Commodity Program Reform and the Structure of U.S. Agriculture

Similar documents
The state of the farm economy: Some big-picture considerations. Patrick Westhoff

Structural Changes in the Agricultural Economy

Oral Statement before the United States Senate Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition, and Forestry. Hearing on the trade section of the farm bill

Baseline Update for U.S. Farm Income and Government Outlays

CORN: WILL ACREAGE REBOUND IN 2002

Outlook for the 2014 U.S. Farm Economy. Kevin Patrick Farm Economy Branch Resource and Rural Economics Division

U.S. Dairy Products, Cash Receipts

CRS Report for Congress

FAPRI-UMC Report December 8, 2005

Farm Commodity Policy: Programs and Issues for Congress

October 20, 1998 Ames, Iowa Econ. Info U.S., WORLD CROP ESTIMATES TIGHTEN SOYBEAN SUPPLY- DEMAND:

SOYBEANS: LOW PRICES TO PERSIST

Ending stocks can adjust due to a variety of factors from changes in production as well as adjustments to beginning stocks and demand.

Future Challenges in Agricultural Export Marketing

U.S. Agricultural Policy and WTO Commitments

/ / / / / / / / / / /11. Wheat Corn Soybeans

THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY. Daniel A. Sumner and William Matthews 1

Rethinking US Agricultural Policy:

Exploring Options for a New Farm Bill

Hog:Corn Ratio What can we learn from the old school?

CORN: DECLINING WORLD GRAIN STOCKS OFFERS POTENTIAL FOR HIGHER PRICES

Changing Tobacco Markets: Effects on Burley Tobacco Farms 1,2

Encyclopedia of Politics of the American West

CORN: CROP PROSPECTS TO DOMINATE PRICES

Diversified versus Specialized Swine and Grain Operations

Commodity Value Enhancement Fund Analysis

The Revenue Program Option in the 2008 U.S. Farm Bill: Evaluating Performance Characteristics of the ACRE Program

Impacts of the Commodity Provisions of the Food and Agriculture Risk Management for the 21st Century Act of 2007 (FARM 21)

THE WELFARE IMPACT OF JAPANESE AGRICULTURAL TRADE POLICY DISTORTIONS. Sjors Hendricus Antonius Bom *

Grain, Oilseed and Fiber Crop Outlook

Fall Crop Outlook Webinar

The Impact of Ethanol and Ethanol Subsidies on Corn Prices: Revisiting History

Agriculture: expansions highlighted developments

BioEnergy Policy Brief July 2009 BPB

SOME ASPECTS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICY IN AUSTRALIA

1979 Food and Agricultural Outlook

Dr Biswajit Dhar Professor and Head Centre for WTO Studies Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi

Grain Prices Remain Sensitive to Weather, Export Developments

Hancock Farmland Investor

USDA Agricultural Baseline Projections to 2008

Public Policy and Agriculture

CORN: HIGHER PRICES COMES EARLY

2018 Farm Bill Survey

For additional information, contact the Washington Office staff person who serves your state.

U.S. milk production up 0.6 percent over NY milk production up 3.5 percent. Income over feed costs projected to fall 6 percent

CRS Report for Congress

TIMELY INFORMATION. Agriculture & Natural Resources AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS AND RURAL SOCIOLOGY, AUBURN UNIVERSITY, AL

CORN: FIVE CONSECUTIVE LARGE CROPS?

Agriculture: issues of the past resurface

BioEnergy Policy Brief January 2013

What Is the Farm Bill?

Competitiveness of American Agriculture in the Global Economy. Ian Sheldon. AED Economics

THE CURRENT STATE OF THE U.S. AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY

CRS Report for Congress

o:y J:.. Carroll' Bottum1

SOYBEANS: LARGE SUPPLIES CONFIRMED, BUT WHAT ABOUT 2005 PRODUCTION?

