How Working Time Reduction Affects Employment and Wages

Similar documents
Dispersion in Wage Premiums and Firm Performance

Tilburg University. Flexibility of the labor market Santos Raposo, P.M. Publication date: Link to publication

Does the Color of the Collar Matter? Firm Specific Human Capital and Post-Displacement Outcomes

Does the color of the collar matter? Firm specific human capital and post-displacement outcomes

Performance Pay, Competitiveness, and the Gender Wage Gap: Evidence from the United States

Decomposing the Wage Losses of Displaced Workers: The Role of the Reallocation of Workers into Firms and Job Titles

Can overtime premium flexibility promote employment? Firm- and worker-level evidence from a labour law reform. CGR Working Paper 72. Pedro S.

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in Services: Direct Evidence from a Firm Survey

A Note on Risk Aversion and Labour Market Outcomes: Further Evidence from German Survey Data

Volume 35, Issue 1. Implicit contracts and industrial relations - Evidence from German employeremployee

Tilburg University. On the Employment Effects of Part-Time Labor van Lomwel, A.G.C.; van Ours, Jan. Publication date: Link to publication

LABLAC LABOR DATABASE FOR LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN

Estimating Earnings Equations and Women Case Evidence

Training and the New Minimum Wage

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data

The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets

Unpaid Overtime in Germany: Differences between East and West

Overtime Policy and Labor Market Outcomes: Evidence from South Korea

Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle

The Nature of Wage Adjustment in the U.S.: New Evidence from Linked Worker Firm Data

Chasing the carrot. Effort provision of fixed-term employees

Can Worksharing Decrease Unemployment while Maintaining Economy Growth? A Case Study for Six World Leading Economies

Labor Market Imperfections and the Firm s Wage Setting Policy

Wage dispersion and employment turnover in Taiwan

Topics in Labor Supply

The Age Pay Gap in Italy Investigating the Sources of the Pay Differential by Age

Compensation Practices, Worker Mobility, and Wage Dispersion: Evidence from Brazilian Employer-Employee Matched Data

The Timing of Labor Demand Ana Rute Cardoso Daniel S. Hamermesh José Varejao

FLSA recordkeeping requirements

Unionization and Informal Economy

High Wage Workers Match with High Wage Firms: Clear Evidence of the Effects of Limited Mobility Bias

WARWICK ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS

Working from Home: Heterogenous Effects on Hours Worked and Wages

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TIMING OF LABOR DEMAND. Ana Rute Cardoso Daniel S. Hamermesh José Varejão

Labour cost index in the private sector Instructions for responding

UNIVERSITY OF WAIKATO. Hamilton. New Zealand. The Public Sector Pay Premium and Compensating Differentials in the New Zealand Labour Market

Results from Portugal

Labor market imperfections and the firm s wage setting policy

The Impact of Higher Fixed Pay and Lower Bonuses on Productivity

Report to the Legislature: Overtime in Minnesota Agriculture

The Minimum Wage and Worker Productivity: A Case Study of California Strawberry Pickers

Proposal 1: Require that each medical student complete one rotation at a qualified geriatric care facility.

Exports, Imports and Wages: Evidence from Matched Firm-Worker-Product Panels

Wage Mobility within and between Jobs

Sources of Displaced Workers Long-Term Earnings Losses 1

WHO ARE YOU CALLING, "MANAGER"? THE PROPOSED WHITE-COLLAR EXEMPTION OVERTIME REGULATIONS

WAGE EFFECTS OF FIRM SIZE: EVIDENCE FROM LINKED EMPLOYER-EMPLOYEE PANEL

Ruhm, C. (1990). Do Earnings Increase with Job Seniority? The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 72 (1):

The Effect of Foreign Acquisition on Employment and Wages: Evidence from Finnish Establishments

Review Questions. Definitions. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

