FISHERIES AND AQUACULTURE Vol. I - Rational Exploitation and Conservation of Marine Ecosystems - Jean-Paul Troadec

Similar documents
The Economics of Sustainable Aquaculture

1 Objectives of the project

Revised mapping of the CITES Strategic Vision: objectives and the Aichi Targets in the Strategic Plan for Biodiversity

Response from the Institute of Fisheries Management to the Government s A Green Future: Our 25 Year Plan to Improve the Environment

Fisheries and Aquaculture in a Changing Climate

Managing Natural Resources

By Papa Gora NDIAYE 1, Fisheries Economist Geneva, March 22 nd 2017

Sustainability, Fisheries and Aquaculture

Ifremer. French Research Institute for the Exploitation of the Sea

EU request on criteria for CITES non-detriment finding for European eel (Anguilla anguilla)

JICA s Position Paper on SDGs: Goal 14. Goal 14: Conserve and sustainably use the oceans, seas and marine resources for sustainable development

B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia

Fisheries, Aquaculture & Algae Biomass Assessment

Key conservation policies and their targets

Sustainable Development of Mediterranean Aquaculture

Challenges for Sustainable Global Fisheries. Kieran Kelleher Senior Fisheries Specialist The World Bank

Aquaculture Evaluation

An Introduction to the Concept and Application of Marine Protected Areas. Michael J. Fogarty 1

UNCTAD Oceans Forum. Michele Ameri, Legal Officer 21 March 2017

16 Biological Resources

"Aquaculture in the Bioeconomy framework - Nordic developments. Gilli Trónd, Project Manager, Danish Technological Institute

ENGLISH SUMMARY. Chapter I: Regulation of the Agricultural Emissions of Nitrogen to Coastal Waters

14/12/2010 MISTRALS

Need & Opportunities for more integrated farming practices in coastal and offshore aquaculture. Patrick Sorgeloos Ghent University, Belgium

Resolution XI.3. Adjustments to the Strategic Plan for the triennium

Aboriginal Aquaculture in Canada Initiative. September 27, 2018 Saskatoon, Saskatchewan

Open Working Group, February 2014: Australia, the Netherlands, United Kingdom Constituency Statement. Oceans and Seas, Forests and Biodiversity

Life Cycle Assessment (LCA) of aquatic products

Changing the Face of the Waters Meeting the promise and challenge of sustainable aquaculture

Effluents from land based marine farms: nature, treatment, valorisation, modelisation. Applications to fish and shrimp rearing

FISHERY COMMITTEE FOR THE EASTERN CENTRAL ATLANTIC Scientific Sub-Committee

Over the past decades, global markets for fish and fish products have changed

Aquaculture for Poverty Alleviation and Food Security. Slide 2: World annual average per capita consumption of fish and fishery products

Capacity Analysis and Fisheries Policy: Theory versus Practice

EU CFP reform: Towards Sustainable EU-ACP Fisheries relations

Sachiko TSUJI (FIPS, FAO) WS on Environmental Statistics

Theme 12: Aquaculture

CONVENTION ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN ENDANGERED SPECIES OF WILD FAUNA AND FLORA

MINIMIZING DISPARITIES BY CHANGING PUBLIC ATTITUDES AND PERCEPTIONS, AND BY IMPROVING EDUCATION AND PUBLIC AWARENESS

Commercial Shellfish Aquaculture in the Inland Bays

Sustainable Aquaculture

OPERATIONAL GUIDLINES OF BOAD

ENVIRONMENT AND DEVELOPMENT-Vol.II- Capacity For Developing Innovative Production Technologies - Ying Chen

ICHIRO NOMURA ASSISTANT DIRECTOR-GENERAL FISHERIES DEPARTMENT FAO, ROME

ECONOMICS OF SHRIMP FARMING

Selva Shrimp A Sustainable Aquaculture Program by Blueyou Consulting. Selva. Shrimp. The Sustainable. Shrimp. Premium Black Tiger Prawns. Choice!

