Frank P Maier-Rigaud. Behavioural versus Structural Remedies in EU Competition Law

Similar documents
The University of Oxford Centre for Competition Law and Policy

Enforcement of EU competition policy

Merger Remedies: Principles, Incentives, and Effectiveness. John Kwoka Economics Department Northeastern University, Boston September 2014

Introduction. The findings. The wider context ANTITRUST

The New Approach of the European Commission to Competition Cases in the Energy Sectors Case COMP/ RWE Gas Foreclosure

Session on International Enforcement Perspectives Federal Trade Commission and Antitrust Division Hearings on Section 2 of the Sherman Act

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case FI/2013/1498

Discussion Points. Presented by the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) to the OECD Competition Committee

On the Art 82 enforcement priorities Effects on consumer welfare

DRAFT COMMISSION GUIDELINES ON THE ASSESSMENT OF NON- HORIZONTAL MERGERS

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

Undue discrimination by SMP providers How Ofcom will investigate potential contraventions on competition grounds of Requirements not to unduly

ICN Recommended Practices for Merger Analysis and Model ICN Guides. MICHELE PACILLO, AGCM ITALY MWG Workshop Washington DC February 16, 2017

EFTA SURVEILLANCE AUTHORITY

The past two decades of international experience

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of (Text with EEA relevance)

Application of the Actual Costs Saved and Avoided Costs Saved Standards

Regulating oligopolies in telecoms: the new European Commission guidelines

Competition Law Conference IBA/ KBA Seoul 28 April 2011

ROMANIA S EXPERIENCE ON THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE COMPETITION AUTHORITY AND THE SECTOR REGULATORS

Measuring exclusionary effects under Article 82

The law and economics of rebates

Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation

Remedies in EU Merger Control

Article 101 (3) TFEU

Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles. A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group

RECOMMENDATIONS. (Text with EEA relevance) (2014/710/EU)

Abuse of Dominance Under Art 102 Towards multiple standards?

Prohibition of the abuse of a dominant position

Economic Analysis for Merger Remedies. Bruce Lyons

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Notice. Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty (2004/C 101/08)

ProbusBNW Dialogue Dinner. London - 18/09/2003

Pubic Monopolies, Concessions and Competition Law and Policies

Analysis of the effects of a merger

Comments on Chapter IV Part I Controller and processor 25/08/2015 Page 1

THE TYRANNY OF MARKET SHARES: INCORPORATING SURVEY-BASED EVIDENCE INTO MERGER ANALYSIS

Merger remedies in the UK Roundtable 1

Agency Name: The Office for the Protection of Competition, Czech Republic Date: 17 th October 2008 Tying & Bundled Discounting

If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an to

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

ECN RECOMMENDATION ON INVESTIGATIVE POWERS, ENFORCEMENT MEASURES AND SANCTIONS IN THE CONTEXT OF INSPECTIONS AND REQUESTS FOR INFORMATION

BT s response to Ofcom consultation document. Price Rises in Fixed Term Contracts

Refusal to Supply and Article 82. Damien Geradin Universities of Liège and Tilburg, and College of Europe, Bruges Howrey, LLP

Conglomerate and vertical mergers in the light of the Tetra Judgement Götz DRAUZ, Directorate General Competition, Deputy Director-General

First impressions on the Revised US and UK Merger Guidelines

New revenue guidance Implementation in the technology sector

EDITORIAL THE ARTICLE 82 DISCUSSION PAPER: A MISSED OPPORTUNITY SIMON BISHOP AND PHILIP MARSDEN

Non-price Effects of Mergers - Note by Canada

Official Journal of the European Union L 344/65 RECOMMENDATIONS COMMISSION

Agency Name: Office of Competition and Consumer Protection, Poland Date: December 16, 2008 Tying & Bundled Discounting

- Material influence - Level of shareholding - Plus factors. - Cooperative / concentrative JV - R&D - Extraterritoriality

COMPETITION LAW AND STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES Contribution from Sweden

APPENDIX 1 COMMENTS ON EACH QUESTION

Case T-306/01. Ahmed Ali Yusuf and Al Barakaat International Foundation v Council of the European Union and Commission of the European Communities

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

State aid under EU law

BirdLife Position on Species Protection under the EU Birds and Habitats Directives

Mobile call termination market review Ofcom. 4 June Response by Telefonica UK Ltd

CESR S CONSULTATION MIFID REVIEW CLIENT CATEGORISATION FRENCH BANKING FEDERATION S RESPONSE

II. General Policies

Case T-342/99. Airtours plc v Commission of the European Communities

EU Competition law and Energy: Recent cases and issues

on the conditions for the application of FDA UIOLI pursuant to paragraph a) - d) of the CMP Guidelines

Predatory Pricing. 2. Please list your jurisdiction s criteria for an abuse of dominance/monopolization based on predatory pricing.

