APPLIED MICROECONOMICS Christian Klamler

Similar documents
Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Chapter Fourteen. Topics. Game Theory. An Overview of Game Theory. Static Games. Dynamic Games. Auctions.

Game Theory DR. ÖZGÜR GÜRERK UNIVERSITY OF ERFURT WINTER TERM 2012/13. What can we model as a game?

Chapter 13 Outline. Challenge: Intel and AMD s Advertising Strategies. An Overview of Game Theory. An Overview of Game Theory

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

INSE 6441: Game theory guest lecture Applications of game theory in business, finance and policy

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Game theory (PR 13) Competitive strategies.

Price MCI MSC MEC. q1 Firm output. Industry output

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3

What Is Covered. Econ 2 Final Exam. The Big Concepts. An Outline of Topics Covered In Econ 2

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Econ8500_Game_Theory. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Game theory (PR 13) Module 5 Oct.

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

ECO 5341 Strategic Behavior Lecture Notes 1

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS (EC201)

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Principles of Economics

Part II. Market power

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Exam #2 (100 Points Total) Answer Key

Oligopoly 12/11/2017. Measuring Market Concentration. Oligopoly. Look for the answers to these questions: Concentration ratio

Syllabus. Firms and Markets Professor Paul Scott Office: KMC Course description

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

Intro to Algorithmic Economics, Fall 2013 Lecture 1

Microeconomics (Fall term) Syllabus

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Game Theory III Applications (part 2)

MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS THEORY, APPLICATIONS, AND CASES EIGHTH EDITION. W.Bruce Allen The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania

Econ 302: Microeconomics II - Strategic Behavior. Problem Set #8 July 5, 2016

Econ Microeconomics Notes

PROBLEM SET 3. a) Find the pure strategy Nash Equilibrium of this game.

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Game theory (Sections )

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Microeconomics Sixth Edition

Oligopoly. Economics. Measuring Market Concentration. Oligopoly. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions CHAPTER 17

DEFINITIONS A 42. Benjamin Disraeli. I hate definitions.

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Welfare Economics. The Edgeworth Box. The Basic Theorem. Some Basic Assumptions

Economics 101A (Lecture 27) Stefano DellaVigna

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Game theory. (PR

Brown University ECON 1130, Intermediate Microeconomics (Mathematical) Spring 2017 Class meets Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30 p.m.

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 13 Sections 13.1, 13.2, 13.3 and 13.6 continued

Lecture 11 Imperfect Competition

Midterm Review. B. How should the government intervene? - Often multiple options; to choose, need answer to know effects of policies.

Introduction: Markets and Prices p. 1 Preliminaries p. 3 The Themes of Microeconomics p. 4 What Is a Market? p. 7 Real versus Nominal Prices p.

Economics 101A (Lecture 19) Stefano DellaVigna

Lecture 21: Strategic Interaction and Game Theory

Final Exam cheat sheet

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Harvard University Department of Economics

Midterm Review. B. How should the government intervene? - Often multiple options; to choose, need answer to know effects of policies.

Multiagent Systems: Rational Decision Making and Negotiation

PUBLIC CHOICES, PUBLIC GOODS, AND HEALTHCARE

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Firm Supply. Market demand. Demand curve facing firm

The Need for Information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

An Introduction to Game Theory

Week One What is economics? Chapter 1

The Need for Information

Auction Theory An Intrroduction into Mechanism Design. Dirk Bergemann

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

Microeconomics Exam Notes

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2012

Lecture 21: Strategic Interaction and Game Theory

The Economics of Industry Exam Review. June 14, 2002

University of Victoria Winter Econ 203 Problem Set 3

DO NOT OPEN THIS BOOKLET OR TURN IT OVER [until told to do so]

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

CS 486/686 Lecture 17 2-Player Normal-Form Games 1. Determine dominant-strategy equilibria of a 2-player normal form game.

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 13. Game Theory. Gaming and Strategic Decisions. Noncooperative v. Cooperative Games

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

q S pq S cq S. where q is the total amount produced/consumed. There are two representative firms that maximizes their profits, max pq 1 c 2 q2 1 q 1

Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard

Game Theory Exam, June 2015

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Spontaneous Cooperation under Anarchy

Transcription:

APPLIED MICROECONOMICS Christian Klamler Slides based on: Pindyck R.S. and D.L. Rubinfeld (2009): Microeconomics, 7th edition, Pearson International Edition (and on slides by Companion Webpage, Pearson Education). Osborne, M.J. (2004): An Introduction to Game Theory, Oxford University Press. Gibbons, R. (1992): A Primer in Game Theory, Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York. This work is protected by regional copyright laws and is provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of any part of this work (including on the Internet) will destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. 1

General Information Time and location: see UniGrazOnline for details Course material available on my webpage (access via usual uni-graz login) christian.klamler@uni-graz.at Office hours Mon 13.30 15.00 Grading: 3 exams or short tests 4 April (max 15 points) Thur. 11 May (max 40 points); HS 15.04; 8 am Fr. 23 June (max 45 points); HS 15.13; 1.15 pm in-class participation more than 50 points necessary for positive grade! 2

Content of course Lecture and slides are based on chapters from the following textbooks: Gibbons, R. (1992): A Primer in Game Theory, Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York. Chapters 1 2; Static and dynamic games of complete information Osborne, M.J. (2004): An Introduction to Game Theory, Oxford University Press. Chapters 2 6; Strategic games and extensive games 3 Pindyck R.S. and D.L. Rubinfeld (2003 or younger): Microeconomics, 5th (or higher) edition, Pearson Education. Chapter 13 Game Theory Strategic aspects in decision making Chapter 17 Asymmetric information Incomplete information as market failure Chapter 18 Externalities and Public Goods Market failures and government intervention prerequisite: VU Microeconomics!!