SUSTAINABILITY AND RESILIENCE IN NATURAL RESOURCE SYSTEMS: POLICY DIRECTIONS AND MANAGEMENT INSTITUTIONS

Presented by Jacob Ainoo-Ansah

Chapter 8 Natural Resources

Market Access and Fish and Seafood Sustainability: A Fisheries and Oceans Canada Perspective

The role of green economy in sustainable development

Trapping in special enclosures to create a more fertile growing environment an operation used in southeast Asia with milk fish and shrimp

CNL(10)51. NASCO Guidelines for the Protection, Restoration and Enhancement of Atlantic salmon Habitat

NOAA AQUACULTURE PROGRAM

GLOBAL AQUACULTURE GROWTH THROUGH TECHNOLOGICAL DEVELOPMENT. Dr. Arne Fredheim Research Director SINTEF Ocean Adjunct Professor NTNU/AMOS

Implications of Mexico s Rural Development Strategy for aquaculture and wild fisheries. Claudia Stella Beltrán T.

Vulnerability in Inland Fishing Communities in Africa: lessons learned

AQUACULTURE SUMMARY. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture Report FAO 2016

Fisheries and Aquaculture Department

THE CURRENT CLIMATE FOR A SUSTAINABLE BLUE ECONOMY

Science and Technology Advantages: An important mean for Blue Aquaculture Development in Vietnam

Addressing Fisheries Subsidies: A Quest for Sustainable Fisheries Production

INTEGRATED SOLID WASTE MANAGEMENT TOWARDS GREEN ECONOMY IN VIETNAM

Fish Conservation and Management

WCS Recommendations for The Ocean Conference

Models for the assessment of sustainability and risk in fish and shellfish aquaculture

OBLIGATIONS TO PROTECT MARINE ECOSYSTEMS UNDER INTERNATIONAL CONVENTIONS AND OTHER LEGAL INSTRUMENTS

Chapter 8. Oceans and Fisheries 4/20/2009. Chapter 8: Outline. Canada s Arctic Ocean. Physical. Socioeconomics. Towards Sustainable Ocean Environments

AQUACULTURE INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITIES IN SE ASIA SUSTAINABLE GROUPER FARMING IN THE PHILIPPINES

Climate change vulnerability, fisheries and aquaculture:

End poverty in all its forms everywhere

The Science of Climate Change and Fisheries

Future Growth of the U.S. Aquaculture Industry and Associated Environmental Quality Issues

TURBOT AQUACULTURE: PRODUCTION AND MARKETS by Trond Bjørndal and José Fernández-Polanco

Counter Measures in Fisheries & Aquaculture Climate Change. Jackie Alder UNEP

Sustainable Aquaculture and Food Security

The 15 Oceanography Symposium

A BLUEPRINT FOR GEORGIA OYSTER AQUACULTURE

HIGHLIGHTS ON RESEARCH ACTIVITIES AT KMFRI BY DR. ENOCK WAKWABI, DEPUTY DIRECTOR, KMFRI INLAND WATERS RESEARCH DIVISION, KMFRI HEADQUARTERS, MOMBASA.

MITIGATING MARINE EUTROPHICATION IN THE PRESENCE OF STRONG SOCIETAL DRIVING FORCES

Recommended Strategies and Actions to Address Ocean Acidification

RIVER SEDIMENTS AND COASTAL FISH PRODUCTION: WHAT ABOUT THE MEKONG?

Adoption of guidelines on small-scale fisheries

PROFe JUDI -w'an6alw'a w'akhun6u, 6H

A Partnership for Saving West Africa s Coastal Assets

Marine & Coastal Management. Presentation to Portfolio Committee DAFF

Overview of Presentation

Sustainable resource management

NOUAKCHOTT DECLARATION ON THE FISHERIES TRANSPARENCY INITIATIVE (FiTI)

ICRI Scorecard. Presented by Marea E. Hatziolos The World Bank

14 Organizations Promoting Sustainable Fishing Practices

Issues associated with wetland biodiversity and. agriculture globally. and the extent of agriculture in Ramsar wetlands.

Definition of Sustainability

Advice July 2014

School of Fisheries, Aquaculture and Aquatic Sciences

A STUDY ON CATFISH CULTURE AT VARIOUS LOCATIONS IN ANAMBRA STATE, NIGERIA

AACL BIOFLUX Aquaculture, Aquarium, Conservation & Legislation International Journal of the Bioflux Society

THE EXPERIENCE AND DEVELOPMENT OF RESPONSIBLE AND ECO-FRIENDLY AQUACULTURE PRODUCTION PRACTICES FOR FOOD SAFETY AND TRACEABILITY IN TAIWAN

Conserve and sustainably use the oceans, seas and marine resources for sustainable development

BSc (Hons) Aquaculture (Full-Time) (with 6-month Internship) - A337

Transcription:

