Marginal willingness to pay (WTP). The maximum amount a consumer will spend for an extra unit of the good.

Similar documents
Monopolistic Markets. Causes of Monopolies

Chapter 8 Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Lecture 12. Monopoly

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

CH 15: Monopoly. Lecture

Monopolistic Markets. Regulation

- pure monopoly: only one seller of a good/service with no close substitutes

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

ECON 4100: Industrial Organization. Lecture 1- Introduction and a review of perfect competition versus monopoly

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3D

Monopoly. Chapter 15

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

iv. The monopolist will receive economic profits as long as price is greater than the average total cost

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Market structure 1: Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it cannot influence the price that is paid for its product.

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Question 1 A. In order to find optimal level of consumption and utility, we set MRS=MRT. These are found by:

Demand curve - using Game Results How much customers will buy at a given price Downward sloping - more demand at lower prices

Lecture 2: Market Structure I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

Market Power at Work: Computer Market Revisited

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

CHAPTER NINE MONOPOLY

Industrial Organisation ECON309

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester

Monopoly. Basic Economics Chapter 15. Why Monopolies Arise. Monopoly

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2009

ECON 102 Brown Final Exam Practice Exam Solutions

Monopoly and How It Arises

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Indicate whether the sentence or statement is True or False. Mark "A" if the statement is True or "B" if it is False.

Monopoly and How It Arises

The Four Main Market Structures

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

INTERPRETATION. SOURCES OF MONOPOLY (Related to P-R pp )

Perfectly Competitive Markets

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION.

micro2 first module Social costs of monopoly Price regulation Price regulation Price regulation overshooting Natural monopoly Market power part III

Chapter 11 Perfect Competition

Principles of. Economics. Week 6. Firm in Competitive & Monopoly market. 7 th April 2014

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik)

Industrial Organization

Lecture 10: Market Power and Monopoly

AP Microeconomics Review Session #3 Key Terms & Concepts

Unit 7. Firm behaviour and market structure: monopoly

Chapter 11. Monopoly. I think it s wrong that only one company makes the game Monopoly. Steven Wright

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Lecture 11: Market Power and Monopoly

PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N CASE FAIR OSTER. PEARSON Prepared by: Fernando Quijano w/shelly Tefft

Lecture 2: Market Structure Part I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

11.1 Monopoly Profit Maximization

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key. Instruction:

Monopoly CHAPTER 15. Henry Demarest Lloyd. Monopoly is business at the end of its journey. Monopoly 15. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Lecture 11: Market Power and Monopoly

MONOPOLY. Characteristics

Firms in competitive markets: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Average Cost 0 20 NA NA NA a) Is this a short run or long run information on cost? Why?

13 C H A P T E R O U T L I N E

4. Which of the following statements about marginal revenue for a perfectly competitive firm is incorrect? A) TR

AGEC 105 Homework Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

Review. 1. Production function - Types of production functions - Marginal productivity - Returns to scale

Principles of Microeconomics ECONOMICS 103. Topic 8: Imperfect Competition. Single price monopoly. Monopolistic competition.

14.54 International Trade Lecture 17: Increasing Returns to Scale

I. Introduction to Monopolies

QUIZ 4 VERSION A "Introduction to Antitrust"

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

EconS Monopoly - Part 2

Marginal Cost. Average Cost 0 20 NA NA NA a) Is this a short run or long run information on cost? Why?

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3C Answer Key

Economics. Monopoly. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Vance Ginn & Ron Cronovich C H A P T E R P R I N C I P L E S O F

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

CH 14. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Handout 1: Monopolistic Competition and International Trade

Review Chapters 1 & 2

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Name (Print in BLOCK letters) FIRST HOUR EXAM ECN 4350/6350

Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition Chapter 8 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

Networks, Telecommunications Economics and Strategic Issues in Digital Convergence. Prof. Nicholas Economides. Spring 2006

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

Perfect Competition CHAPTER14

Econ 300: Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring 2014 Final Exam Study Guide 1

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Quiz 10. For questions 1-9, consider firms using a technology with cost and marginal cost functions:

Tutorial 3 - Sessions 6to8:

c) Will the monopolist described in (b) earn positive, negative, or zero economic profits? Explain your answer.