GAME THEORY 4

Introduction 5 What is game theory? Tool to analyse situations in which decision-makers interact. Wide range of applications (not only real games) economics firms competing for business bidders competing in an auction political science law political candidates competing for votes jury members deciding on a verdict biology etc. animals fighting over prey

Introduction Example 6 Firms competing for business each firm controls its own price but not the price of the other firms! each firm cares about all the firms prices, because these prices affect its sales should be considered in its own pricing decision which price should a firm set? Those and similar questions will be discussed in this course!

Introduction Historical aspects 7 Antoine-Augustine Cournot John von Neumann; Oskar Morgenstern John Nash Nobel-Prize 1994: Harsanyi, Nash, Selten Nobel-Prize 2005: Aumann, Schelling Nobel-Prize 2007: Hurwicz, Maskin, Myerson Nobel-Prize 2012: Roth, Shapley

Introduction Basic Concepts 8 Modelling decision-makers (players) Players choose actions/strategies from a set of possible actions what could those actions be? Players have preferences over states of the world complete, consistent (transitive) Theory of rational choice says that the action chosen by a decision-maker is at least as good, according to her preferences, as every other available action. Difference between consumer theory game theory

Introduction Basic Concepts 9 relationship between players cooperative vs. non-cooperative games binding contracts structure of the game simultaneous vs. sequential moves informational aspects common knowledge information or events that all players know, everybody knows that everybody knows them, everybody knows that everybody knows that everybody knows them, etc. complete information each player s payoff function is common knowledge perfect information at each move, the player knows the full history of the game so far

Strategic / Normal Form / Static Games 10

Definitions 11 What is a game? A strategic game (normal form game) consists of a set of players, N for each player i a set of actions, A i ={a i,b i, } for each player, preferences over the set of action profiles e.g. represented by utility function u i (.) important: players move simultaneously!

Example Prisoners Dilemma 12 Story: 2 suspects in a major crime are held in separate cells Enough evidence to convict each of them of a minor offence Not enough evidence to convict both of them of the major offence unless one of them acts as an informer (to fink) They are both independently faced with the following decision problem if neither confesses, both get 2 years if only one confesses he gets 1 year, the other 10 years if both confess, both get 5 years Formal representation N={1,2} A 1 ={fink, quiet}=a 2 u 1 (f,f)=-5; u 1 (f,q)=-1; u 1 (q,f)=-10; u 1 (q,q)=-2 u 2 (f,f)=-5; u 2 (f,q)=-10; u 2 (q,f)=-1; u 2 (q,q)=-2

Payoff matrix Prisoners dilemma 13 N={1,2} A 1 ={fink, quiet}=a 2 u 1 (f,f)=-5; u 1 (f,q)=-1; u 1 (q,f)=-10; u 1 (q,q)=-2 u 2 (f,f)=-5; u 2 (f,q)=-10; u 2 (q,f)=-1; u 2 (q,q)=-2 let us transform this information into a matrix players actions actions payoffs

Prisoners dilemma 14 What will the (rational) suspects do? Dominant Strategy it always leads to a higher payoff, irrespective of what action the other player chooses. what happens if both follow their dominant strategies? Pareto (in)efficiency outcome is Pareto efficient if it is not possible to improve one player s payoff without lowering the other player s payoff Pareto improvement

Dominant strategies formal definitions 15 Notation a = (a 1,,a n ) is a strategy profile, i.e. a strategy a i for each player i. (a i,a -i ) means that all j i choose their strategy according to profile a, while player i chooses strategy a i u i (.) is the utility function of player i, which attaches to each strategy profile the utility that i derives from it. Strategy a i strictly dominates strategy a i, if for all strategy profiles a -i of the other players. Strategy a i is called strictly dominated. Would you ever want to play a strategy that is strictly dominated? Best response function

Iteration 16 A strictly dominated strategy is NEVER a best response no rational belief of a player could ever assume another player to choose a strictly dominated strategy given common knowledge that the players are rational strictly dominated strategy can be eliminated changes the structure of the payoff matrix repeat the process iterated elimination of strictly dominated actions equilibrium in dominant strategies

Exercises 17

Dominant strategies 18 Ex.: Do we have strictly dominant or strictly dominated strategies here? Strategy a i weakly dominates strategy a i, if for all strategy profiles a -i of the other players, and for some strategy profile a -i. Strategy a i is called weakly dominated.

Iteration 19 What about weakly dominated actions? those can be best responses! less appeal solution depends on the order of elimination

Solutions 20 What if there are no dominant strategies? can we explain behaviour or predict outcome? best strategy for any given player depends in general on the other players actions rational players complete information common knowledge In case game theory makes a (unique) prediction about the strategy each player should choose, for this prediction to be correct, the players need to be willing to play the predicted strategy. best response strategically stable self-enforcing

Nash equilibrium 21 John Nash A Nash equilibrium is an action profile a* with the property that no player i can do better by choosing an action different from a i *, given that every other player j adheres to a j *. A Nash equilibrium somehow corresponds to a steady state. There is no individual incentive to choose a different strategy. Hence, it embodies a stable social norm : if everyone else adheres to it, no individual wishes to deviate from it.