RATIONAL EXPLOITATION AND CONSERVATION OF MARINE ECOSYSTEMS Jean-Paul Troadec Menez Perroz, Plouguerneau, France Keywords: rational exploitation, conservation, marine ecosystem, natural resources, wealth distribution Contents 1. Introduction 2. The Exploitation and Conservation of Natural Resources 2.1. Technological Intensification and Production Systems 2.2. Relationships between Production Systems and Ecosystems 2.2.1 Direct Impacts 2.2.2 Indirect Impacts 2.2.3 Exogenous Pollution 2.3. Adjustment of Production Systems to Ecosystem Capacity 3. Rationalization of Uses 3.1. The Dynamics of Overfishing 3.2. Management Objectives 3.3. Biological and Economic Conditions of Sustainable Development 4. Effects on Wealth Distribution 5. Conclusions Glossary Bibliography Biographical Sketch Summary The introduction to this article recalls the state of fisheries at the beginning of the new millennium. The massive overcapacities, severe and pervasive resource depletion, and recurrent conflicts which characterize the exploitation of renewable resources these can be traced back to the deficiencies of classic governance institutions used for regulating access. The second section reviews the changes in the relationships between production systems and natural ecosystems that take place in the process of technological intensification. Fisheries are taken as a model to illustrate how rationalization and resource conservation, together with conflict minimization, all depend on the application of technical measures to maintain the productive, reproductive and assimilative capacities of fish stocks and ecosystems, as well as on the adjustment of use capacities to the limited capacities of natural resources. The third section examines how, by acting upon the economic forces causing overcapacities, the extraction of resource scarcity rents can minimize their effects. These rents can also provide revenues for financing the regulation of uses. However, if the objectives of economic efficiency and resource conservation are fully compatible, the short-term reduction of employment implied by the initial reduction of use capacities remains the major obstacle to institutional reforms. The fourth section investigates the effects on

wealth distribution of various regulation instruments. If the choice of resource property regimes and mechanisms of use rights allocation has important distributive effects, the allocation of exclusive rights reduces the uncertainty and risk affecting fishing activities and other uses under current access conditions. Finally, the conclusion points out that use rationalization and resource conservation are directly conditioned to the adoption of suitable institutions for limiting access. Such adjustment is equally important for the development of new activities aquaculture in particular. Some of the factors that facilitate or impede the emergence of institutions that are adapted to the new conditions of resource scarcity are identified. 1. Introduction The survey of world fisheries in the chapter Harvesting the seas (Sections State of World Resources and The Dynamics of Overfishing) gives evidence of the pervasive extension of overcapacities and resource depletion. Most fisheries currently manifest problems of economic inefficiency. These problems are summarized below: physical yields, and even more, the unit economic value of landings, decline while stock variability is amplified, fisheries are economically inefficient fish stocks are losing their economic value, fleet and use conflicts are recurrent, technical measures aiming at preserving stock productivity are more difficult to enforce, and scientific knowledge and information on fish stocks and fisheries are underutilized. These types of problems are not restricted to fisheries. When expansion opportunities are exhausted, all uses of natural resources are subject to similar unbalances. In semiclosed basins, shellfish farming is affected by overstocking resulting in longer growing cycles and higher mortalities which curtail the profit of farming activities. In intensive farming systems, organic matter, pharmaceuticals and chemicals that are released, as well as fish escapes, have to be adjusted to the assimilative capacity of ecosystems. In coastal areas, cultivated water bodies have to be preserved against pollution from industries, agriculture and urban centers. The underlying causes of overexploitation are economic. However, the adjustment of use capacities to the productive, reproductive and assimilative capacities of ecosystems rests in the governance institutions that are currently used for regulating access. The regulatory systems designed by self-governing customary communities, or at a higher level, by central administrations during the expanding phase of fisheries, were primarily intended to preserve the productivity of fish stocks rather than to adjust fishing capacities to their productivity (see Harvesting the seas, sub-section Regulatory Systems). It is, therefore, understandable why regulation of access to fisheries to date has been ineffective. The adjustment of institutions to the new conditions of resource scarcity has already started. The adoption of the new Law of the Sea has been the first step. The new Ocean

