Right decision, wrong reasons

Similar documents
The G roceries Groceries Remittal Decision Decision Some concerns 12 November 2010

Report on Premises Assurance Model selfassessment

International energy price comparisons study

CUSTOMER CENTRICITY INDEX. March Which are the most effective levers to create customer loyalty?

Revisiting the hypothetical monopolist test, and the role of common sense market definitions

BOOTS/ALLIANCE UNICHEM

Nisa Retail / Co-operative Group Merger Inquiry

Unilateral Effects In Horizontal Mergers. Jeffrey Prisbrey Charles River Associates April 28, 2016

Defining Product Markets in the UK Grocery Industry

Edexcel Economics A-level

Taking stock of the OFT s approach in supermarket mergers

Empirical Applications in Transport Economics. Philippe Gagnepain. Office: Tel:

Mark Scheme (Results) Summer 2007

Briefing. Mobile prices in Austria

Emissions trading/tradable pollution permits

Capacity building workshop on the ex post evaluation of competition authorities enforcement decisions: A methodological summary

Mark scheme (Results) Summer Pearson Edexcel GCE AS Level in Business (8BS0/02) Paper 02 Managing Business Activities

AQA Economics A-level

A level: Economics B. Paper 1 practice papers

Franchises and Fascias: Who is leading the way in the world of food retailing? How do Symbol Fascias stack up versus the bigger players.

CASE ME/6752/18 INITIAL SUBMISSION. J Sainsbury plc. ASDA Group Limited

Evaluating Advertising Return on Investment. Quantifying the return on investment in advertising is important for several reasons:

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2010 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

Efficient regime for the expansion of renewable energies, further development of the energy-only market and preservation of EU-ETS

June 2003 SAFEWAY MERGER INQUIRIES: REMEDIES STATEMENT

Economic potential of smart metering in Germany

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

Limited distribution: a self-assessment exercise

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

MARK SCHEME for the May/June 2012 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

MARK SCHEME for the May/June 2012 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

Economics: Introduction

Tesco / Booker Merger Inquiry

Choosing Among Tools for Assessing Unilateral Merger Effects

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON

We apply economics to markets, organisations and policies.

Competition and Monopoly in Markets

SAMPLE RESOURCE. porter s five forces. business strategy. Top Trumps

NPD in an environment of range rationalisation.

Are consumers getting what they REALLY want?

WHy contractors. Take Bad Jobs

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

AQA Economics AS-level

AS Economics. Economics Paper 1: The Operation of markets and market failure Final Mark scheme. 7135/1 June Version/Stage: v1.

INTERNAL AND EXTERNAL ANALYSIS OF ASDA 1 INTERNAL AND EXTERNAL ANALYSIS OF ASDA. Name. Course Instructor Institution Location Date of Submission

UNIVERSITY OF CAMBRIDGE INTERNATIONAL EXAMINATIONS General Certificate of Education Advanced Level

Strategy is the way a business operates in order to achieve its aims and objectives.

Developments in Unilateral Effects Analysis: Price Pressure Tests

Webrooming vs Showrooming. a report by PushON ecommerce. Delivered.

Loyalty penalties and the limits of competitive markets

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 3: Supply, Demand & Equilibrium

The 10 Big Mistakes People Make When Running Customer Surveys

Mark Scheme (Results) January 2011

Mark Scheme (Results) Summer Pearson Edexcel GCE In Business (9BS0) Paper 2: Business activities, decisions and strategy

Towards an effects based approach to price discrimination. Anne Perrot «Pros and Cons 2005» Stockholm

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education Economics Assessment Unit A2 1. assessing. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 20 MAY, MORNING

If the industry s short-run supply curve equals the horizontal sum of individual firms short-run supply curves, which of the following may we infer?

GUARANTEEING SATISFACTION INVESTING TO WIN CUSTOMERS AND GROW MARKET SHARE

Mark Scheme (Results) January 2011

Public goods. Public Economics. Carlo Fiorio Bocconi University

BCG Full Case Example

What is good mental health in the city workplace and how do we measure it?

Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand. Data

Version 1.0: abc. General Certificate of Education. Applied Business 8616/8619. The Marketing Environment. Mark Scheme

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers

Can Analysis of Dominance be taken UPPwards? Possible Lessons from Mergers

Mark Scheme (Results) Winter 2010

Mark Scheme (Results) Winter 2010

Competition and Market Authority's energy market investigation inquiry one off evidence session

ECON 1602 (B 09A): BASIC ECONOMIC CONCEPTS: MICROECONOMICS

How are small specialist stores existing in a market so widely dominated by large chain firms like Tesco and Asda?


Cash Flow if you re out of money, you re out of business.

Joven Liew Jia Wen Industrial Economics I Notes. What is competition?