Nash equilibrium formal definitions 22 Notation a = (a 1,,a n ) is a strategy profile, i.e. a strategy a i for each player i. (a i,a -i ) means that all j i choose their strategy according to profile a, while player i chooses strategy a i u i (.) is the utility function of player i, which attaches to each strategy profile the utility that i derives from it. The strategy profile a* is a Nash equilibrium if, for every player i and every action a i of player i, a* is at least as good according to player i s preferences as the action profile (a i,a -i *) in which player i chooses a i while every other player j chooses a j *. Equivalently, for every player i, for each strategy a i of player i.

Nash equilibrium and best responses 23 We can also define a Nash equilibrium in terms of best response functions: The strategy profile a* is a Nash equilibrium if and only if every player s strategy is a best response to the other players strategies, i.e. for all players i:

Exercises 24

Nash equilibrium: Prisoners Dilemma 25 many situations structurally similar to PD 2 individuals work on a joint project each of them can work hard (h) or not (n) preferences are assumed as follows based on those preferences, certain payoff functions could lead to the following payoff matrix: similar conclusions as in the PD-game free-rider behaviour other examples: duopoly, common properties, etc.

Exercises 26 Is the structure of the following models different from the one in the PD-game? If so, in what form? Which numbers do you need to insert, such that the payoff matrix becomes structurally equivalent to the one in the PD-game?

Nash equilibrium: Battle of Sexes 27 In the PD-game, main question is whether the players will cooperate. In the following game the players agree that it is better to cooperate than not to cooperate, but they disagree about the best outcome. many structurally similar situations The BoS game: 2 people have to decide on where to go 2 options: concert (C) or football (F) one person prefers C, the other F both prefer going together over going alone

Nash equilibrium: Coordination Game 28 adapt the BoS game by changing the payoff as follows: Nash equilibria? what is the difference to the BoS game focal point Thomas Schelling (1960) Nash s theory says nothing about the actual equilibrium that will occur in case of several Nash equilibria. However, equilibria that are obviously better for everyone, seem to occur more often.

Nash equilibrium: Chicken game 29 the following game makes coordination difficult players can either choose to back down (B) or challenge (C) Nash equilibria? what is the difference to the BoS game compare non-nash outcome (B,B) to Nash-equilibria chicken game has many applications e.g. military conflicts (arms races)

Nash equilibrium: Matching Pennies 30 2 players choose simultaneously whether to show the head or the tail of a coin If they show the same side, P2 pays P1 one Euro. If they show different sides, P1 pays P2 one Euro. What does the payoff matrix look like? As the players interests are diametrically opposed, such a game is strictly competitive and purely conflictual. (zero-sum game) No Nash equilibrium (at least in pure strategies)

Strategic Games - Illustrations STRATEGIC GAMES ILLUSTRATIONS 31

International trade 32 trade theory shows, that trade can be mutually beneficial still governments try to restrict imports by imposing tariffs see USA vs. EU trade conflicts various game theoretic applications possible countries decide between tariffs (T) and no tariffs (N) Nash equilibria?

Cournot s model of oligopoly 33 Model the competition between a small number of sellers (oligopoly) Cournot (1838) modeled the industry as the following strategic game: Players: the firms Actions: each firm s set of possible outputs Preferences: represented by each firm s profit, given in its profit function

Cournot s model duopoly 34 what do the firms think about the situation? for any given action of firm 2, firm 1 s actions yield her various outcomes choose the best action for any of firm 2 s actions

Cournot s model duopoly 35 Best response function or reaction curve can we find an equilibrium?

Cournot s model duopoly 36 How does the Nash equilibrium outcome compare with collusive outcomes firms could agree on size of production would the firms be better off? lower profit for firm 2 lower profit for firm 1 collusion could in general be of benefit to the firms will it occur?

Cournot s model duopoly 37 Numerical example P = 100 Q C 1 (Q 1 ) = 10Q 1 ; C 2 (Q 2 ) = 10Q 2 What does the Nash-Cournot equilibrium look like? What is the collusive outcome? but what problems do occur with this outcome? What happens if we increase the number of firms? keep the assumption of identical linear cost functions of the firms inverse demand function remains P(Q) what is the Nash equilibrium in this case the price in the NE of Cournot s game decreases as the number of firms increases, approaching c

Bertrand s model of oligopoly 38 Firms choose prices and not quantity as in Cournot s model each firm then produces enough to meet the demand it faces, given the prices chosen by all the firms should this not lead to the same results as in Cournot s model? Bertrand s oligopoly game Players: firms Actions: set of possible prices Preferences: represented by the firms profits what would you expect to happen in case of homogeneous outputs consumers buy always at the lower price

Bertrand s model duopoly 39 assume differentiated products the higher priced good does not loose all its demand example: the firms demand functions are assumed to be: Q = 12 2P+ P 1 1 2 Q = 12 2P + P 2 2 1 costs: fixed cost of 20, no variable costs profit function: profit maximizing price to be determined via: best responses

Bertrand s model duopoly 40 TABLE 12.3 Payoff Matrix for Pricing Game Firm 2 Charge $4 Charge $6 Firm 1 Charge $4 $12, $12 $20, $4 Charge $6 $4, $20 $16, $16 What is the Nash equilibrium pair of prices? What is the collusive outcome? Are there individual incentives to stick to an agreement?

Electoral competition 41 Game theory is important to model the foundation for many theories of political phenomena what determines the number of political parties? what determines the policies that political parties propose? how is the outcome of an election affected by the electoral system? Simple model is a strategic game of the following form: Players: candidates Actions: (political) positions (usually numbers on a left-right line) Preferences: payoff relative to voting outcome

Electoral competition 42 Candidates have certain positions on the line Voters have preferences over the positions the closer the candidate is to a voter s ideal position, the more the voter likes this candidate single-peaked preferences In this model, each candidate attracts the votes of all citizens whose favourite positions are closer to her position than to the position of any other candidate.