Economic and Financial Conditions Bode Well for U.S. Agriculture

CORN: USDA REPORTS FAIL TO CONFIRM SMALLER SUPPLIES

U.S. Farm Policy and Developing Countries 미국의농장정책및개발도상국. Dr. Gary W. Williams Professor of Agricultural Economics Texas A&M University

CORN: PRODUCTION EXCEEDS EXPECTATIONS

FAPRI Outlook: Prospects and Uncertainties for the Next Decade

EASTERN CORN BELT DELAYS CONTINUE, MORE FARM PROGRAM DETAILS

The Outlook for Grain Markets and Texas Agriculture in Emily Kerr and Michael Plante

CORN: SMALLER SUPPLIES ON THE HORIZON. April 2001 Darrel Good No. 3

U.S. Farm Bill Scenarios and Impact on Developing Countries

Table 1. U.S. Agricultural Exports as a Share of Production, 1992

INTERPRETATION OF LONG-TERM TRADE PROJECTIONS: CHINA S ROLE IN FORECAST DISCREPANCIES AND ITS IMPACT ON EXPECTATIONS FOR WORLD AGRICULTURAL TRADE

Actual Farm Bill Spending and Cost Estimates

WikiLeaks Document Release

An Analysis of Historical Trends in the Farmgate Report. Brigid A. Doherty and John C. McKissick (1) Center for Agribusiness and Economic Development

Impacts of WTO Policy Reforms on U.S. Rice

IS THE CURRENT FARM PROSPERITY SUSTAINABLE?* Mike Boehlje, Brent Gloy, and Jason Henderson** Center for Commercial Agriculture.

2018 AG ECONOMY OUTLOOK NORTH DAKOTA BANKERS ASSOCIATION 66 TH LEGISLATIVE SESSION

SOYBEANS: AN EARLY WEATHER MARKET

Former Soviet Union Region To Play Larger Role in Meeting World Wheat Needs

Characteristics, Plans, and Opinions of Kentucky Dairy Termination Program Participants

CORN: BETTER DEMAND, PRODUCTION CONCERNS

Reshaping Agricultural Production: Geography, Farm Structure, and Finances

MICRO DYNAMICS OF INCOME, DEBT MANAGEMENT AND FARM FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE

CORN: MARKET TO REFLECT U.S. AND CHINESE CROP PROSPECTS

The Distribution of Farm Program Payments in the U.S.

TIMELY INFORMATION Agriculture & Natural Resources

Legislative Outlook on 2007 Farm Bill

Statement of. Thomas M. Hoenig. President. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. before the. Senate Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition and Forestry

CORN: ATTENTION NOW TURNS TO THE NEW CROP

Iowa Farm Outlook. December 15, 2004 Ames, Iowa Econ. Info. 1900

2016 Agricultural Resource Management Phase III. Great Lakes Region Indiana Michigan Ohio

GRAIN PRICE OUTLOOK: SEASONALITY, ACREAGE, CHINA ON GMO, ETHANOL

The Impacts of Eliminating the Direct Payments on the U.S. Cotton Market CERI-P11-01

Emerging Biofuels: Outlook of Effects on U.S. Grain, Oilseed, and Livestock Markets

College of Agriculture, Extension Service in Agriculture and Home Economics FOOD IN OUR SOCIETY

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 17: ANALYSIS OF PAST FARM BILL PROGRAMS II

NAFTA and Domestic Policy Impacts: U.S. View

Geography, Farm Structure, and Finances

Third Quarter 2012 Earnings Conference Call. 15 August 2012

John Deere s Outlook on Cattle Economics

The Frame of Agricultural Policy and Recent Agricultural Policy in Korea June

Crop costs and margins and future cereal prices

Analysis of the October 2010 USDA Crop Production & WASDE Reports

AGRICULTURAL TRADE AND ITS IMPORTANCE

Transcription:

CARD Working Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 7-1989 Commodity Program Reform and the Structure of U.S. Agriculture William H. Meyers owa State University Patrick C. Westhoff owa State University Follow this and additional works at: http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/card_workingpapers Part of the Agricultural and Resource Economics Commons, Agricultural Economics Commons, Economics Commons, and the Public Policy Commons Recommended Citation Meyers, William H. and Westhoff, Patrick C., "Commodity Program Reform and the Structure of U.S. Agriculture" (1989). CARD Working Papers. 66. http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/card_workingpapers/66 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the CARD Reports and Working Papers at owa State University Digital Repository. t has been accepted for inclusion in CARD Working Papers by an authorized administrator of owa State University Digital Repository. For more information, please contact digirep@iastate.edu.