GENDER DIVERSITY IN MANAGEMENT POSITIONS AND THE GENDER WAGE GAP. EVIDENCE FROM SPANISH LABOR MARKET

PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT ACROSS KANSAS (PEAK)

The Computer Use Premium and Worker Unobserved Skills: An Empirical Analysis

The Timing of Labor Demand

Designing the integration of register and survey data in earning statistics

The Relative Power of Employment-to-Employment Reallocation and Unemployment Exits in Predicting Wage Growth

THE POST-HISTORY OF ENTREPRENEURS: IMPACT OF BUSINESS OWNERSHIP EXPERIENCE ON CAREERS AND WAGES

working papers Pedro S. Martins Luca David Opromolla September 2011

The effect of upward nominal wage pushing on workers accessions and separations

The Sources of Wage Variation: A Three-Way High-Dimensional Fixed Effects Regression Model

The Youth Labour Market in Australia Implications From Work Choices Legislation

Exporting and Worker Training

TECHNICAL COLLEGE OF THE LOWCOUNTRY PROCEDURE PROCEDURE NUMBER: REF. STATE BOARD POLICY: REF. STATE BOARD PROC.:

INTERNAL OPERATING PROCEDURE. Procedure No. _HR-2005_. Revision(s) 06/27/1996; 02/01/2006; 02/01/2007; 1/26/2017 Related References Purpose

Labour Market Effects of Work- Sharing Arrangements in Europe

An Extension of the Blinder-Oaxaca Decomposition to a Continuum of Comparison Groups

Career Progression within Large Firms

Incentive pay and the wage structure of firms: Evidence from a panel of Dutch firms

ECB/CEPR Labour Market Workshop 2006 "Wage and Labour Cost Dynamics"

The NEW White Collar Exemption Rule: How to Prepare

Labor Demand. Rongsheng Tang. July, Washington U. in St. Louis. Rongsheng Tang (Washington U. in St. Louis) Labor Demand July, / 53

Chapter 3. Table of Contents. Introduction. Empirical Methods for Demand Analysis

THE NEW OVERTIME REGULATIONS HOPE EASTMAN JIM HAMMERSCHMIDT JESSICA SUMMERS

Dismissals for cause: The difference that just eight paragraphs can make

EXAMINATION 1 VERSION A "Labor Supply and Demand" February 24, 2014

Quasi-Fixed Labor Costs and Their Effects on Demand

Fixed-Term Contract Employees and Intra-Firm Wage Gaps

Upward nominal wage rigidity

Explaining the Wage Gap Between Contingent and Noncontingent Workers

Multiple job holding, local labor markets, and the business cycle

Labor Economics. Evidence on Efficiency Wages. Sébastien Roux. ENSAE-Labor Economics. April 4th 2014

Public Sector Pay Premium and Compensating Differentials in the New Zealand Labour Market

The Diversity of Personnel Practices and Firm Performance

CGR Working Paper Series. The third worker: Assessing the trade-off between employees and contractors. CGR Working Paper 75. Pedro S.

Frequently Asked Questions (FAQ) Holiday Pay and Leave for December

Wasted Resources in Germany: the Paucity of Female Supervisors and the Wage Disadvantage of Their Subordinates

Online Appendix for the article: Higher and higher? Performance pay and wage inequality in Germany

THE IMPACT OF IN-HOUSE TRAINING ON THE DIVERSITY

Rule 3. Compensation

!"#$%&'()*+,-./#&0()/1&2.34'/5&326-.7)/

STRATEGIC CONSIDERATIONS IN COMPLYING WITH THE OFCCP S NEW 503/VEVRAA REGULATIONS

The E ciency of Human Capital Allocations in Developing Countries

Trade and Inequality. Clausen Conference on Global Economic Issues 2017 Bob Koopman Chief Economist, World Trade Organization

Overtime Compensation

Gender difference of the informal sector wage gap: a longitudinal analysis for the Korean labor market