Electoral competition 43 special position: median position m with the property that half of the voters favourite positions are at most m, and half of them at least m median Which position should a candidate (in case of 2 candidates only) try to occupy? Try to be as close to the median as possible to win the election Hotelling-Downs model of electoral competition tendency to move towards median position

Electoral competition 44 many structurally similar situations competition in product characteristics where should I locate myself to sell drinks on the beach? Beach location game consumers buy drinks from the seller closest to them if the median is in the middle and your competitor is at A, then try to put yourself between median and A eventually both will be at the median clustering at the median examples: supermarkets, car stores, etc.

Auctions 45 In an auction a good is sold to the party who submits the highest bid. used to allocate significant economic resources licenses (radio, mobile phones, ) oil and gas exploration rights government bonds works of art ebay many forms of auctions English auction bids called out sequentially and known to players Dutch auction price lowered until a buyer stops sealed bid auction all bids are private and made simultaneously I don t know the bids of the other players

Auctions 46 Further distinction private value auction each bidder knows own individual valuation valuation might differ between bidders e.g. painting common value auction item has same value to all bidders bidders uncertain about precise value and their estimates differ e.g. oil fields, party games (glass of coins) winner s curse Two pricing options: first-price auction sales price equal to the highest bid second-price auction (Vickrey auction) sales price equal to the second highest bid why should this make sense?

Auctions First-price sealed-bid 47 Model: v i : player i s private value attached to the object assumption: v 1 > v 2 > > v n b i : player i s submitted (sealed) bid p: price, at which the object is finally sold First-price sealed-bid auction bidders do not know the others bids highest bidder wins and pays the price she bids The first-price sealed-bid auction is the following strategic game Players: n 2 bidders Actions: the set of possible bids b i Preferences:

Auctions First-price sealed-bid 48 Nash equilibria in a first-price sealed-bid auction? is telling the truth a Nash equilibrium? (b 1,,b n ) = (v 1, v 2, v 3,, v n ) what if the bids are (v 1 -ε,v 2,,v n )? telling the truth is weakly dominated by other bids many Nash equilibria

Auctions Second-price sealed-bid 49 The second-price sealed-bid auction is the following strategic game Players: n 2 bidders Actions: the set of possible bids b i Preferences: where p is the selling price (i.e. second-highest bid) Nash equilibria in a second-price sealed-bid auction? is telling the truth, i.e. (b 1,, b n ) = (v 1,, v n ), a Nash equilibrium? how many Nash equilibria do you find? could there be a Nash equilibrium in which the player n receives the object? what happens if we think of the bidding events to unfold over time? certain equilibria seem to be unreasonable

Auctions Second-price sealed-bid 50 In a second-price sealed-bid auction a player s bid equal to her valuation weakly dominates all her other bids. i.e. for any bid b i v i, player i s bid v i is at least as good as b i, no matter what the other players bid, and is better than b i for some actions of the other players. Osborne 2005 a second-price auction has many Nash equilibria, but the equilibrium (b 1,,b n ) = (v 1,, v n ) has weakly dominating actions for all players.

Mixed Strategies 51

Introduction 52 Reconsider Matching Pennies Game no Nash equilibrium always incentive to deviate what strategy would you choose? probability distribution maximize expected utility/payoff use preferences over lotteries lottery P with 3 possible outcomes (a,b,c) and probabilities (p a,p b,p c ), and lottery Q with probabilities (q a,q b,q c ) Player i prefers lottery P to Q if player decides according to her expected utility von Neumann Morgenstern preferences Bernoully payoff function

Mixed Strategies Definitions 53 A mixed strategy of a player in a strategic game is a probability distribution over the player s actions. a profile of mixed strategies is usually denoted by α α i (a i ) is the probability that player i attaches to her playing action α i A strategic game (with vnm preferences) consists of a set of players for each player, a set of actions for each player, preferences regarding lotteries over action profiles that may be represented by the expected value of a ( Bernoulli ) payoff function over action profiles.

Matching Pennies q probabilities by P2 1-q 54 probabilities by P1 p 1-p If P1 chooses H with prob. p, and P2 chooses H with prob. q, then P1 will get the following payoff: if q < 0.5, then 4q-2<0 and hence p = 0 is optimal for P1 but then q < 0.5 cannot be optimal for P2 if q > 0.5, then 4q-2>0 and hence p = 1 is optimal for P1 but then q > 0.5 cannot be optimal for P2 only steady state if q = 0.5 and p = 0.5

Matching Pennies best response functions 55 What do the best response functions look like in this game? if q < 0.5, then p = 0 is optimal for P1 if q > 0.5, then p = 1 is optimal for P1 if q = 0.5, then any p [0,1] is optimal for P1 1 B 2 0.5 B 1 q 0 p 0.5 1

Mixed Strategies Equilibrium 56 The mixed strategy profile α* in a strategic game with vnm preferences is a (mixed strategy) Nash equilibrium if, for each player i and every mixed strategy α i of player i, the expected payoff to player i of α* is at least as large as the expected payoff to player i of (α i, α -i *) according to a payoff function whose expected value represents player i s preferences over lotteries. Equivalently, for each player i where U i (α) is a player i s expected payoff to profile α. The mixed strategy profile α* is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if α i * is in B i (α -i *) for every player i.