Agency Name: Superintendencia de Industria y Comercio Date:

BEREC study on Oligopoly Analysis and Regulation

Questionnaire on the Electronic Money Directive (2000/46/EC)

RECOMMENDATIONS. (Text with EEA relevance) (2014/897/EU)

Q. 1: Should the PRIPs initiative focus on packaged investments? Please justify or explain your answer.

Tightening Up Refusal to Supply - a comment on the Article 82 Discussion Paper

Response to CESR s consultation on Inducements under MIFID (06-687)

Eric Olson Student Fellow Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies LOYOLA UNIVERSITY CHICAGO SCHOOL OF LAW

E U R O P E A N E C O N O M I C A R E A

ICN Merger Working Group Project on Remedies in Merger Review: Interim Report, March 2015

Independent Regulators Group Rail. IRG Rail

Procurement Guide Part 1

Abuses of dominant position in the Commission s Guidance and the case-law of the Court of Justice and the General Court

Can Analysis of Dominance be taken UPPwards? Possible Lessons from Mergers

QUESTION 80. Trademarks and consumer protection

BEREC views on Article 74 of the draft Code Co-investment and very high-capacity (VHC) networks

Unless otherwise stated, the questions concern unilateral conduct by a dominant firm or firm with significant market power.

Joven Liew Jia Wen Industrial Economics I Notes. What is competition?

Abuse of Dominance in Energy Markets

ROADMAP. A. Context, Subsidiarity Check and Objectives

Effective enforcement by National Competition Authorities

CPI Antitrust Chronicle November 2013 (1)

GUIDELINES ON ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE (only the Italian text is authentic)

LOOKING BEYOND THE DIRECT EFFECTS OF THE WORK OF COMPETITION AUTHORITIES: DETERRENCE AND MACROECONOMIC IMPACT

Citation Osaka University Law Review. 42 P.1.

Implementation of EU Postal Legislation. A guide to the transposition of EC Directive 97/67/EC as amended by Directive 2008/6/EC

Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39

(Text with EEA relevance) (2009/C 45/02) I. INTRODUCTION

12. A Sustainable Murray Darling Basin: The legal challenges

1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration

On Fairness and Welfare: The Objectives of Competition Policy (Comment)

Big Data and Competition Law Preliminary thoughts

An Economic Approach to Article 82

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case ES/2013/1466

BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2017/1960

Transcription:

Frank P Maier-Rigaud * Behavioural versus Structural Remedies in EU Competition Law and it will fall out as in a complication of diseases, that by applying a remedy to one sore, you will provoke another; and that which removes the one ill symptom produces others (Thomas More, Utopia, p 40) 1. Introduction The effectiveness of competition law in general and any competition authorities enforcement efforts in particular depends as much on the actual implementation of the adopted decisions via remedies as on the investigation of the infringement and the finding of liability. The purpose of this chapter is to discuss the role of structural remedies in EU competition law in a non-merger context. The focus is on the distinction between behavioural and structural remedies, the general role of structural remedies and the scope for implementing structural remedies from a legal and economic perspective. 1 The motivation for this discussion stems from the curious asymmetry between the relatively frequent use of structural remedies in merger cases on the one hand and their sparse use in antitrust and in particular abuse of dominance cases on the other hand. * Director and Head of NERA s European Competition Economics Group; Professor, Department of Economics and Quantitative Methods at the I É SEG School of Management Paris and the Universit é Catholique de Lille. The author would like to thank Marc Pirrung and Lars Kj ø lbye for highly instructive discussions on the topic of remedies throughout the years. Sources referenced in the text and in the following footnotes are listed in full at the end of this chapter. 1 General introductions to remedies under Article 101 and 102 TFEU can be found in Lowe and Maier-Rigaud (2008) as well as Hellstr ö m et al (2009). For the merger context, some of the relevant papers are the ex post evaluation exercise carried out by DG COMP (European Commission, 2005) and summarised in Kopke (2005) and the notice on merger remedies (European Commission, 2008). See also L é v ê que and Shelanski (2003) and Davies and Lyons (2007). There seems to be a trend towards behavioural remedies also in merger control, at least in the US. See Kwoka and Moss (2011).