Commodity Program Reform and the Structure of U.S. Agriculture Abstract Current agricultural commodity programs affect the structure of U.S. agriculture in a variety of ways. An informal survey of participants in a conference concerning the structure of agriculture indicates a weak consensus among professionals that current programs increase the number of farms, result in more specialization, and encourage land ownership by operators. Analysis by the Food and Agricultural Policy Research nstitute (FAPR) indicates that the elimination of current farm programs would reduce net farm income dramatically, especially in the short run. The negative effects on farm income are estimated to be smaller if other countries also eliminate their agricultural subsidy programs. Disciplines Agricultural and Resource Economics Agricultural Economics Economics Public Policy This article is available at owa State University Digital Repository: http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/card_workingpapers/66

Commodity Program Reform and the Structure of U.S. Agriculture by William H. Meyers and Patrick C. Westhoff Working Paper 89-WP 44 July 1989 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development owa State University Ames, owa 511 William H. Meyers is professor of economics and associate director of CARD. Patrick C. Westhoff is a postdoctoral research associate, CARD. Thts paper was presented at the NC-181 Regional Research Meetmg on the Structure of Agriculture, Tucson, Anzona, January 7-12,1989.

iii Contents Figures. Tables Abstract ntroduction Program Functions that Affect Agriculture Prospects for the 199s under Current Programs mpact of Eliminating Commodity Programs mplications for Farm Structure References............... v v vii 1 1 5 8 ll 21

v Figures Figure 1. Figure 2. Figure 3. Figure 4. Figure 5. Figure 6. Figure 7. Figure 8. Figure 9. Figure 1. Figure 11. Figure 12. Real U.S. gulf port prices U.S. wheat net returns U.S. corn net returns U.S. total crop acres NF and government payments Net CCC outlays Area plant in eight major crops Total area planted and idled Price index for eight major crops Price index for five livestock products Net farm income Government cost 15 15 16 16 17 17 18 18 19 19 2 2 Tables Table 1. Table 2. Hypotheses on the effect of commodity programs on farm structure............... Distribution of farms, direct government payments, cash sales, net farm income, and off-farm income by value of sales class, 1987.... 4 12

vii Abstract Current agricultural commodity programs affect the structure of U.S. agriculture in a variety of ways. An informal survey of participants in a conference concerning the structure of agriculture indicates a weak consensus among professionals that current programs increase the number of farms, result in more specialization, and encourage land ownership by operators. Analysis by the Food and Agricultural Policy Research nstitute (FAPR) indicates that the elimination of current farm programs would reduce net farm income dramatically, especially in the short run. The negative effects on farm income are estimated to be smaller if other countries also eliminate their agricultural subsidy programs.

ntroduction As a consequence of budget pressure at home and GATT multilateral trade negotiations abroad, there has been much debate in recent years about radical reform or elimination of commodity programs. This immediately raises the question of how current programs have influenced the structure of agriculture in the United States and, conversely, how their removal would alter this structure. Because debate has focused largely on commodity programs, this paper does not address the broader range of issues such as taxation, credit, research, and other policies affecting agriculture. t begins by reviewing hypotheses on how commodity program functions are likely to affect the structure of agriculture. Then, prospects for the 199s under the extension of current policies are reviewed based on recent projections by the Food and Agricultural Policy Research nstitute (FAPR, a joint program between CARD and the Center for National Food and Agricultural Policy, University of Missouri-Columbia). Finally, comparisons of. projection scenarios under two policy reform options are used to evaluate the potential impacts of reform on the structure of agriculture. Program Functions that Affect Agriculture Current commodity programs are a package of policy instruments that include income support, price stabilization, commodity credit, and supply management. Recently, environmental policy instruments such as

2 cross-compliance and the conservation reserve programs have been included; but these instruments are more likely than the others to be excluded from deliberations on reducing support levels in the context of either unilateral or multilateral policy reform. Export enhancement has also become a significant part of government program costs, but it can be considered a targeted program on trade with limited impact on the farm structure question. t would be difficult, if not impossible, to empirically measure the separate effects of the different instruments in the package of commodity progrs. A farmer participating in the wheat program, for example, receives a deficiency payment and becomes eligible for loans and the farmer-owned reserve in exchange for setting aside a certain proportion of base acres. There is certainly some income support included in the payment, and some subsidies are embedded in the loan programs, but program benefits are also, in part, payment for removing land from production. n terms of looking at structural impacts, however, it is useful to separate the differing impacts on the structure of agriculture of these program functions or instruments. This cannot be done quantitatively, but it can be done qualitatively through the application of economic theory, available empirical evidence, and reasoned judgment. Given the subjectivity of these evaluations, however, analysts will differ in their conclusions. The degree of uncertainty about the direction of these impacts is reflected in the views of six participants in the NC-181 Regional Research