Regime gives coastal States the necessary authority to revise legislation regarding use rationalization and resource conservation within their EEZs. Most countries have already adopted legislation for controlling the fishing activities of foreign fleets. Few, however, have done so for the limitation of fishing capacities in their own fleets. The regulation of access has no standard solution. The natural characteristics of renewable resources and notably the mobility of fish stocks and the fluidity of ecosystems the technical features of fishing and farming systems, and the socioeconomic organization of user groups, impose particular constraints that require specific arrangements. In addition, the emergence of new institutional schemes depends on the conditions prevailing in each country and on the decisions taken by national authorities. 2. The Exploitation and Conservation of Natural Resources 2.1. Technological Intensification and Production Systems With technological intensification, physical controls are extended over new physiological functions of selected species and certain components of their environment. Domestication proceeds step by step, each step characterized by a specific production function, or assimilation function with respect to pollution (see Harvesting the seas, sub-section Fishing or Production Systems). The relationships between production systems and ecosystems can be analyzed on the basis of their level of technological intensification. For this purpose, six sets of fishing and farming systems can be distinguished. These are: Fishing, in which the surplus production of wild populations is harvested. Attraction-retention of fish concentrations: in such systems, man interferes, primarily with the distribution, and accessorily with the growth, of concentrations of wild stocks, by closing their migratory routes (valiculture), by providing shelters (artificial reefs), or by enhancing forage production through simple cultural practices (such as acadjas in Benin). Investigations on the reproductive strategies of aquatic populations indicate that their abundance is determined primarily by the success of their recruitment, i.e. by the number of fishes which survive at the end of the early stages (eggs, larvae and fry) and which compensate for population losses by natural and fishing mortalities. The level of recruitment depends primarily on the hydrodynamic conditions prevailing during the early stages, and secondarily on the biomass of the parental stock. Population abundance and production are much less influenced by the environmental conditions prevailing during the exploited phase of year classes. Thus, from a domestication viewpoint, attraction-retention systems differ from fishing essentially by the limited effects of simple cultural practices on the growth of fish concentrations. If local yields can be enhanced significantly, it is probably more by the attraction and retention of fish concentrations, than by a direct effect on the recruitment of populations. Extensive farming systems: in these systems, man exerts certain controls on the reproduction of cultivated stocks, either indirectly by providing artificial substratum for the settlement of larvae (e.g. by catching and stocking natural

spat in shellfish culture), or directly by releasing in the open sea fry that is raised in hatcheries (ranching). Semi-intensive farming systems: in addition to controls on reproduction, man can stimulate forage production by fertilizing the environment in which the stock grows (e.g. fish culture in ponds, lagoons or small lakes). Intensive farming systems: in addition to controls on reproduction, cultivated stocks are artificially fed (e.g. fish culture in ponds, pens and raceways). Fully-controlled farming systems: by recycling the waste products of cultivation, these systems become autonomous from the environment examples include the culture of African cat fish (Clarias gariepinus) in the Netherlands, the culture of tilapias in heated waters in Belgium, or pond culture in which water is recycled in Israel. 2.2. Relationships between Production Systems and Ecosystems The relationships between fishing/farming systems and ecosystems include direct and indirect impacts of the former on the latter, as well as exogenous pollution which can modify the quality and carrying capacity of ecosystems. 2.2.1 Direct Impacts Fishing and attraction/retention systems rest on the exploitation of wild populations. Most of them occupy a high level in the food web. Stock productivity can be preserved, first by preventing the premature capture of juvenile fishes, and second, by maintaining the spawning stock above a level below which recruitment may be reduced. All other farming systems include some control of reproduction. In addition, in all those that have reached the stage of commercial production (extensive culture of sedentary species such as seaweeds and shellfishes, and semiintensive and intensive systems), the cultivated stocks are collectively or individually owned. With domestication and appropriation, cultivated stocks lose their status of natural resources. They can be assimilated as capital assets, in a similar way to fishing boats or farming infrastructures. In semi-intensive and intensive systems, the constraint resulting from the limited trophic capacity of ecosystems is relaxed by the enhancement of forage production, or removed by the supply of artificial feeds.