Mixed strategies BoS game q probabilities by P2 1-q 57 probabilities by P1 p 1-p mixed strategies NE in addition to NE in pure strategies in a BoS game possible? P1 s expected payoff in playing B is: 2q + 0 (1-q) P1 s expected payoff in playing S is: 0 q + 1 (1-q) Hence P1 will play B as long as 2q > (1-q), what is the case for q > 1/3

Mixed strategies BoS game 58 1 B 2 q 1/3 B 1 0 p 2/3 1 3 Nash equilibria, two in pure strategies and one in mixed strategies.

Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium results 59 Is there always a NE in a strategic game? Every strategic game with vnm preferences in which each player has finitely many strategies has a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Can strictly dominated actions be used in a mixed strategy NE? A strictly dominated strategy is not used with positive probability in any mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. What is special in those games?

Exercises 60 Calculate pure- and mixed-strategy NE for the following games?

Extensive Form or Dynamic Games 61

Extensive form games definitions 62 Normal form games suppress the sequential structure of decisionmaking we implicitly assumed that each decision-maker chooses her strategy once and for all Extensive form games describe the sequential structure of decisionmaking explicitly allow for studying situations in which each decision-maker is free to change her mind as events unfold complete and perfect information An extensive form game with perfect information has four components: set of players a set of sequences (terminal histories) a player function that assigns a player to every (non-terminal) sequence for each player, preferences over the set of terminal histories

Example entry game 63 An incumbent (I) faces the possibility of entry by a challenger (C) C as a firm considering entry into an industry occupied by I C as politician competing for leadership of a party with current leader I C as an animal competing with another animal (I) for leadership in group How does the extensive game work? At the start of the game and after any (non-terminal) sequence of events, a player chooses an action in the entry game, C has the options in and out those actions start the game I has the option acquiesce and fight those actions follow a previous move in of C

Example entry game 64 N={I,C} Terminal histories (in, acquiesce) (in, fight) (out) player function P P( ) = C P(in) = I preferences u I (out) = 2; u I (in, acquiesce) = 1; u I (in, fight) = 0 u C (out) = 1; u C (in, acquiesce) = 2; u C (in, fight) = 0

Game tree 65 decisions taken at those points (histories) in C out acq. I fight 1,2 2,1 0,0 The set of all actions available to the player who moves after h is: A(h) = {a: (h,a) is a history} Example: histories are, in, out, (in, acquiesce), (in, fight) available actions at h: A( )={in, out} A(in)={acquiesce, fight}

Solving games in extensive form 66 C Which action would a potential challenger (C) choose in this game? acq. I in fight out 1,2 2,1 0,0 consider questions of credibility backward induction not always well-defined length of terminal histories payoffs at decision nodes

Strategies 67 What is a strategy of player i in an extensive game with perfect information? a function that assigns to each history h after which it is player i s turn to move (i.e. P(h) = i) an action in action set A i (h). 1 C D 2 2 E F G H 2,1 3,0 0,2 1,3 player 1: C, D player 2: EG, EH, FG, FH each strategy is a contingency plan.

Strategies 1 68 C D 2 E F 2,0 G 1 H 3,1 1,2 0,0 what are the strategies for the two players? player 2 has 4 available strategies: which? Attention: A strategy of any player i specifies an action for every history after which it is player i s turn to move, even for histories that, if the strategy is followed, do not occur. e.g. DG und DH in the above example

Outcomes 69 A strategy profile determines the terminal history that occurs Let s be the strategy profile and P the player function Follow the strategies until a terminal history is reached. denote this terminal history of s with O(s) O(s) is a list of actions 1 G 1 E 2 H C F 3,1 D 2,0 Determine O(s) for s = (DG,E)? Determine O(s) for s = (CH,E)? Determine O(s) for s = (CH,F)? Determine O(s) for s = (CG,E)? 1,2 0,0

Nash equilibrium 70 As in normal form games, we are interested in equilibria steady state The strategy profile s* in an extensive game with perfect information is a Nash equilibrium if, for every player i and every strategy r i of player i, the terminal history O(s*) is at least as good according to player i s preferences as the terminal history O(r i,s -i *). Equivalently, for each player i, for every strategy r i of i. How can we find the Nash equilibria in an extensive game? transform extensive form game into normal form game The set of Nash equilibria of any extensive game with perfect information is the set of Nash equilibria of it s strategic (or normal) form.

Normal form vs. extensive form 71 C acq. I in fight 2,1 0,0 out 1,2 player C s strategies are in and out player I s strategies are acquiesce and fight leads to the following corresponding game in normal form: What are the Nash equilibria? How can we interpret them? What can be done?

Subgame 72 The notion of Nash equilibrium ignores the sequential structure of an extensive game treats strategies as choices made once and for all before play begins can lead to Nash equilibria which are not robust The following notion of equilibrium models a robust steady state requires each player s strategy to be optimal, given the other players strategies Subgame not only at the start of the game but also after every possible history For any nonterminal history h, the subgame following h is the part of the game that remains after h has occurred. proper subgame number of subgames is equal to the number of nonterminal histories

Subgames 73 1 G 1 E 2 H C F 3,1 D 2,0 Determine the proper subgames of this game? 1,2 0,0 1,2 G 1 E 2 H 0,0 F 3,1 1,2 G 1 H 0,0

Subgame perfect equilibrium 74 A subgame perfect equilibrium is a strategy profile s* with the property that in no subgame can any player i do better by choosing a strategy different from s i *, given that every other player j adheres to s j *. acq. I in fight 2,1 0,0 C out 1,2 Nash equilibrium (out, fight) is not a subgame perfect equilibrium Strategy fight is not optimal following the history in Nash equilibrium (in, acquiesce) is a subgame perfect equilibrium

Subgame perfect equ. and Nash equ. 75 Every subgame perfect equilibrium is a Nash equilibrium A subgame perfect equilibrium generates a Nash equilibrium in every subgame In a Nash equilibrium every player s strategy is optimal, given the other players strategies, in the whole game but it may not be optimal in some subgames however, it is optimal in any subgame that is reached when the players follow their strategies.