3 Meeting on the Structure of Agriculture, held in Tucson, Arizona, January 7-12, 1989. These participants and the senior author of this paper recorded their own hypotheses concerning the impacts of government farm programs on several indicators of the structure of U.S. agriculture. Results (Table 1) indicate some consensus on the impacts of income support and net impacts of commodity programs, but there is a lot of uncertainty about the impacts of price stabilization, commodity loans, and supply management programs. The weakness of this limited consensus, however, is indicated by the fact that in more than half of the issues considered, only four of the seven respondents agreed about likely impact. Admittedly, some uncertainty was due to the vagueness of some categories defined by the author. nsofar as consensus emerged, it supported the hypothesis that the current package of commodity programs has increased the number of farms, reduced farm size, and increased specialization, the rate of adopting new technology, the barriers to exit and entry, the land ownership by operators; and family income of farmers. The same pattern of expected effects emerged for the income-support instruments in the commodity programs. Moreover, the degree of agreement about the income-support effects was higher. Although the income-support aspects of the programs seemed to dominate the overall effects, where there was consensus about the impacts of other program instruments, it was usually in the same direction as the income support effect. The exception was the hypothesis that price stabilization programs would increase farm size, probably because of risk-reducing effects.

4 Table 1. Hypotheses on the Effect of Commodity Programs on Farm Structure Program Function Effect ncome Price Commodity Supply Net On/Of: Support Stabilization Loans Mgt. Number of Farms + +?? + Farm Size +? Specialization + + +? + Adoption of New Technology + + +? + Barriers to Entry & Exit +?? + + Land Ownership by Operator +??? + Family ncome +? + + + NOTE: Where four or more of the seven respondents agree, a "+" or "-" is indicated, otherwise "?" is indicated. + means higher or more - means lower or less? means uncertain

5 Overall, these indicators are not very conclusive. t will be difficult to draw conclusions about the effects of policy reform on farm structure if we cannot resolve differences among analysts about the effects of current programs on the structural indicators. Prospects for the 199s under Current Programs Before evaluating the impacts of policy reform, it is useful to evaluate the prospects for agriculture if current programs are continued. This is the baseline to which policy changes can be compared. The FAPR projections for U.S. agriculture (FAPR 1989) are based on moderate growth rates for real GOP in the United States and around the world, the continued depreciation of the U.S. dollar relative to most developed country currencies, and the continuation of current commodity programs with only slight modifications. n particular, it is assumed that current programs will remain in effect until the Food Security Act of 1985 expires in 199. The reduced acreage set-aside rates for feed grains and wheat brought about by the 1988 drought are assumed to continue. The conservation reserve is assumed to reach the 4-million-acre minimum specified by the law. For the years beyond the current legislation, it is assumed that target prices will remain at the 199 level, and that loan rates and dairy support prices will continue to be adjusted based on formulas in the current legislation. Other countries are also assumed to continue current agricultural policies; no adjustment is made for policy changes that may occur as the result of the current GATT negotiations.

6 Prices of grains and soybeans are expected to return quickly to predrought levels, assuming normal weather and no unexpected demand shocks in 1989 and 199. Slight increases in nominal prices are projected in the subsequent years, but they are not enough to keep real commodity prices from continuing their long-term decline (Figure 1). Surplus capacity is expected to be a more serious problem for cotton and rice as these prices remain close to loan rates, and direct payment rates and progra participation rates remain high. A measure of the well-being of crop producers can be the net returns to participants and nonparticipants in commodity programs. n the case of wheat, net returns to participants remain relatively stable in the $75-$8 range for the next four years, then decline as costs continue to increase but target prices remain constant (Figure 2). The gap between participant and nonparticipant net returns, which was $2-$3 per acre in the 1985-1987 period, returns to about $2 per acre after the impacts of the drought wear off in 199, but it declines to an average of about $1 per acre in the second half of the decade. Corn net returns, after recovering from the drought impact, do not. return to the predrought levels but gradually decline over the projection period (Figure 3). The gap between participant and nonparticipant returns, which averaged $8 per acre from 1985 to 1987, remains in the $4-$5 range over the projection period. For both wheat and corn, as with sorghum and barley, the participation rates decline as the gap narrows between participant and nonparticipant returns.