California Sales Professional Exemptions PART 4 OF 5: OVERVIEW OF CALIFORNIA EXEMPTION

Wage and Hour Law Update. Brian M. O Neal McMahon Berger, P.C North Ballas Road St. Louis, MO (314)

Guide to Navigating the Proposed Overtime Regulations

CPB Discussion Paper 198. Wage-Tenure Profiles and Mobility. Anja Deelen

Appendix (Additional Materials for Electronic Media of the Journal) I. Variable Definition, Means and Standard Deviations

Transcription:

How Working Time Reduction Affects Employment and Wages Preliminary version Pedro S. Raposo Jan C. van Ours January 28, 2008 Abstract December 1, 1996 the standard workweek in Portugal was reduced from 44 hours to 40 hours. We study how this mandatory reduction affected employment and wages. We find that the working hours reduction increased hourly wage of workers involved, keeping monthly earnings approximately constant. The working hours reduction did not lead to job loss of workers directly affected but may have caused negative employment effects for workers working less than 40 hours per week. Keywords: Workweek reduction, natural experiment, employment dynamics JEL codes: J22, J63, J81 Department of Economics, Tilburg University; email: P.M.SantosRaposo@uvt.nl. Pedro S. Raposo gratefully acknowledges financial support by the Portuguese Foundation of Science and Technology, FCT [SFRH/BD/21906/2005]. Department of Economics and CentER, Tilburg University, The Netherlands; Department of Economics, University of Melbourne, Parkville, Australia; IZA and CEPR; vanours@uvt.nl. 1

1 Introduction In the past decades working hours have been reduced in many countries, often with the purpose of worksharing, assuming that working time reduction has a positive effect on employment. There are a few studies that analyze the effects of working hours reduction. Crépon and Kramarz (2002) study the 1982 reduction of the workweek in France from 40 to 39 hours finding that it didn t create jobs but increased unemployment. Hunt (1999) finds similar results for gradual working time reduction in Germany. Investigating developments over the period 1984-94 she finds that working time reduction led to higher hourly wages and lower employment. Andrews et al. (2005) also find no evidence of positive employment effects of work-sharing in Germany. Skuterud (2007) presents an analysis of the Canadian province of Quebec where the standard workweek was gradually reduced from 44 to 40 hours concluding that despite a 20% reduction among full-time workers in weekly hours worked beyond 40, the policy failed to raise employment. Varejão (2006) investigates the effects of the 1996 working time reduction in Portugal finding that the policy originated a negative scale effect, a substitution of overtime for normal hours and wage restraint. He finds that the firms reaction to the policy is affected by the presence of minimum wage earners and the use of overtime hours. This paper looks at the impact of a workweek reduction from 44 to 40 hours that was introduced in 1996 in Portugal. Our study is distinct from Varejão (2006) for three reasons. First, we look at short-term and long-term effects. Second, we use a longer time period before the policy change to identify the effects of the working hours reduction. Third, we investigated the presence of firm effects. 2 Portuguese labor market 2.1 The reduction of the workweek In Portugal, mid 1990s the unemployment rate was about 7%, almost 3%-point below the average of the European Union. In December 1996, a new law was intro- 2

