richards, and Jeff Zabel for their helpful comments. The views expressed in this paper are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.

The Veblen Effect, Targeted Advertising and Consumer Welfare 1. Introduction The Veblen effect, traditionally associated with conspicuous consumption, is in today s parlance, associated with brand name products that are functionally equivalent to cheaper products but confer a social status valued by the consumer. However, unlike in Veblen s era, this effect is no longer restricted to luxury goods. Hip people wear Brand X clothing, smart people buy that brand of appliance, and popular kids have that brand of toy. The social status or meaning system embedded in a brand name, such as in the Harley Davidson brand, is often the overarching goal of a firm s advertising strategy. In recent years this goal has become more important as technological and social forces increase the value of brand identity and its power to the consumer. This paper presents a simple monopoly model of advertising to create a Veblen effect; that is, advertising creates a desire for the consumer to belong to the reference group associated with the product. We show that a firm has an incentive to tailor its advertising messages to create a social identity for its product and to target its advertising at the most lucrative segment of a particular social grouping. This insight is consistent with what popular marketing gurus preach - once you know who you are targeting, it is much easier to figure out which media you can use to reach them and what marketing messages will resonate with them. 2 2 http://www.marketingdonut.co.uk/, http://adage.com/blogs/

Our approach to advertising builds on the insights of identity economics in Akerlof and Kranton (2005) and Becker and Murphy (1993). It can be considered complementary to Wirgenfelt (1990), Clark and Horstman (2005) and Pastine and Pastine (2002, 2008) where advertising helps the consumer coordinate his or her consumption choices on the popular brand in a market of competing brands. Advertising can however create for the consumer a valued peer effect or group identification that is profitable for the firm even if there is no competition from a rival. If peers in the target group buy the advertised product, it reinforces the view to the consumer that this is the right choice for someone seeking to belong to that group. We show that when advertising is designed to create this kind of Veblen effect, while it does create value for the consumer, it leads to an outcome where less output is sold at a higher price in a narrower or more segmented market than in the standard monopoly model. As a result, even though consumers value the identification effect, they are worse off. This is because the firm uses advertising to exploit a form of price discrimination and appropriate more surplus. The traditional monopolist has only price as a tool and hence, will maximize profit by serving more consumers at a lower price than the advertising monopolist who has both price and advertising tools. 2. A Monopoly Model of Identity and Peer Effect Advertising The firm s goal in advertising is to target a consumer group with messaging that creates a valued association to the brand and increases the willingness to pay. Suppose that a monopolist is selling a product of quality V at constant marginal cost c, which we set equal to zero. Assume that there is a unit mass of consumers each of whom will buy at most one unit of the product. In the absence of advertising, the net surplus of the ith consumer is:

U i = θ i V p if the good is purchased = 0 otherwise (1) where θ i is uniformly distributed over the interval [0,1]. The parameter θ rank orders consumers by the intensity of their preference for the good, and could be related to income as well as other life style characteristics. The monopolist who does not advertise maximizes profit by choosing to serve the marginal consumer θθ MM = 1, or a target consumer population 2 of ½, at a price pp MM = VV 2 and earns profit ππmm = VV 4. Consumer surplus is CCCC = VV 8. Advertising is a two-stage decision: in the first stage the firm decides how broad a segment of the consumer population to target with its campaign. The targeted segment is the focus of the campaign s messaging that is launched in the second stage. The goal of the campaign is to create among the targeted consumers an identity and sense of belonging to a group of peer consumers. The peer group effect increases the value of buying the good. There is a trade-off in identifying the target market. Being in and a member of the group only works if some are out. Alternatively, the gains in terms of increased willingness to pay from buying the product and belonging to the group diminish as the group becomes less focused or a broader segment. The choice of which segment of the θ distribution to target in stage 1 depends on how the advertising messages resonate with the targeted group in stage 2. Denote the targeted group by 1 θθ, where θθ is the marginal consumer. In stage 2 the firm tries to create through its advertising a peer effect among the targeted consumers 1 θθ that increases each consumer s willingness to pay by αα(θθ ). The peer effect or value of belonging to a group depends on how well defined, or in this context narrow, the group is. Accordingly, we assume that αα θθ is a twice differentiable function and that (θθ ) θθ > 0, 2 αα(θθ ) θθ 2 > 0, and αα(0) = 0.

