Unit 9: Externalities

Similar documents
Unit 9: Externalities

Unit 8: Imperfect Competition II oligopoly and monopolistic competition

CH 21: Externalities & Market Failure. Lecture

Externalities, Property Rights and Public Goods

Externalities, Property Rights and Public Goods

Area VI. Area II + IV + VI. Area II. Area I + III + V. Area III + V

Answer each of the questions below. Round off values to one decimal place where necessary.

Monopolistic Markets. Regulation

Externalities and the Environment

Economics 325: Public Economics Section A01 University of Victoria Midterm Examination #1 VERSION 1

EXTERNALITIES. Problems and Applications

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

Lecture 6. Externalities. 1 gkaplanoglou public finance

Ec 11 Caltech Lecture 1 Notes (revised: version 2.0)

Lecture 2: Market Structure I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

Externalities C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

Lecture 12: Externalities and Public Goods

Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities

Externalities. 5 Microeconomics ACTIVITY 5-2

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

Economics 101 Fall 2013 Answers to Homework #6 Due Tuesday, Dec 10, 2013

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination

Lecture 2: Market Structure Part I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

Additional Questions. Externalities and Public Goods.

Outline. Introduction. ciency. Excise Tax. Subsidy 2/29

MARKETS AND THE ENVIRONMENT. Review of Market System

Lecture 5: Externalities

Econ 325: Environmental and Natural Resource Economics Fall 2007 Problem Set 2. Due in class: Tuesday October 2, 2007

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

Do not remove any pages or add any pages. No additional paper is supplied

2. THEORIES OF EXTERNALITIES

Top 10 Most Common Errors AP Economics 2011

Market Failure 24 SEP 2009

A situation in which the free-market system fails to satisfy society s wants.

Topic 3. Welfare theorems. Dead Weight Loss for externalities. Dead Weight Loss for public goods. Dead Weight Loss for tragedy of the commons

Market structure 1: Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it cannot influence the price that is paid for its product.

1 Competitive Equilibrium

ECON 5113 Microeconomic Theory

Topic 10: Price Discrimination

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

1. Individuals OWN resources and determine what to produce, how to produce, and who gets it. 2. The opportunity to makeprofit gives people INCENTIVE

I. An Introduction to Externalities and Market Failures. II. Externalities. EC 441: Handout 5A: Externalities and Solutions

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies

The homework is due on Wednesday, December 7 at 4pm. Each question is worth 0.8 points.

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

UNIVERSITY OF CALGARY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 357 (01) PROBLEM SET 4. Dr. J. Church Fall 2011

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Quiz 10. For questions 1-9, consider firms using a technology with cost and marginal cost functions:

TUTORIAL 10 Welfare. Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring Massimo Scotti

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 5: Externalities. External costs and benefits

Copyright 2016 Pearson Canada Inc. 5-1 EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY. After studying this chapter, you will be able to:

All but which of the following are true in the long-run for a competitive firm that maximizes profits?

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 7 - EXTERNALITIES.

General Equilibrium for the Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/9 (Lecture 9, Micro Theory I)

Micro Problem Set 2 WCC Winter 2015

Lecture 11. Firms in competitive markets

Externality Essentials Revised

Downloaded for free from 1

ESSENTIAL KNOWLEDGE. Names: Microeconomics Unit 1: Basic Economic Concepts. Scarcity. Opportunity Costs. Economic systems (i.e. market and command)

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 2

Pricing with Market Power

Exercise 2. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Exercise

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

a) I, II and III. b) I c) II and III only. d) I and III only. 2. Refer to the PPF diagram below. PPF

EconS Monopoly - Part 2

Economics 381/Environmental Studies 312 Review Assignment

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Environmental Economic Theory No. 10 (26 December 2017)

A01 325: #1 VERSION 2 SOLUTIONS

Market Design: Externalities

Midterm 2 Sample Questions. Use the demand curve diagram below to answer the following THREE questions.

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 3

Chapter 17. Externalities, Open Access, and Public Goods

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

Perfect Competition Definition

Luca Spataro Lectures 2. Public Economics. Efficiency (Ref. Myles 1995, ch. 2) March 2015, University of Pisa

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Q K L MPL APL FC VC TC AFC AVC ATC MC $ $ $40 $ $550 $10

AS Economics Governement Intervention and government failure

Ch. 9 LECTURE NOTES 9-1

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Getting ready for the AP Macroeconomics Exam Lesson 2

To do today. Efficiency MB and MC Consumer surplus Producer surplus Deadweight loss. Theories of fairness

CH 15: Monopoly. Lecture

Chapter 16: Equilibrium

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics Homework 4

q p(q) ε d (q) = dp(q) dq C(q) = cq + F. = 1 q q + m max

Introduction to Economics II: Producer Theory

Micro Semester Review Name:

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Equilibrium and E ciency

Econ 381/ES312 Midterm 2: Sample Questions

Transcription:

Unit 9: Externalities Prof. Antonio Rangel February 19, 2014 1 Public bads 1.1 What is an externality? An externality arises when the actions of one economic actor a ect DIRECTLY the utility function or production function of another economic actor (i.e. not through a market transaction) Examples: E ect on Direct/Market? others? Roommate plays loud rock music X Direct Consumption of pharmaceuticals contaminates X Direct fish stocks Microsoft hires 10,000 new software X Market engineers Company invents drug that makes people 10x smarter X Market First two examples are externalities since they directly a ect others. Last two examples are not externalities since they impact on others take place through the market 1.2 Public bads Public bads are externalties that are: 1

Negative Non-targeted (i.e. a ect either all consumers, or all firms, or both) Examples: CO 2 emmissions and global warming Noise polution Poverty, when people care about others well-being Simple model: 3goods:q, m, e, wheree denotes the level of the externality (e.g. pollution) Each unit of q consumed generates 1 unit of e N identical consumers, with utility U(q, m, e) =B(q)+m D(e), with D 0 > 0,D 00 0, and 0 F identical firms, with CRS production function, so that c(q) =µq Market is competitive Market equilibrium: Consumers maximize utility and firms maximize profit, taking as given the level of externality Prices adjust so that q-market clears Consumer s problem: max B(q) pq D(e) q 0 Since e is taken as a constant by the consumer, the demand function for good q is as it was without externalities Firm s problem: max pq µq q 0 2

As before: 8 >< 0 if p<µ q S (p) = anything if p = µ >: 1 if p>µ Optimal allocations: Optimal allocation given by solution to: " X max B(q i ) D X!# q i q 1...q N 0 i i X µq i i FOCs: RESULT: q B 0 opt ND 0 (q opt ) N {z } Marginal social benefit = µ {z} Marginal social cost (note that, given symmetry, everyone consumes the same amount of q) q >q opt DWL > 0 Accounting recipe/convention for where to place the externalities: Externalities that a ect utility go into MSB Externalities that a ect production costs go into MSC 1.3 A more complex example Model: All externalities are firm-to-firm Each unit of q produced generates one unit of pollution e Aggregate demand function: qmkt D (p) =1000 p 3

10 identical firms with cost function c(q j )=5q 2 j + eq j,sothat MC(q j e) =10q j + e Firm s problem: max q 0 pq (5q 2 + eq), with e taken as given MR = p, MC =10q + e =) qj S (p) = p e 10 =) qmkt S (p) =p e Market equilibrium: Equilibrium conditions: 1. Prices adjust so that q D mkt (p )=q S mkt (p ) 2. e = q S mkt (p ) Supply function plus (2) imply that in equilibrium q S mkt (p) = p 2 Then the market clearing condition is given by 1000 p = p 2 It follows that Optimality: q opt given by MSB = MSC MSB = MPB = p D mkt =1000 q MSC: p = 2000 3,q = 1000 3 cost function convex, so optimal to split production equally across firms q Total social cost: TSC(q) = 10c =10 5 q2 + q q = 10 100 10 3 2 q2 =) MSC =3q FOCs: MSB = MSC =) 1000 q =3q =) q opt =250 4

Marginal social cost vs. marginal private cost MSC = 3q MPC = p S 1000 mkt (q) =q + e = q + 3 See equilibrium and DWL diagram in the video lectures 1.4 Why does the FWT fail? Market forces leads to an allocation at which MPB = p = MPC At optimal allocation we have that MSB = MSC Without externalities we have that MSB = MPB and MSC = MPC. Thus, the invisible hand of the market leads to an allocation at which MSB = MPB = p = MPC = MSC,whichisoptimal With externalities, MPB > MSB and/or MPC < MSC Given this, market induces an equilibrium allocation at which MSB < MSC,whichimpliesthatq >q opt 2 Corrective policies for public bads 2.1 Pigouvian taxation Policy: Tax imposed on every consumer or firm generating an externality on others Tax equal to total marginal externality at optimum Tax revenue returned to consumers in lump-sum transfer RESULT: Pigouvian tax system leads to an optimal equilibrium allocation Why? 5