duced with the aim of reducing the standard workweek from 44 to 40 hours. The law was not passed as a tool to create jobs and reduce unemployment but it was introduced because the newly-elected government wanted to speed up the convergence of Portuguese traditionally long hours of work to the European average (Varejão, 2006). The new law implied that by 1st December 1997 all jobs should meet the new standard, 40 hours per week, in the following way: First, by 1st December 1996, all workweeks above 42 hours should be reduced by 2 hours; workweeks below 42 hours but above 40 hours should meet the new standard of 40 hours per week. Second, by 1st December 1997, all workweeks still above 40 hours should meet the standard. In order to compensate firms for the reduction in working hours the new law introduced some flexibility. The reduction was implemented taking into account that the normal workweek could be defined on a 4 months average. The maximum number of hours could be increased 2 hours per day given that it did not exceed 10 hours per day and 50 hours per week. 2.2 Data We use a longitudinal dataset matching firms and workers in the Portuguese economy, called Quadros de Pessoal (QP Lists of Personnel ). The data are gathered annually by the Ministry of Employment, based on an inquiry that every establishment with wage-earners is legally obliged to fill in. Reported data cover all the personnel working for the establishment in a reference week in October (see Cardoso (2006) for details). Every year QP gathers information for more than 250 thousand firms and 2.5 million workers. We use information for the time period 1994-1998. The worker data include gender, age, schooling, monthly earnings and duration of work. Our sample contains workers that are wage earners, regardless of being fulltime or part-time workers. We dropped individuals with missing information on normal hours of work and monthly earnings. 3

2.3 Definitions of variables Normal hours are defined as the hours worked during a normal week. This measure is not affected neither by irregular or unusual overtime, work for premium pay, regular pay, or no pay at all, nor by unusual absence or rest. 1 Overtime hours in a week is the time worked in addition to the hours worked during normal periods of work, and having a higher hourly wage than normal rates. Monthly earnings are the monthly payments associated with the normal duration of work. We use the national consumer price index to transform nominal earnings into real ones. The hourly wage is computed as the ratio of monthly earnings and normal hours of work. The worker is considered to lose his job in 2 situations. First, if he comes in our sample twice in the same year, in which case we consider he changed job. Second, if he disappears from our sample for at least one year. 3 Empirical analysis Table 1 shows that in the period October 1994-1996 on average 23% of the Portuguese workers had a normal workweek between 40 and 42 hours, while 27% had a workweek of more than 42 hours. So, half of the Portuguese workers was affected by the reduction in working hours. By October 1997 the percentage of workers working more than 40 hours decreased to 38 and by October 1998 only 9% of the workers worked more than 40 hours. We analyze the impact of the reduction of the workweek assuming that the policy change resembles a natural experiment. The treatment group consists of all individuals who worked more than 40 hours in October 1996; the control group consists of workers who worked 35-40 hours in October 1996. 2 1 The duration of work is neither self-reported as in Hunt (1999) nor refers to hours worked during a reference week as in Crépon, B. and F. Kramarz (2002). QP collects information on both normal and overtime hours done in the reference month; a posteriori we transform them into weekly hours. 2 We ignore the workers on part-time jobs (less than 35 hours) because they may have a different 4

To analyze the effects of the working week reduction we estimate the following equations: y it = βx it + δ 1 h 4042,i.d 96,it + δ 2 h 42p,i.d 96,it + δ 3 h 4042,i.d 97,it + δ 4 h 42p,i.d 97,it + ɛ it (1) where y, the dependent variable, represents changes in normal hours, overtime hours, hourly wages, monthly wages and employment status for individual i in the period from October in year t to October in year t + 1. Furthermore, x represents a vector of personal characteristics, β is a vector of parameters, the δ s are also parameters while ɛ is an error term. Included in x are d 96 and d 97, dummy variables indicating calendar years and h 4042 and h 42p dummy variables representing working hours categories, 40-42 hours per week and more than 42 hours per week respectively. Both categories are defined on the basis of the situation in October 1996, just before the introduction of the working time reduction. Assuming that the workers working less than 40 hours per week were not affected, the general calendar time effects are represented by the calendar year dummies and assuming that the differential development of the affected workers is represented by the working hours categories, the interaction terms represent the treatment effects. Our main interest concerns the short-run treatment effects represented by δ 1 and δ 2, and the long-run effects represented by δ 3 and δ 4. The relevant parameter estimates are presented in the upper part of Table 2. As expected normal hours go down substantially. Overtime hours increase in the first year, but in the second year they are approximately constant. Apparently, the initial reduction of normal working hours is partly compensated by an increase in overtime hours although this effect is small. Hourly wages for workers affected increase, leaving monthly earnings approximately constant. Somewhat surprisingly the affected workers in the category 40-42 hours have a lower probability to lose their job than non-affected workers. This may be explained by the flexibility that firms could use on this group of workers. So far, we ignored firm information. However, it might be that the treatment attachment to the labor market. To exploit the natural experiment character of the working time reduction we focus on workers that are close to the threshold of 40 hours per week. 5