7 The total acreage planted to major program crops declined about 4 million acres as a result of acreage reduction programs over the past three years (Figure 4). As the acreage reduction program is cut back in response to the drought, planted acreage is expected to increase by more than 2 million acres in 1989 and to remain fairly stable at that level for the next few years. n the latter half of the decade, growth in area continues as export-led price increases bring more land into production. dle land, which reached nearly 8 million acres in 1988, is reduced by 24 milliori acres in 1989. t remains about 6 million acres for the next few years. The significant change in idle acres is the shift :rom annual acreage reduction programs, which accounted for two-thirds of the idle acreage in 1988/89, to the long-term conservation reserve, which accounts for two-thirds of the idle acreage from 199 onward. The expectation that a larger share of land idled will be in the long-term conservation program indicates that market prices could be more volatile in response to weather variability in the United States and around the world, given that carryover stocks are also substantially lower than they have been at any time since 198. The net farm income before adjustments for inventory changes is a relatively stable indicator of income, in that it avoids the wide fluctuations that sometimes occur in the values of inventories. By this measure, net farm income reached record levels of $46-$47 billion in 1987 and 1988 (Figure 5). The projections are for gradually declining net farm income levels, as increases in production expenses are expected to exceed

8 the growth in cash receipts from market prices. The decline in government payments, from the peak of nearly $17 billion in 1987 to less than $9 billion in 1993, also contributes to this decline in income. This decline in payments is associated with falling target prices until 199 and with lower rates of participation in commodity programs as market prices increase in the later years. n general, the outlook is for a farm economy not as robust in terms of cash flow as it has been the past two years, yet more healthy than was the case during the early 198s. Having been helped over the period of large surplus capacity by large acreage reduction programs and a major drought, farmers are expected to receive more of their income from the market and less from the government, leading to government program costs in the range of $1 billion or less rather than the $2 billion or more common in recent years (Figure 6). mpact of Eliminating Commodity Programs n a previous report (CARD 1988), FAPR models were used to evaluate the impacts of unilateral elimination of U.S. commodity programs or the elimination of these programs in the context of multilateral trade liberalization and policy reform among the major trading countries. The results provide insights into how current programs influence commodity prices, land use, farm income, and government costs. These results are summarized here as they relate to possible effects of such policy reform on farm structure.

9 Reported results are based on changes from a predrought scenario. The effects of the 1988 drought on these results would be expected to include short-run impacts on prices, planted acreage, farm income, and government costs. The long-run effects should be very similar to those reported in this section. n both scenarios the current programs are phased out over the 1989-1991 period, and the conservation reserve program is continued. Unilateral elimination of U.S. commodity programs results in a rapid increase in acreage planted to program crops as acreage reduction programs are eliminated (Figure 7). This, combined with the liquidation of government-held stocks, results in a drop in crop prices during the three-year phase-in period (Figure 9). The lower crop prices lead to an expansion in livestock production and lower livestock prices, which reach their low points two years later than the crop sector (Figure 1). The impacts are smaller in the later years, since the baseline idled acreage was smaller in the later years. The total area planted and idled declines as total land use falls in response to lower returns to crop production (Figure 8). Net farm income, assuming no compensation payments, drops by ever larger amounts until the maximum drop of about $15 billion in 1992 (Figure ll). Thereafter, the net farm income loss dimishes to about $1 billion annually. Government costs also drop substantially, but the cost of continuing the conservation reserve program keeps it at slightly more than $2 billion annually. The cost savings reach a maximum of nearly