Backward induction 76 In a game with a finite horizon the set of subgame perfect equilibria may be found directly by using backward induction Start by finding the optimal actions of the players who move in the subgames of length one given those actions, we find the optimal actions of the players who move first in the subgames of length two, etc. if in a subgame there are multiple actions that lead to the same payoff for that player, consider all those actions separately. 1 C D 2 2 E F G H 2,1 3,0 0,2 1,3

Backward induction - Exercises 77 G 1 1 C D 2 E F 2,0 1 H I J 1,2 0,0 1,2 3,1 C D 1 E 2 2 2 F G H I J K 3,0 1,0 1,1 2,1 2,2 1,3

Backward induction - Exercise 78 Exercise: 2 players, 21 flags players can sequentially remove 1,2 or 3 flags the player who removes the last flag wins

GAMES WITH PERFECT INFORMATION EXTENSIVE FORM GAMES ILLUSTRATIONS 79

Product Choice Problem 80 What are the NE? Draw the game tree with firm 1 going first what are the subgame perfect NE? change the order of action of the firms

Stackelberg s model of duopoly 81 Stackelberg s duopoly game (compare to Cournot model) one firm goes first, the other reacts based on the other s quantity Assume inverse demand function: and cost functions: if firm 1 goes first, how much would they produce? compare to Cournot equilibrium would you want to go first or second?

Properties of subgame perfect equilibrium 82 First-mover advantage for any cost and inverse demand functions for which firm 2 has a unique best response to each output of firm 1, firm 1 is at least as well off in any SPE of Stackelberg s game as it is in any NE of Cournot s game. what if firm 1 could change its quantity again? and if firm 2 knew this and would change also? where does this lead? value of commitment Osborne 2004

(Empty) Threats and Commitment 83 Incumbent (I) firm announces price war in case potential entrant (C) enters the market Extensive form game looks as follows: C I in out acc fight 0,10 5,5-1,-1 Strategic form game can be written as: Is fight (in case C plays in ) a credible threat? What are Nash equilibria? Are they subgame perfect?

(Empty) Threats and Commitment 84 Can the incumbent make the threat credible? needs to change the payoffs in the game! invest in excess capacity, invest in consumer loyalty this decreases payoffs in case E stays out or enters without fight increases payoffs in case of fight C I in out acc fight 0,10-c 5,5-c -1,-1+d I will fight if 5-c < -1+d if this holds, then (out, fight) is a SPNE

Markets With Asymmetric Information or The Economics of Information 85

Information 86 Until now we assumed complete information often some agents know more than others ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Seller or producer knows more about the quality of a product than the buyer Managers know more about costs, competitive position and investment opportunities than firm owners asymmetric information explains many institutional arrangements in societies guarantees, incentive schemes in contracts, etc.

Quality Uncertainty 87 Example: Market for Lemons two kinds of cars: high quality and low quality sellers and buyers can tell the quality of a car two markets emerge Pearson Int.

Quality Uncertainty what if sellers know more about quality than buyers? buyers will view all cars as medium quality, i.e. think that there is a 50-50 chance that the car is of high quality perception different than expectation eventually high quality cars will be driven out of the market market failure 88 Medium quality cars sell for $7500, selling 25,000 high quality and 75,000 low quality. Pearson Int.

Implications of Asymmetric Information 89 ADVERSE SELECTION is a form of market failure resulting when products of different qualities are sold at a single price because of asymmetric information low quality goods can drive high quality goods out of the market (lemons problem) Hence, too many low and too few high quality goods are sold market fails to produce mutually beneficial trade Applications Market for Insurance insured person knows more about health status than insurance company Market for Credit borrower knows more about his risk attitude than bank many other situations retail stores, dealers of paintings, craftsmen (electricians), restaurants,

Market Signaling 90 what can high-quality seller/agents do? MARKET SIGNALING is the process of one agent using signals to convey information to the other agent about the true state sellers use signals to inform buyers about product s quality use guarantees and warranties cost of warranties to low-quality producers might be too high importance of reputation and standardization low-risk individuals try to inform insurers about their risk status workers try to signal employers their productivity weak vs. strong signal signals may be inaccurate design mechanisms to give incentives to let the agents reveal their true situation separating equilibrium

Market Signaling Example 91 2 types of workers MP 1 = 1; MP 2 = 2 Price of good: 10000 Expected employment time: 10 years AP 1+2 = 1.5 wage 15000 if type was known each type would get its marginal product firm tries to distinguish workers on basis of education y is the number of years educated no other attributes of workers used

Market Signaling Example 92 Education cost functions C 1 (y) = 40000y C 2 (y)= 20000y education does not increase a worker s productivity it is only a value as a signal What kind of equilibrium do you find? Pearson Int.

Moral Hazard other problems from asymmetric information, besides adverse selection, what might happen if you buy a life-insurance? what might happen if you buy an insurance against theft? what might happen if you finally got the job? 93 MORAL HAZARD occurs when a party/agent whose actions are unobserved affects the probability or magnitude of a payment alters the ability of markets to allocate resources efficiently moral hazard not only changes behavior it also creates economic inefficiency

Moral Hazard 94 Example insurance cost of driving a car is $0.50 per mile if observed by insurance company (plus $1 for fuel, taxes, etc.) if miles not observed, any additional mile does not incur the $0.50 cost but only the $1 cost for fuel, taxes, etc. will increase the quantity above efficient level Pearson Int.