Look at basic model of public bads Externality from consumers to consumers N consumers with U(q, m, e) =B(q)+m F firms with MC = µ N consumers D(e) Pigouvian tax: = ND 0 (q opt )imposedonconsumers Consumer s problem: with D(e) takenasgiven. FOC: B 0 = p + max q 0 B(q) pq q D(e) In equilibrium, p = µ =) B 0 = µ + ND 0 (q opt ) q tot N This is the same as optimality condition, so qtot N Intuition: = qopt N Optimality requires an allocation at which: MSB = MSC q q MPB ND 0 MPC = µ Utility maximization leads consumers to set B 0 = p Profit maximization leads firms to set p = µ B 0 = MPB and chosen to be ND 0 (q opt ), which implies that the invisbile hand of the market with the tax induces an equilibrium allocation at which the optimality condition is satisfied Remarks: 1. Optimal Pigouvian tax restores e ciency BUT feasible only if the goverment has all of the information needed to calculate ND 0 (q opt ) 2. Model assumes everyone produces the same marginal damage, otherwise more complicated tax system is required. 3. Policy works if tax is imposed either to firms or consumers 4. Policy doesn t work if imposed on both consumers and firms 6

2.2 Permit markets Policy: Government creates = q opt units of permits Each permit allows owner to produce/consume 1 unit of q (which is the good generating the externality) Individuals/firms who exceed allocated permits pay 1 fine (so that, no cheating in equilibrium) Consumers/firms allowed to trade permits freely Two versions of the policy: 1. Permits sold by government 2. Permits are freely allocated RESULT: If = q opt,thenthepermitpolicyleadstoane cient allocation. Furthermore, in equilibrium permits trade at a price equal to the optimal Pigouvian tax (i.e., p = ) Why? Again, consider simple model of public bads Look at case in which permits freely allocated Consumer s problem: max B(q) pq p (r endowed i ) q 0,r where r is the number of permits bought, sold This is equivalent where p is price of permits. FOCs: max q 0 B(q) (p + p )q, B 0 = p + p 7

Why? In equilibrium, p = µ (by CRS cost function of firms) q-market: demand curve with permits is demand curve without permits shifted down by p. Then, if p = ND 0 (q opt ), the inverse demand function with permits = MSB, and thus in equilibrium q = q opt r-market: inverse demand curve for permits is equal to demand curve for q without permits, shifted down by p = µ. Supplyfixed at = q opt. From the FOCs of the utility maximization problem we get that p = ND0 (q opt ). Intuition: cost of permits acts as a per-unit tax, but now the size of the tax is determined endogenously in the permit market Now consider the case in which permits are sold by government Government sells permits in the permit market Permit endownment a ects the wealth of consumers (since they can sell the permits in the market), but it has no e ect on their demand functions So equilibrium is same as before: p,p,q Only di erence is that now policy raises revenue EQUIVALENCE RESULT: Optimal Pigouvian tax system (with revenue returned by lump-sum transfers to consumers) is equivalent to the optimal permit market with permits sold (with revenue returned by same lump-sum transfers) Why? In Pigouvian taxation the government sets the price of the externality (i.e., = ND 0 (q opt )) and the market finds q opt In the permit market the government sets the quantity to = q opt,andthemarketfindspriceofexternalityp = ND 0 (q opt ) 8

For both, total revenue raised = q opt ND 0 (q opt ), and thus can support identical lump-sum transfers to consumers Remarks: 1. Permit markets can restore e ciency, but government needs to know q opt 2. Permit markets vs. command-and-control/direct regulation: Commandand-control requires knowing what everyone should consume and produce, not just optimal total quantity. Thus, permit markets require less information to be able to design optimal policy. 3. System optimal only if = q opt 3 Public goods Key features: Positive externalities to other consumers/firms Non-rivalry in consumption (everyone can benefit from positive externality) Examples: Basic research & development LoJack anti-theft system Network externalities in consumption (HBO, facebook) Simple model: N consumers, each with utility U(q, m, e) =B(q)+m + G(e), 0measuresthestrengthofexternality,G 0 > 0,G 00 apple 0 good q produced by firms with constant marginal cost of production µ 9

RESULT: q <q opt ;i.e.,thereisunderproductionofthepublicgood. See video lecture for graphical analysis of equilibrium and DWL Corrective policy: Pigouvian subsidies Policy: 1. Subsidize sale/purchase of good q with subsidy = NG 0 (q opt ) 2. Subsidy financed with lump-sum taxes RESULT: Optimal Pigouvian subsidy system restores optimality Corrective policy: Government provision Consider extreme case in which individuals derive no private benefit from consuming the good generating the externality: U(q, m, e) =0+m + Market equilibrium: q =0 Policy: Buy q opt and finance w/ lump-sum taxes. This restores optimality Goverment provision can t restore full optimality if lump-sum taxes are not feasible G(e) 4 Summary With externalities, first welfare theorem fails: With public bads, overprovision of good generating the externality With public goods, underprovision of the good generating the externality Corrective policy for public bads: Pigouvian taxes: =marginaldamageatq opt Permit market: = q opt Corrective policy for public goods: Pigouvian subsidies: =marginalpositiveexternalityatq opt Direct government provision (financed with taxes) 10