Course informa-on. Final exam. If you have a conflict, go to the Registrar s office for a form to bring to me

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

micro2 first module Basic assumptions of PC 2. Product homogeneity 1. Large number of firms Profit maximization in general 3. Free entry and exit

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

Transcription:

McPeak Lecture 10 PAI 723 The competitive model. Marginal willingness to pay (WTP). The maximum amount a consumer will spend for an extra unit of the good. As we derived a demand curve for an individual s preferences, we can interpret the demand curve tracing out the consumer s marginal willingness to pay at different levels of consumption. Consumer surplus (CS) the monetary difference between what the consumer is willing to pay for a given quantity of good and what the good costs. [show graph] Relies on the fact that the demand curve is downward sloping and that the price for purchasing is the same for all units. The area under the demand curve and above the price line. The area below the price line is expenditure (p times q).

If price increases and demand is constant, consumer surplus falls. The decrease in consumer surplus for a given price increase will be larger: The greater the initial expenditure on the good The less elastic is the demand curve. Producer surplus. The difference between the minimum amount necessary for the seller to be willing to produce the good and the selling price. [show graph] Producer surplus is revenue minus variable cost. Since profit is revenue minus cost, the difference between profit and producer surplus is fixed cost in the short run, and there is no difference in the long run.

The maximum societal welfare comes from maximizing consumer surplus plus producer surplus. Why are there gains to trade? [show graph of when quantity is too low] [ show graph of when quantity is too high]

Monopoly. There is only one supplier of a good for which there is no close substitute. How can such a thing happen? 1) Technical reasons. a. Economies of scale. A natural monopoly exists when one firm can produce at a lower cost than several firms producing the same good and total output level (AC is downward sloping over the feasible range of output). 2) Legal reasons. a. Patents. b. Franchises c. Legal barriers. 3) Anti-competitive behavior Marginal revenue as you recall is the change in revenue divided by the change in q. In the competitive model, the price taking firm faced a marginal revenue of p, since price did not change with the output level of the firm. Now, the monopoly firm faces the entire demand curve. This is downward sloping, so by picking a level of q, there is also an associated p (the whole demand curve is defined by (p,q) pairs).

[show graph] 30 20 Price Discrete MR Bisection MR 10 0 1 3 5 7 9-10 11 13 15 17 19 21 23-20 -30 Discrete MR Bisection MR Price TR 1 23 23 2 22 44 21 20 3 21 63 19 18 4 20 80 17 16 5 19 95 15 14 6 18 108 13 12 7 17 119 11 10 8 16 128 9 8 9 15 135 7 6 10 14 140 5 4 11 13 143 3 2 12 12 144 1 0 13 11 143-1 -2 14 10 140-3 -4 15 9 135-5 -6 16 8 128-7 -8 17 7 119-9 -10 18 6 108-11 -12 19 5 95-13 -14 20 4 80-15 -16 21 3 63-17 -18 22 2 44-19 -20 23 1 23-21 -22 24 0 0-23 -24

Note there is a difference between calculating the MR from one observation to the next compared to the MR at a given point. Bisection rule. Marginal revenue for a linear demand curve defined by: p=a-b*q is MR=a-2*b*q. For a linear demand curve, the marginal revenue curve bisects the demand curve. Why? Well demand is (24-q)=p in the example above, and we know p*q is revenue. So p*q is the same as (24-q)*q, or 24q-q 2. The marginal of this is the derivative with respect to q, or 24-2q. The competitive firms choose q given p. Here, the monopoly chooses p and q based on information about the entire demand curve. It is making its choices in the awareness that increasing q decreases price, and that marginal revenue is a function of the quantity they pick.