The Principal-Agent Problem 95 Asymmetric information often applies to situations were one person (principal) hires another person (agent) to make economic decisions. Agency relationship exists whenever there is an arrangement in which one person s welfare depends on what another person does. Principals cannot monitor the productivity of agents perfectly PRINCIPAL-AGENT-PROBLEM agents pursue their own goals, rather than the goals of the principal owners hiring managers patients hiring doctors to decide on treatment investors hiring financial advisors car owner/buyer hiring mechanic Problem of diverging incentives Principal needs mechanism to provide incentive for agent to work in principal s interest e.g. reward structure based on long-term performance

The Principal-Agent Problem 96 Example managing a firm out of the principal s vs. the agent s view Nicholson

The Principal-Agent Problem How can owners design reward systems so that managers and workers come as close as possible to meeting the owners goals? Example: manager can use low effort (a=0) or high effort (a=1) firm s profit also depends on luck, however firm has incomplete information 97 low effort (a=0) high effort (a=1) bad luck good luck 10,000 20,000 20,000 40,000 manager s cost function is c=10,000a and she wants to maximize wage owner s goal is to maximize expected profit, given uncertainty and inability to monitor the manager what is the optimal payment scheme?

Asymmetric Information in Labor Markets 98 Competitive labor market would not allow for unemployment why do still most countries experience unemployment? efficiency wage theory can explain presence of unemployment and wage discrimination labor productivity depends on the wage rate nutritional reasons in developing countries In developed countries use shirking model perfectly competitive market - workers can work or shirk monitoring workers is costly or impossibility imperfect information what if shirkers are detected? wage at market clearing rate gives incentive to shirk - firm pays more to make loss from shirking higher wage at which no shirking occurs is the efficiency wage but what if all firms pay efficiency wages? is there again an incentive to shirk?

Asymmetric Information in Labor Markets Unemployment can arise in otherwise competitive labor markets when employers cannot accurately monitor workers. no shirking constraint (NSC) gives the wage necessary to keep workers from shirking. What is the optimal payment scheme? The firm hires L e workers (at a higher than competitive efficiency wage w e ), creating L* L e of unemployment. 99 Pearson Int.

Asymmetric Information in Labor Markets 100 One of the early examples of the payment of efficiency wages can be found in the history of Ford Motor Company. Ford needed to maintain a stable workforce, and Henry Ford (and his business partner James Couzens) provided it. In 1914, when the going wage for a day s work in industry averaged between $2 and $3, Ford introduced a pay policy of $5 a day. The policy was prompted by improved labor efficiency, not generosity. Although Henry Ford was attacked for it, his policy succeeded. His workforce did become more stable, and the publicity helped Ford s sales.

Externalities and Public Goods 101

Externalities 102 You are having a party and your neighbor is upset because of the loud music. What happens here? You are imposing an EXTERNALITY on your neighbor the effects of production and consumption activities not directly reflected in the market Negative externalities an action by one party imposes a cost on another party pollution of river by firm upstream affects firms downstream noise of airplanes affects citizens negative effect not taken into account by pollutant Positive externalities someone s beautiful garden from which all can benefit (by looking at it) What if I buy some bread and this raises the price of bread for you? pecuniary externalities

Negative Externalities and Inefficiency 103 Externalities create an external cost not represented in the firm s cost structure marginal external cost (MEC) Marginal social cost (MSC) = MC + MEC Pearson Int.

Positive Externalities 104 Pearson Int.

Externalities 105 Mathematical Model of a production externality firm 1 produces output q selling it in a competitive market production of q imposes a cost e(q) on firm 2 equilibrium output q 1 is given by P = c (q 1 ). firm 1 takes only private costs into account but not social costs what is the efficient amount of output? merge the two firms to internalize the externality leads to a FOC in which price equals marginal social cost

Correcting Market Failure 106 What can the state do to correct market failure? Model assumptions: Negative externality, pollution by firm output and emission decisions are independent no link between quantity of emissions and quantity of output marginal external cost (MEC) of emissions is upward sloping substantially increasing harm as pollution increases marginal cost of abating emissions (MCA) is downward sloping if emissions are high, there is little cost to controlling them, but large reductions require costly changes in production process

Correcting Market Failure 107 Pearson Int.

Correcting Market Failure Three ways to make firms reduce emissions to an efficient level Emission standards legal limit on quantity of emissions Emission fees charge levied on each unit of emissions Transferable emission permits permits to be traded on a market 108 Pearson Int.

Correcting Market Failure 109 What is better? Standard or Fees? Assumptions policymakers have asymmetric information same fee or standard required for all firms Pearson Int.

Correcting Market Failure 110 7 optimal fee is $8 now incomplete information what if 12,5% failure on standard (standard of 9)? what if 12,5% failure on fee (fee of $7)? advantage of standards when MSC is steep and MCA flat and limited information about efficient fee and efficient standard 9 Pearson Int.

Correcting Market Failure 111 Transferable Emissions Permits policymaker determines the level of emissions and number of permits permits are traded in a market help develop a competitive market for externalities firms with high abatement costs will purchase permits from firms with low abatement costs combines both, standards and fees allows pollution abatement to be achieved at minimum cost Examples Australian carbon trading scheme Kyoto protocol

Emissions Trading - Example 112 Limiting Sulfur Dioxide emissions since 1990s Expected permit price: $300 but initially much lower because less costly to reduce emissions (cheaper mining of low sulfur coal). Sharp increase in 2005 as low sulfur coal price increased and more power plants were built leading to more permit demand Price of Tradeable Emissions Permits Pearson Int.