effects are influenced by the firm share of workers that worked more than 40 hours per week. To investigate this possibility we add to equation (1) a number of interaction terms: 3 y it = βx it + (δ 1 + ω 1.n)h 4042,i.d 96,it + (δ 2 + ω 2.n)h 42p,i.d 96,it +(δ 3 + ω 3.n)h 4042,i.d 97,it + (δ 4 + ω 4.n)h 42p,i.d 97,it + ɛ it (2) where n represents the share of workers in the firm in worker i that worked more than 40 hours in October 1996. To the extent that the ω s differ from zero the composition of the workforce affects the treatment effect. As shown in the lower part of Table 2 ω 1 and ω 2 are often insignificantly different from zero indicating that in the short run the composition of the workforce is not very important. However, since the other ω-parameters often differ significantly from zero, in the long-run the treatment effect is influenced by the workforce composition. Table 3 gives an idea of the size of the firm effects by presenting treatment effects calculated on the basis of the parameter estimates of the lower part of Table 2. From these calculations we draw two conclusions. First, the treatment effects are bigger in absolute terms for workers who worked more than 42 hours per week, with one exception, the employment effect. Workers in the category 40-42 hours are less likely to lose their job than workers working fewer or more hours. Our second conclusion concerns the firm effects. Most of the treatment effects do not depend on the share of workers working 40 hours or more. Apparently, the firm effects are significant but quantitatively not very important. The only exception concerns the long term effects on employment. Somewhat surprisingly, the employment effects are more favorable the higher the share of workers working more than 40 hours. Our interpretation of this phenomenon is that there are negative spillover effects affecting the employment of workers that worked less than 40 hours per week. 3 And, we also added to the equation n i, n i.d 96,it, n i.d 97,it, to make sure that the ω-parameters represent the treatment effects. 6

4 Conclusions The reduction of working hours from 44 to 40 directly affected about half of all workers in Portugal since they were working more than 40 hours per week prior to the introduction of the new law in December 1996. Initially, the reduction of working hours was compensated by the use of overtime. Hourly wages of the affected workers increased, reducing their monthly wage only slightly. Workers in the category 40-42 hours were less likely to lose their job. The composition of the workforce in the firm seems to have influenced the employment of workers who worked less than 40 hours per week. P.M. We will investigate the employment effects in more detail taking in consideration job creation and job destruction into account. 7

References Andrews, M.J., T. Schank and R. Simmons (2005) Does worksharing work? Some empirical evidence from the IAB-establishment panel, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52, 141-176. Crépon, B. and F. Kramarz (2002) Employed 40 Hours or not-employed 39: lessons from the 1982 workweek reduction in France, Journal of Political Economy, 110, 1355-1389. Hunt, J. (1999) Has work-sharing worked in Germany?, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 117-148. Skuterud, M. (2007) Identifying the potential of work-sharing as a job-creation strategy, Journal of Labor Economics, 25, 265-287. Varejão, J. (2006), Work-sharing revisited - lessons from a natural experiment, Working paper, Faculdade de Economia do Porto. 8

Table 1: Proportion of workers in each hour category; normal working hours October 1994-1996 1997 1998 1994/6-97 1997-98 <35 11 8 11-3 3 35-40 37 54 80 17 26 40-42 22 23 8 1-15 >42 30 15 1-15 -14 Total 100 100 100 0 0 9