Profit maximization steps for the monopolist. 1) Identify q * that determines where MR(q * )= MC(q * ) 2) Calculate what is the implied p * for that q * from the demand curve. 3) Calculate profit which is defined by p * times q * minus cost at q * / look at p * compared to AC(q * ). 4) Shut down (produce q=0) if p * is less than average variable cost (SR) or average cost (LR). Simple example. Demand is defined by p=24-q, and total cost is defined by TC=q 2, so that MC = 2*q (you will be given this, not be expected to derive it). If we know that p=24-q, we can use the bisection rule to define MR=24-2*q, since R=p*q, =24q- q 2. Where is MR=MC? Where is 24-2*q=2*q, 24=4q, or q=6. At a quantity of six, I plug back into the demand curve and find that p=24-6, or 18. [note: a common mistake is to plug back into MR curve to solve for price]

Profit for me at this point is revenue minus cost, or 18*6-6*6, or 72. To make life easier on us, I will tend to give you a constant marginal cost, but the procedure is the same.

How does this differ from a perfectly competitive market in terms of outcome? If we use the given demand curve and recall that the MC curve traces out the supply curve in a perfectly competitive market, we find: 24-q=2q where supply and demand meet at a (p,q) pair, which solves for q * =8, implying that p * =16. [show on graph] There is a deadweight loss of monopoly. The market structure makes it so that transactions that would occur in a perfectly competitive market do no occur, thus reducing total societal welfare. Note efficiency / equity distinction.

Now we can modify the example. Change cost, so that TC=2*q, MC=AC=2. Keep demand at p=24-q. This is the horizontal supply curve discussed last class. For the monopolist, MR = MC, so 24-2q=2. This solves for q m =11, which is where p m =13. In perfect competition by contrast, 24-q=2 when q pc =22, so that p pc =2. CS with perfect competition is the area above the competition price line and below the demand curve, a triangle. When q=0, p=24 by the demand curve. So we have (p when q=0 - p competition )*(q competition )*(1/2)=(24-2)*22*(1/2)=242 CS with monopoly is the area above the monopoly price line and below the demand curve, a triangle. (p when q=0 - p monopoly )*(q monopoly )*(1/2)=(24-13)*11*(1/2)=60 ½. PS with perfect competition is the area below the price line and above the supply curve = 0. PS with monopoly is the area defined by: (p monopoly -mc)*(q monopoly ), or (13-2)*11 =121 Total welfare under competition is 0+242=242 Total welfare under monopoly is 121+60 ½, or 181.5

This illustrates a general result total welfare is reduced under monopoly market structure compared to a perfectly competitive market. So what can we do about a monopoly? 1) Optimal price regulation, which sets a price ceiling. What would the equilibrium market clearing price quantity pair be if the market was competitive? Set the price ceiling at this level, so that the demand curve facing the monopolist is modified to have a flat spot, then decrease after passing to the right of this p, q pair.

[show graph when the price ceiling is set too low]

This is very difficult to get right if you don t know the actual demand and cost curves. Also may have a natural monopoly that is defined by decreasing average costs over the total range of feasible output levels. This means MC is below AC over this range as well, since if AC is downward sloping, that means MC is below it. A policy that sets the price ceiling based on the marginal cost curve would make it better for the monopolist to shut down rather than produce (thus losing whatever consumer and producer surplus we are getting under the monopoly situation).

Anti-Trust Laws Beyond regulating prices, monopolies are prohibited by anti-trust laws and can be regulated through policy. There are anti-trust laws prohibiting actions that are likely to restrain competition. Sherman Act (1890) - Section one prohibits contracts, combinations, or conspiracies in restraint of trade. - Example: agreeing to restrict output or fix price. - Includes both explicit and implicit arrangements.

- For example, parallel conduct, in which firm B always follows firm A s pricing, is illegal, even if there is no formal agreement. We will match any competitors lowest price? - Section two makes it illegal to monopolize or attempt to monopolize a market. Clayton Act (1914) - The Sherman Act made it clear that monopolies were illegal, but was unclear about other practices. Thus in 1914, the Clayton Act was passed. - The Clayton Act helped to clarify the Sherman Act. - The Clayton Act prohibits actions that restrain competition. - For example, it prohibits mergers that substantially lessen competition Enforcement: - It also prohibits predatory pricing setting prices below cost to drive competitors out of business. 1. Federal Trade Commission - Created in 1914 to set standards dealing with anti-trust. 2. Department of Justice's Anti-Trust Division - Interpretation of laws may vary as political power changes, as it is part of the executive branch. 3. Private legal proceedings