1 $8 billion in fiscal year 1993 (Figure 12), but they average more than $5 billion annually for the 1992-1996 period. Thus, the cost savings under a unilateral approach would be sufficient only to compensate for approximately one-half of the loss in farm income. The multilateral scenario for eliminating government support programs in the United States and abroad provides much different results. The larger reduction in prices to producers and consumers in such areas as the European Community and Japan results in substantial increases in demand for U.S. commodity exports. This more than offsets the increase in available crop acreage in the United States and leads to higher--rather than lower--prices for U.S. crops and livestock. The exception to this pattern is soybeans, where prices decline since current policies abroad tend to favor the U.S. soybean industry. The higher market prices lead to planted acreage levels higher than those of the unilateral scenario. The effects of higher prices and greater production lead to smaller short-run declines in net farm income. n fact, near the end of the adjustment period, net farm income levels are approximately the same as those in the baseline. Costs decline even more rapidly under the multilateral scenario since market prices are higher. This leads to a maximum cost savings of about $9 billion in fiscal year 1991 and to an average of about $6 billion annually for the period 1992-1996. Thus, in the multilateral case, there are more than ample savings generated by the elimination of programs to compensate producers for the loss of income during the transition period.

ll mplications for Farm Structure Under the unilateral commodity program phaseout, there would be severe price declines and even more severe declines in net returns since deficiency payments would also be lost. More price risk would also be expected, given the lower level of commodity stocks and the lack of a loan program or price floor. Land prices and asset values in general would be expected to decline substantially in consort with the decline in expected net returns. The estimated impacts also suggest that even in the long run, the government cost savings are smaller than the loss in net farm income. According to the weak consensus cited earlier among conference participants (Table 1), program elimination without compensation would lead to fewer and larger farms,. greater diversification, slower adoption of new technology, reduced barriers to entry, reduced land ownership by operators, and of course, lower income. Another way to look at the potential impacts of the income losses is to ask which farms are most heavily dependent upon government payments. The 1987 data on the distribution of government payments by value of sales class (Table 2) indicate that the farms most heavily dependent on government payments relative to farm income and total income are those in the classes $4,-$99,999 and $1,-$499,999, based on value of sales. The largest farms (by value of sales) either are not producing commodities affected by the government programs or they have reached the payment limitation constraint. Very small farms earn most of their income

12 Table 2. Distribution of Farms, Direct Government Payments, Cash Sales, Net Farm ncome, and Off-Farm ncome by Value of Sales Class, 1987 Sales Class $5, and over $1, to $499,999 $4, to $99,999 Less than All $4, Farms Number of Farms 29, 272, 286, 1,589, 2,176, Percent of Farms 1.3 12.5 l3.2 73. 1. Percent of Government Payments 7.9 47.6 25.5 19. 1. Percent of Cash Receipts 37.5 39.9 13 1 9.4 1. - - - (dollars per agricultural operation) Payment per Farm 46,1 29,3 14,9 2, 7,7 Cash Sales per Farm Payment/Sales (%) 1, 787,7 2.6 22,8 14.4 63,4 23.5 8,2 24.4 63,5 12 1 Net Farm ncome Payment/Net Farm ncome (%) 738. 1 6. 71,7 41. 18,7 8. 516 a 21.5 36.6 Off-farm ncome Payment/Total ncome 29.4 2.5 14,8 33.9 14,6 44.7 23,7 8.3 21,5 17.9 - (billion dollars) Total Payments 1.3 8. 4.3 3.2 16.7 SOURCE: Economic ndicators of the Farm Sector, USDA, ERS, National Financial Summary, pp. 39-51, October 1988. a Net farm income is negative without government payments.

l3 off the farm and depend on government payments for only 8 percent of their total income. Of course, these averages obscure some very large cotton and rice farmers who are highly dependent on payments for their income, as well as some very small, poor farmers who do not have a large off-farm income. Still, the evidence suggests that the effect of removing commodity programs without compensation would be most severe on farms within the $4,-$99,999 class. n the context of a multilateral phaseout of government support programs in the United States and abroad, there would be more than ample government cost savings to institute compensation payments to offset the loss of incomes from the programs. Under the current U.S. GATT proposal, such payments would have to be "decoupled" (neutral with respect to production, consumption, and trade). Such compensation would not need to be distributed in the same way as are current program benefits. Targeting could be employed to achieve particular structural or rural development targets, provided that Congress could find a targeting scheme sufficiently broad-based to achieve majority support. However, even the general idea of decoupled programs has not yet been widely accepted in Congress. n an environment without commodity program bases and supply management constraints, the possibilities for increased diversification could offset somewhat the increased risk associated with the removal of commodity programs. Declines in asset value, while causing financial problems for current producers, would, of course, reduce barriers to entry for new farmers. These are among the reasons why it is difficult for