208 Frank P Maier-Rigaud This asymmetry seems mainly due to the legal perception that there exists a strong presumption that structural remedies are disproportionate 2 in a nonmerger context and that in implicit recognition of their highly intrusive nature, Article 7(1) of Regulation 1/2003 makes clear that structural remedies are only to be employed in exceptional circumstances From this, it follows that three cumulative conditions must be satisfied before structural remedies may be imposed : (1) structural remedies are a remedy of last resort, ie behavioural remedies would be insufficient; (2) structural remedies must be effective; and (3) structural remedies must be proportionate. 3 As stated by Wind (2005: 659), Priority is given to behavioural remedies, as structural remedies are used only if it is not possible to use the first. As will be argued below, this legal interpretation is doubtful, but from a narrow economic point of view it is surprising to find that a suspected (!) substantial lessening of competition that may not even amount to dominance is presumably treated more fiercely and rigorously than the abuse of an already existing dominant position. As long as the abuse of a dominant position has a more significant anticompetitive impact than the projected lessening of competition of a therefore prohibited merger (or the avoided effects due to a partial divestiture in the context of an approval), such an asymmetry may be incompatible with an economic effects-based approach to competition policy. As a result, it would seem reasonable to make use of the full spectrum of remedies available to the Commission in resolving competition problems in antitrust cases which may benefit not only the consumers and companies harmed by these infringements but ultimately even the perpetrators. This chapter sets out to contribute to the clarification of the role of structural remedies from a competition policy perspective, but also from the perspective of the concerned companies on which such measures would be made binding. In addition to the economic arguments that would speak in favour of rehabilitating structural remedies in dominance cases, it is argued that the Commission clearly has the legal means of following such a more economic approach in the choice of remedies to be imposed. By clarifying this latter point, the chapter contributes to lifting the myth of a primacy of behavioural over structural remedies that does not withstand scrutiny of a detailed analysis of the relevant wording of Regulation 1/2003. 4 2 O Donoghue and Padilla (2006: 683) and identically in (2013: 887). 3 O Donoghue and Padilla (2006: 735). The test proposed on these and earlier pages has already been criticised in Adam and Maier-Rigaud (2009: 142f). Unfortunately, these parts have not been updated and are reprinted identically in O Donoghue and Padilla (2013: 946). 4 See Maier-Rigaud (2012), where some of the key arguments made here were already presented.

Behavioural versus Structural Remedies in EU Competition Law 209 2. Behavioural versus structural remedies There is no generally accepted definition of structural remedies in the literature, and the discussion of structural remedies has typically focused only on a subset of cases where such remedies could be imposed, namely in merger control. Davies and Lyons (2007) propose a clean break principle in order to distinguish between structural and non-structural remedies. According to their definition, a structural remedy is one that neither requires ongoing monitoring by the enforcement authority nor establishes ongoing links between firms. A structural remedy is thus characterised as a one-off measure, as opposed to a measure creating an ongoing relationship between a firm and a regulator or with other firms. This follows the ICN Merger Remedies Review Project Group (ICN, 2005) that characterises structural remedies as one-off remedies that intend to restore the competitive structure of the market. Another approach, focussing on property rights, is formulated by Motta et al (2003). The approach is based on the notion that structural remedies modify the allocation of property rights and create new firms: they include divestiture of an entire ongoing business, or partial divestiture. 5 This is contrasted to non-structural remedies, which set constraints on the merged firms property rights: they might consist of engagements by the merging parties not to abuse of certain assets available to them. They might also consist of contractual arrangements such as compulsory licensing or access to intellectual property. 6 Lévêque (2000) finally considers the dichotomy of structural versus behavioural remedies as over-simplifying and confusing, and proposes instead to characterise remedies along two different dimensions: first, as to their target, such as a firm s environment, output or property rights; and second, as to whether they change the incentives of the addressee to behave in a certain way or whether they prescribe certain behaviour. In his terminology, economic instruments lead to a change in incentives that make an infringement of antitrust rules a non-profitable strategy, whereas regulatory instruments do not change these incentives and therefore need monitoring and enforcement (command-and-control regime). Council Regulation 1/2003 proposes the terms structural and behavioural remedy without clear definition. In the present context, a structural remedy is defined as a measure that effectively changes the structure of the firm by a transfer of property rights regarding tangible or intangible assets, including the transfer of an entire business unit, that does not lead to any ongoing 5 Motta et al (2003: 108). 6 Ibid.