These assumptions are consistent with the view that the broader or less focused is the targeted consumer population, the less strong is the peer effect that can be created by the advertising. Alternatively, the narrower is the target market, or the higher is θθ, the stronger is the peer effect that can be created from advertising. Moreover, the assumption that 2 αα(θθ ) θθ 2 > 0 implies that the marginal effect is increasing in the narrowness of the target market. This can be interpreted as the keeping up with the Jones dimension of identity and peer effects. Advertising messages, the creativity of their message notwithstanding, are often ignored and do not resonate. There is some uncertainty about whether targeted consumers are in fact reached by a firm s advertising messages. Denote by φ the extent to which a targeted consumer is reached and affected by the advertising and branding of the product. A firm is able to increase the likelihood that its campaign is effective by expending more resources, both on the quality and quantity of different messages. Denote by KK(φφ) the cost incurred by the firm to create with likelihood φφ a peer effect in targeted group, and assume that KK (φφ) > 0 aaaaaa KK"(φφ) > 0. The benchmark or no advertising case is equivalent to setting φφ = 0, and KK(φφ) = 0. In stage 2 the firm designs and implements a campaign with likelihood φφ > 0 that its advertising messages resonate with targeted consumers and creates a Veblen effect. The willingness to pay of consumer i is equal to θθ ii VV + φφφφ θθ, where αα(θθ ) is the value of the peer or Veblen effect created of belonging to the group and θθ ii θθ. The profit-maximizing strategy is to sell the good at a price pp φφ; θθ = θθ VV + φφφφ θθ. The firm chooses in stage 2 φφ to maximize profit: ππ φφ; θθ = vvθθ + φφφφ θθ cc 1 θθ KK(φφ), where c, the unit cost of production is set c = 0. Suppose that KK(φφ) = 1 2 kkφφ2. The

optimal advertising strategy is to φφ θθ = αα θθ 1 θθ kk > 0 for θθ < 1. The optimal reach φφ decreases as the cost of advertising or the parameter k increases. As the target audience becomes narrower, or as θθ increases, the optimal reach φφ increases for αα θθ 1 θθ > αα θθ. Given our assumptions that (θθ ) θθ > 0, 2 αα(θθ ) θθ 2 that the condition αα θθ 1 θθ > αα θθ holds, and φφ (θθ ) θθ > 0, and αα(0) = 0 it is straightforward to show > 0. Firms choose a campaign with greater or more effective reach the more targeted or better defined is the intended consumer audience. The relationship αα θθ > αα θθ 1 θθ implies that the marginal increase in the peer effect from an increase in θθ, (or a decrease in the target audience), is greater than the peer effect averaged over the target population. The optimal advertising strategy leads to a price: pp = θθ VV + αα θθ 2 1 θθ kk. In Figure 1 we illustrate different demand functions that the firm faces for different choices of targeted groups (1 θθ ) and the optimally chosen advertising strategies for that target. Observe that an increase in reach or φφ is associated with higher θθ and an increase in the elasticity of demand. This is true in Becker and Murphy (1993), but what is different here is that the greater elasticity of demand is associated here with less output being sold in a narrower market segment.

Figure 1 In stage 1 the firm chooses its target consumer segment, or equivalently θθ to maximize profit ππ θθ, φφ θθ = θθ VV(1 θθ ) + αα θθ 2 1 θθ 2. The first and second order conditions for profit maximization are: ππ θθ = VV(1 2θθ ) + αα θθ 1 θθ αα θθ 1 θθ αα θθ. (2) kk 2kk ππ θθθθ = 2VV + αα θθ 1 θθ αα θθ 2 kk + αα θθ 1 θθ αα" θθ 1 θθ 2αα θθ kk (3)

The second term in (2) is positive because αα θθ > αα θθ and so if the profit 1 θθ maximizing firm chooses to advertise, or if φφ θθ > 0, then it will choose a segment of the population to serve [1 θθ ] < ½, and hence, restrict output or serve fewer consumers than the benchmark monopolist. It is straightforward to show as well that when [1- θθ ] < ½ or θθ > 1 the price set by the firm is greater than the simple monopoly price, i.e. when 2 θθ > 1, 2 pp θθ = θθ VV + φφ θθ αα θθ > VV. And since when 2 φφ θθ > 0 and advertising is profitable but costly, it follows that consumer expenditure, which in this case is equal to gross revenue, is greater than consumer expenditure under the benchmark monopoly case or pp θθ 1 θθ > VV. 4 It is also easy to show that despite the fact each consumer served derives increased utility from the identification and peer effects created through the firm s advertising, total consumer surplus is lower. The impact of this kind of advertising is to serve fewer consumers at a higher price. This kind of advertising does not reduce consumer surplus because it persuades individuals to buy items they really do not need. Advertising of this type leads to lower consumer surplus because the firm is able to appropriate more of the consumer surplus created from advertising by serving fewer consumers at a higher price than it would if such advertising was not feasible. 3. Conclusion Consumers often value brand names because the brand confers to the consumer a meaning and sense of belonging. We have shown in a simple monopoly model that advertising that creates this kind of brand identity can however leave consumers worse off. The keeping up with the Jones dimension of consumer aspirations and brand

building leads to both higher prices, less output, and lower consumer surplus. As the technology of advertising in the twenty-first century enables both explicit targeting and better identification of consumer subgroups, our result suggests that firms will increasingly use targeted advertising to appropriate more consumer surplus. 4. References Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2005). Identity and the Economics of Organizations. Journal of Economic perspectives, 9-32. Becker, G. S., & Murphy, K. M. (1993). A simple theory of advertising as a good or bad. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 941-964. Clark, C. R., & Horstmann, I. J. (2005). Advertising and coordination in markets with consumption scale effects. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 14(2), 377-401. Pastine, I., & Pastine, T. (2002). Consumption Externalities, Coordination, and Advertising*. International Economic Review, 43(3), 919-943. Wirgenfelt, B. (1990). Advertising Content When Brand Choice is a Signal. Journal of Business, 63 (1), 91-98.