14 analysts to reach a consensus about the effects of current programs on farm structure. Until the research community can assemble more consistent and conclusive results on these effects, strong conclusions remain to be drawn about the effect of existing programs or their elimination on the structure of agriculture.

c.. " soo 4SO 4 35 l v o 3 ' " m 2SO 2 1SO 1 so y Figure 1 (\ 15 Real u.s. Gulf Port Prices 71/72 74/75 77/78 8/81 8.3/8-4 86/87 89/9 92/93 A 93-97 Corn W"\ eat Soybean 9 Figure 2: U.S. Wheat Net Returns 8.. 7 2 so 4 1 3 2 -------.--------r-------.--------.--------r-------.------- 8/81 82/8.3 84/85 86/87 88/89 9/91 92/9.3 A 9.3-97 Porlicipont Nonporli<:ipont

16 Figure 3: u.s. Corn Net Returns < ;.. ::. 18, 7 15 J i 15 14 13 12 11 : \ 1-1 ' 9 l 8...j! 7 -f 6 ' j \ / = so -i 4 8/81 82/8.3 84/85 86/87 88/89 9/91 92/9.3 A 9.3-97 Porticipcnt Nonporticipcnt 33 32 31 Figure 4: U.S. Total Crop Acres CO. WH, 58, BA. SG, OA. Rl, CT "---. < c.3 '""'l i 29 28 27 = :>: 26 25 24 23 22 21 6/61 64/65 68/69 72/7.3 76/77 8/81 84/85 88/89 92/9.3 A 9.3-97 Planted Planted+ldled P!td+ldled-CRP

17 so Figure 5: NF and Government Payments 45! 4 -;! i 35 _J. 3 Q ' 25 j 2 15 t ' 1 J s _J ' 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 as 87 89 91 9.3 A 94-97 Gov't Payments + NF"l (unod(usted) Figure 6: Net CCC Outlays 26 24 22 2 ( 18. J 16 14 ' c iii 1 8 6 4 T 2 71 73 7S 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 A 94-97 F'iscol Year

18 Figure 7: Area Planted 1n 8 Maior Crops Cl"lon._e from Base 13 ---------------------------------------------------------- 12 _j 1 J ' i H 6 -i 11 --i s i 4 i 3 -' 1 _, i/ 1968/89 1989/9 199/91 1991/92 1992/9.3 199.3/94 1994/95 1995/9 1 995/97 Unilateral Multilateral Figure 8: Total Area Planted and dled Unilateral Multilc:Jfe,.ol

1 i 8 -; 6 1 2 J -2 j - j -6-8 -1 l -12 19 Figure 9: Price ndex for 8 Maior Crops \ Change from Bose -14-16 -; -18-2 l -22 1988/89 1989/9 199/91 1991/92 1992/9.3 199.3/94 1994/95 1995/96 1995/97 a Uni!alerol ulliloterol Figure 6 5 4 -t ' ' -1 2. T - -2 l _, - -5 l -6-7 -8-9 -1 -; ' _, J -12 1988 1: Price ndex for 5 Livestock Products Change from Bose n! 1989 199 1991 1992 1993 199 1995 1996 a Unilateral Mulliloiel"ol

2 Figure 11: Net Farm ncome Chong tram 8os _, - -4 - -5 _J -6 l c -7. -8 _, '! ' _, -9 -; -1 ' -11-12 -13 _J -14 - -15 -; -16 1988 1989 199 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 996 Unilateral ultilateral Figure 1 2: Government Cost Change from Bose a '- -1 -j! -2 ' 1-3 -4 -; -5 _, \ -6 \ _, \ ' \ l \! -8 l! -9 F"Y-88 F"Y-89 FY-9 F"Y-91 fy-94 FY-95 r'!'-96 Unilateral Multilateral

21 References CARD. 1988. "Policy Scenarios with the FAPR Commodity Models." Working Paper 88-WP41. Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, owa State University, Ames. FAPR. 1989. "FAPR U.S. and World Agricultural Outlook, Summary and Tables, February 1989." FAPR Staff Report #1-89. Food and Agricultural Policy Research nstitute, University of Missouri-Columbia, and owa State University, Ames.