Recycling What is the efficient amount of recycling? households decide on whether to simply dispose certain waste (e.g. glass) or put it into a recycling container simple disposal usually has low cost to households (MC) and seems to be constant with the amount of waste social costs of disposal (MSC) are much larger and increase with the amount of waste marginal costs of recycling (MCR) are increasing with the amount that needs to be reduced (right-left) as collection, separation and cleaning costs grow at increasing rate 113 Pearson Int.

Recycling 114 What is the efficient amount of recycling? where MSC intersects MCR What is the market outcome? where MC intersects MCR hence the amount m 1 is not socially optimal How could we get to the social optimum? increase the private costs so that MC intersects MCR at the socially optimal amount refundable deposits Pearson Int.

Stock externalities 115 so far externalities from flows of harmful pollution sometimes damage not from emissions flow, but from the accumulated stock of the pollutant. e.g. global warming, seen to result from the accumulation of greenhouse gases (GHG) in the atmosphere does not cause severe immediate harm rather the stock of accumulated GHG ultimately causes harm stock will remain high even if current emission were reduced to zero also positive stock externalities possible e.g. the stock of knowledge resulting from investments in R&D need to compare the present discounted value (PDV) of additional profits resulting from any investment to the cost of the investment i.e. need to calculate the net present value (NPV) cost-benefit analysis helps to decide whether an investment is economically justified

Stock externalities How does a stock built up? stock of pollutant, S present years emissions, E fraction of stock that dissipates, δ first year s stock is first year s emissions 116 in second year, stock equals that year s emissions plus nondissipated stock from the first year in any year t for emissions at constant rate E, after N years the stock will be for N going to infinity, the stock approaches a long-run equilibrium

Stock externalities - Example 117 100 units of pollutant emitted each year, i.e. E i = 100 rate of stock dissipates by 2 percent per year, i.e. δ = 0.02 stock originally zero, i.e. S 0 = 0 stock creates damage (health costs, etc.) equal to 1 mill. per unit annual cost of reducing emissions to zero is 15 mill. per unit Pearson Int.

Stock externalities - Example Does a policy of zero emission make (economic) sense? need to calculate the NPV (assuming social rate of discount R) costs and benefits of a policy apply to society as a whole use opportunity cost to society of receiving an economic benefit in the future rather than today little agreement on how to use it and its size 118 NPV depends on discount rate, R, and dissipation rate, δ numbers for different combinations in the following table: Pearson Int.

Global warming Atmospheric concentration of GHG dramatically increased over the past century even if current GHG emissions are stabilized, atmospheric concentration continues to increase reduction of current GHG emissions increases costs today with benefits in some 50 years or more economic predictions heavily depending on social rate of discount 119 Pearson Int.

Externalities and Property Rights 120 active government regulation not only way to deal with externalities alternative approach: PROPERTY RIGHTS legal rules stating what people or firms may do with their property Example: fishermen owning the river fisherman can demand compensation from firm upstream polluting the river hence there is a cost to the firm upstream from polluting the river in form of this compensation costs are internalized via bargaining economic efficiency can be achieved without government intervention COASE THEOREM if property rights are well specified and parties can bargain without cost and to their mutual advantage, the resulting outcome will be efficient, regardless of how the property rights are specified is bargaining really without cost and are property rights clearly specified?

Externalities and Property Rights 121 what do you think will happen if firm has property right? if fishermen have property right? would they want to stick at those levels? where do we find the socially efficient level of emissions? Pearson Int.

Common Property Resources 122 Sometimes externalities occur if resources can be used without payment COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCE a resource to which anyone has free access air/water/land/fish/animal population/minerals/etc. inefficiencies might occur prisoners dilemma Private cost of fishermen understates the true cost to the society fishermen fish until marginal private benefit is equal to marginal private cost no fisherman takes into account how its own fishing affects others expectation of catching fish too many fish will be caught

Common Property Resources 123 what is the private optimum? what is the social optimum? Pearson Int. Possible solution to install private (or government) ownership owner sets fee for use of resource equal to the MC of depleting the stock

Public Goods 124 are there any reasons for government replacing private firms as producers? PUBLIC GOODS Nonexclusive Nonrival people cannot be excluded from its consumption difficult or impossible to charge for its use marginal cost of its provision to an additional consumer is zero beware of congestion pure public goods provide benefits to people at zero marginal cost and no one can be excluded from enjoying them. in contrast, a private good can be excluded and is rival!

Public Goods 125 exclusive Yes No Yes rival No where is the efficient level of provision of a private good? marginal benefit for a consumer = marginal cost of production where is the efficient level of provision of a public good? marginal benefit for all consumers = marginal cost of production Samuelson condition

Public Goods 126 how much would they consume if this was a private good? what is the socially optimal level of provision? why does it seem difficult to privately provide a public good? Pearson Int.

Public Goods Private provision of public goods difficult free-riding free-rider is someone who does not pay for a nonexclusive good in the expectation that others will incentive problem would you communicate your true benefit? government will take over the production of a public good and set taxes and/or fees accordingly determining how much of a public good to provide when free-riding is possible is difficult voting mechanism design 127

Private preferences for public goods efficient level of education determined by summing the willingness to pay of the different individuals (net of tax payments) leads to an aggregate willingness to pay curve (AW) hence the efficient outcome is where AW is maximized, i.e. at a spending of $1200 is this also the voting outcome? recall median voter theorem 128 Pearson Int.