- - - Figure 1. Annual production and stock biomass in the basin of Marennes-Oléron (France): Portuguese oyster ( ), Japanese oyster ( ), and Japanese oyster in Portuguese oyster assimilation equivalent (*). Source: Héral et al, 1986. Bibliography TO ACCESS ALL THE 18 PAGES OF THIS CHAPTER, Visit: http://www.eolss.net/eolss-sampleallchapter.aspx De Alessi M. (1998). Fishing for Solutions. IEA Studies on the Environment 11, 88 pp. [This paper discusses the consequences of the inadequate management regimes in fisheries, and the opportunities attached to the development of property rights systems.] Hanna S.S., Folke C. and Mäler K.G. (1996). Rights to Nature. Ecological, Economic, Cultural, and Political Principles of Institutions for the Environment, 298 pp. Stockholm: Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. [This book addresses the full range of ecological, economic, cultural and political factors affecting the regulation of natural resource uses. It provides valuable insight into the role of property-rights regimes in establishing societies that are equitable, efficient and sustainable.] Hannesson R. (1993). Bioeconomic analysis of fisheries, 138 pp. Oxford: Fishing News Books. [This book presents bioeconomic models which have been developed by grafting technological and economic variables and relations on the models of population dynamics developed by biologists.]

Héral M., Bacher C. and Deslous-Paoli J-M. (1989). La capacité biotique des bassins conchylicoles. in Troadec J.-P. (ed.) (1989) L homme et les ressources halieutiques. Essai sur l usage d une ressource commune renouvelable, op. cit., 225-259. [This article analyzes the constraints on shellfish culture systems resulting from the limited trophic capacity of cultivated ecosystems.] Kooiman J., Van Vliet M. and Jentoft S. (eds.) (1999). Creative Governance. Opportunities for Fisheries in Europe, 287 pp. Aldershot (UK): Ashgate Publ. Ltd. [Taking European fisheries as a model of the complex biological and social systems of natural resource uses, this book analyzes, in an interdisciplinary approach, the implications of this complexity on the conservation of natural resources, the regulation of their uses, and the livelihoods and way of life of fisher groups. It attempts to broaden prevailing concepts of management to governance and to the creation of new opportunities.] North D.C. and Thomas R.P. (1973). The Rise of the Western World. A new Economic History, 171 pp. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [This book shows how the structure of property rights which developed in the Netherlands and England provided the incentives necessary for sustained growth and the inducements required to encourage innovation and the consequent industrialization in Western Europe.] OCDE (1997). Towards Sustainable Fisheries. Economic Aspects of the Management of Living Marine Resources, 268 pp. Paris: OCDE. [This report analyses the outcomes associated with the use of alternative management regimes in over 100 fisheries in the OECD countries, and provides a comprehensive assessment of their economic performances.] Plattner S., ed. (1989). Economic anthropology, 487 pp. Stanford Univ. Press, Stanford, California. [This book covers the traditional topics of economic behavior and institutions in foraging bands, horticultural tribes, pre-capitalist states, agrarian and peasant societies and industrialized states, as well as other issues, notably common-property resources, the central place of the theory of markets and market places and the fundamentals of economic behavior in markets. ] Rey H., Catanzano J., Mesnil B. and Biais G. (1997). Système halieutique. Un regard différent sur les pêches, 287 pp. Paris: Coll. Propos, Institut Océanographique/IFREMER. [This essay explores the multidimensional nature of fisheries, and the application of the multidisciplinary approach for investigating complex issues of fishery development and management.] Troadec J.-P., ed. (1989) L homme et les ressources halieutiques. Essai sur l usage d une ressource commune renouvelable, 817 pp. Paris: IFREMER. [This book reviews the issues that are affecting fisheries and extensive aquaculture systems, e.g. the natural variability of fish populations and the determinism of their recruitment, the adjustment of shellfish production to the carrying capacity of shellfish basins, the regulation of access and the allocation of fishing rights in fisheries, etc.] Biographical Sketch Jean-Paul Troadec was involved in the 1960s in surveys and assessments of fishery resources conducted by the French Institute of Research for Development (IRD) in the Gulf of Guinea. He then joined the FAO Department of Fisheries, where he participated in the Department s programs in the fields of fishery statistics, stock assessment, and fisheries management, before being in charge of the Fisheries Development Planning Service. In FAO, his work focused on the conditions of fishery development in developing countries, and on the change in fishery management approaches resulting from the full exploitation of world resources. In the 1980s, he became Director of the French Scientific and Technological Institute of Maritime Fisheries (ISTPM), and then Director for Living Resources in the French Research Institute for the Exploitation of the Sea (IFREMER). His research interests concern the changes of marine production systems including the uses and conservation of marine environments, the institutional aspects of their management, and the related changes in research priorities resulting from the full exploitation of fishery resources. He has presented a Ph.D thesis on the biology and population dynamics of West African croakers at the University of Marseilles (France), and edited a book on fisheries management.