Table 2: Parameter estimates Normal Overtime Hourly Monthly Job hours hours wage earnings loss (%) (%) (%) a. Personal characteristics Short run effects h 4042 δ 1-1.52 (35.8)** 0.06 (2.6)** 3.65 (13.5)** -0.47 (1.6) -4.94 (13.6)** h 42p δ 2-3.58 (95.2)** 0.08 (4.8)** 8.26 (34.9)** -0.57 (2.2)** 0.01 (0.0) Long run effects h 4042 δ 3-0.88 (18.2)** 0.05 (2.2)** 2.92 (11.4)** 0.49 (1.7)* -5.73 (16.4)** h 42p δ 4-2.39 (55.3)** 0.02 (1.4) 5.88 (25.9)** 0.05 (0.2) -0.01 (0.3) R 2 0.085 0.0001 0.011 0.003 0.040 b. Personal and firm characteristics Short run effects h 4042 δ 1-2.49 (20.3)** 0.02 (0.2) 6.04 (7.1)** -1.37 (1.5) -3.63 (3.4)** h 4042.n ω 1-0.02 (0.1) -0.01 (0.1) -2.39 (2.1)** -1.49 (1.2) -3.34 (2.3)** h 42p δ 2-4.67 (35.9)** 0.00 (0.1) 9.96 (13.2)** -1.59 (1.9)* 0.32 (0.3) h 42p.n ω 2-0.21 (1.3) 0.03 (0.4) -1.33 (1.3) -1.41 (1.3) -1.97 (1.5) Long run effects h 4042 δ 3 0.04 (0.3) -0.11 (1.8)* 0.77 (1.1) 0.83 (1.0) -1.27 (1.3) h 4042.n ω 3-2.42 (12.7)** 0.21 (2.3)** 3.22 (3.3)** -3.65 (3.2)** -10.18 (7.3)** h 42p δ 4-1.93 (14.2)** -0.02 (0.5) 5.39 (8.1)** 0.65 (0.8) 5.24 (5.9)** h 42p.n ω 4-1.73 (9.3)** 0.04 (0.6) 0.75 (0.8) -4.02 (3.7)** -11.09 (8.9)** R 2 0.089 0.0002 0.014 0.003 0.040 F -statistic 166.4** 2.1** 20.4** 9.1** 18.2** Note: Ordinary least squares; first four columns based on 415,863 observations, the fifth column based on 536,997 observations; parameter estimates of control variables are not represented; control variables are dummy variables for working hours category (h 4042, h 42p ), calendar year dummies (d 96, d 97 ), industry (10 categories), region (7 categories), education (8 categories), wage (5 categories)(not included in the wage and earnings regressions), size of firm (4 categories) and tenure. The estimates in the lower part of the table also contain firm share of workers working more than 40 hours per week (n) and the interaction terms n.d 96, n.d 97. The population includes all full-time workers in the private sector working between 35 and 50 hours. absolute t-statistics based on robust standard errors in parentheses, The F -statistic concerns a comparison of the estimation results in the lower and the upper part of the table; a **/* indicates that the coefficient is different from zero at a 5%/10% level of significance. 10

Table 3: Treatment effects Weekly working hours 40-42 >42 % of workers affected 25 50 25 50 (1) (2) (3) (4) Short run effects Normal hours -2.5-2.5-4.7-4.8 Overtime hours 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Hourly wage (%) 5.4 4.8 9.6 9.3 Monthly earnings (%) -1.7-2.1-1.9-2.3 Job loss (%) -4.5-5.3-0.2-0.7 Long run effects Normal hours -0.6-1.2-2.4-2.8 Overtime hours -0.1-0.0-0.0 0.0 Hourly wage (%) 1.6 2.4 5.6 5.8 Monthly earnings (%) -0.1-1.0-0.4-1.4 Job loss (%) -3.8-6.4 2.5-0.3 Note: The % of workers affected concerns the workers that worked more than 40 hours per week in October 1996; the calculations are based on the parameter estimates of the lower part of Table 2. 11