210 Frank P Maier-Rigaud relationships between the former and the future owner. After its implementation, a structural remedy does not require any further monitoring. This definition implies that a structural remedy removes the incentive or the means of a firm to repeat the infringement of the antitrust laws that was at the source of the administrative procedure. 7 One of the reasons why there is a need for monitoring behavioural remedies stems precisely from the fact that a company may still be facing incentives to circumvent or simply not implement the behavioural remedy. In other words, absent monitoring and enforcement, firm compliance is a dominated strategy. Although a structural remedy also needs some monitoring and where necessary enforcement until a divestiture is completed, this concerns only a limited amount of time (usually several months). After implementation, the firm no longer has an incentive to infringe competition law and no further monitoring or enforcement is necessary. 8 As stated by the OECD (2001), behavioural policies, unlike structural policies, do not eliminate the incentive of the regulated firm to restrict competition despite the best efforts of regulators, regulatory controls of a behavioural nature, which are intended to control the ability of an integrated regulated firm to restrict competition, may result in less competition than would be the case if the regulated firm did not have the incentive to restrict competition. 9 A behavioural remedy, on the other hand, requires permanent monitoring and enforcement. 10 The incentive to circumvent a behavioural remedy also has implications at the design stage. Requiring certain behaviour with respect to one dimension of the strategy space (quantity, price, quality, choice of contractual partners, etc) can easily lead to circumvention by changing the behaviour with respect to another dimension. As a result, behavioural remedies that are designed to prevent circumvention tend to be very detailed and complex. As a consequence, such remedies resemble firm-specific regulation that removes a lot of the flexibility that firms need in order to operate 7 A mandatory, exclusive and non-limited as well as irrevocable licence that is paid up front is in effect equivalent to a structural remedy. 8 There exist structural remedies that may require a behavioural flanking in form of a line-of-business restriction. Without such a restriction, divestitures may only lead to temporary relief if the divested business can easily be replicated or repurchased in the future. 9 See also OECD (2011a: 9, 119), reviewing the OECD Council Recommendation on Structural Separation in Regulated Industries. 10 Given the similarities between behavioural remedies and regulation, the scope of structural remedies extends to situations where competition problems persist despite sector-specific regulation. For an example of structural remedies in a regulated sector see, eg Maier-Rigaud et al (2011), discussing the ENI case, or Hellstr ö m et al (2009), discussing, among other aspects, the E.ON case. Noteworthy is also the recent Article 9 decision in Case AT.39727 CEZ on capacity hoarding. On the friction between the US notion of a regulated conduct defence and the approach in the EU, see OECD (2011b), and in particular the contribution by Richard Brunell therein.

Behavioural versus Structural Remedies in EU Competition Law 211 efficiently and compete effectively in a changing environment. 11 In such an environment, behavioural remedies usually require ongoing revision and adaptation in order to avoid becoming ineffective and/or detrimental to the competitive process. 12 The inflexibility in responding to future dynamic market developments, which cannot be properly antedated either by competition authorities or by market participants, is the key weakness of behavioural remedies. 13 Structural remedies, on the other hand, are within the logic of the market system and allow an efficient adaptation to changing market conditions. They are directly compatible with and have a direct bearing on the incentive structure of market participants. Structural remedies do not affect the flexibility of management to make appropriate business decisions on a lasting basis. 14 A fundamental property of structural remedies is that, from a spectator point of view, they cannot be distinguished from the usual workings of a market system in which mergers and divestitures are a characteristic feature of normal market developments. In that sense, they take full advantage of market allocation dynamics in resolving the competition problem in an efficient way and allow the concerned businesses to move on. While it is possible to look at remedies from a property rights perspective, ie expropriation versus restriction of use, and therefore consider a divestiture as a harsher remedy than a behavioural one, one may well come to a different conclusion when considering the underlying economics. The primary goal of competition policy is to guarantee the proper and efficient functioning of markets in order to achieve the highest possible degree of welfare for society. 15 Structural remedies make use of the dynamics of markets in removing the incentives for committing similar infringements in the future, thereby eliminating competition problems. Behavioural remedies, on the other hand, do not make use of market dynamics but constrain market forces based on some strategy dimension of the firm, 16 thereby distorting market 11 Only from a static point of view is the loss in flexibility the deliberate means to remedy the infringement. 12 Besides the necessity to monitor compliance continuously, the market development has to be monitored to ensure the continued appropriateness of the remedy itself, ie to ensure that the remedy is neither creating advantages nor becoming too restrictive for the firm. The same obviously applies with respect to the impact of the remedy on other market players, requiring a corresponding impact assessment and potential adjustments to the remedy. 13 The fundamental uncertainty about the future is the main reason for market-based allocation protected by competition policy to begin with and should not be confused with the rather static notion of asymmetric information that an antitrust authority may additionally face. 14 See Levinson et al (2000). 15 For present purposes, the question whether total or consumer welfare is the right measure is secondary. 16 In fact, behavioural remedies typically try to simulate the outcome that would be produced by markets in the absence of an infringement by either imposing such an outcome directly (so-called performance or outcome remedies) or by imposing constraints on the