The Joint OFT / CC Commentary on Retail Mergers: FAQ. November RBB Economics

THE Marketing Plan. SCORE Chapter 37 Houston, Texas

BRITISH BUSINESS IN THE DIGITAL AGE

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2015 series 9708 ECONOMICS

Mark Scheme (Results) Summer Pearson Edexcel GCE in Economics & Business (6EB02/01) Unit 2B: Business Economics

Mark Scheme (Results) Winter 2010

GAINING CUSTOMER CONFIDENCE. Data Hygiene Insight

Morning Time allowed: 1 hour 30 minutes

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

6th October 1998 OECD ROUND TABLE ON RETAIL BUYING POWER OCTOBER 29-30, 1998 BIAC ROOM DOCUMENT

Growing our business the Co-op Way: Wholesale - Nisa acquisition A leader s briefing guide. November 2017

Analyzing Organizations Strategically Undergraduate Level Professor: G. Tyge Payne, PhD

Methodological issues in the regulation of mobile voice call termination

Identifying the growth opportunities for your retail brands. Strategic Brand Planning. ConversionModel Customer dynamics redefined TNS 2013

Reading Guide: Merger Retrospective: Waterstone s and Ottakar s (Booksellers in U.K. and Quebec)

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Food and Drink Federation Sales Directors Forum. Leeds Marriott Hotel 15 th July 2014

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Client Briefing. A matter of definition

Exam #2 (100 Points Total) Answer Key

GUIDELINE FOR WRITING A BUSINESS PLAN

Submitted to the United States Postal Regulatory Commission, September 12, 2018

MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS. Townley, Chapter 4

Accounting for Overheads - Marginal Costing

Chapter 5 Aims and objectives. Vision statements

Transcription:

Right decision, wrong reasons Economic issues in the Poundland/99p Stores merger 28 November 2015

A wise and sensible decision

for in my view the wrong reasons Failure to properly assess barriers to entry/expansion No analysis of real question of interest particularly in a Phase 2 context

Entry and expansion

Hard to think of a market where entry and expansion are easier (1) Small high street stores Lots of vacancies

Hard to think of a market where entry and expansion are easier (2) Easy to get hold of stock http://www.thewholesaler.co.uk/suppliers/home_and_garden/pound_lines/ Fit out costs trivial Leases easy to arrange Low-skilled staff on minimum wage

Levels of entry/expansion are extremely high at a national level CMA s revenue impact analysis had 596 Poundland stores facing 923 entry events within 0.5 miles over the last 5 years and 221 99p stores facing 345 entry events within 0.5 miles over the last 5 years

and the parties presented extensive evidence on options in each overlap area Retailer Key Competing Retailers within the Watford Retail Area (c 3m Number on Map Retailer Name Number of Competing Retailer Units 1 Tesco Stores 1 2 Asda Stores 1 3 Morrisons Stores 1 4 Sainsburys Stores 2 5 Tesco Convenience Stores 6 9 Poundland 1 10 99P Stores 1 11 B&M Stores 1 13 Poundworld/Discount UK Stores 1 15 Wilkinsons Stores 1 17 Best One Stores 1 18 Costcutter Stores 6 19 Musgrave Stores 13 20 Nisa Stores 3 22 Premier Stores 4 23 Spar Stores 3 26 Iceland Stores 1 28 Boots Stores 3 29 Superdrug Stores 2 31 WH Smith Stores 3 32 Rymans Stores 2 33 Card Factory 1 34 Argos 1 35 Marks and Spencer 1 36 Primark 1 37 Greggs Total 3 64 Maps of retail sites in each local area GOAD data on vacant sites in each High Street (marked in purple)

The barriers to entry analysis in full

Failure to acknowledge this is a problem for the rest of the analysis Low barriers to entry sufficient to clear merger by themselves remaining analysis superfluous CMA s proposed analytical framework makes little sense when there are low barriers to entry Important to start with a view on entry barriers when considering how to approach case Joint Merger Guidelines place entry barriers after efficiencies does this make sense?

What the CMA did and why I don t like it

Two approaches to the key merger issue Would prices have gone up after the merger? 1. Simulation approach 2. Outcomes approach CMA did this I prefer this

Simulation approaches Full merger simulation Proxy merger simulation (GUPPI, UPP, IPR etc.) Demand estimation (or other way to back out cross-price elasticities) Diversion ratio estimates Marginal costs (or margins) Margins Can t do this data limitations Model of competition Change in ownership structure Assumption of differentiated Bertrand Assumption on cost passthrough (shape of demand curve CMA did this

Proxy merger simulation uses common data Proxy merger simulation (GUPPI, UPP, IPR etc.) Aggregate diversion ratio estimates Margins Assumption of differentiated Bertrand Formula (which variants?) Based on revenue impact analysis Adjusted with data from CC survey Parties estimates of variable margins Used linear IPR

of which the most difficult data point is the aggregate diversion ratio 1. Identify competing fascia 2. Assume DR = 0 for stores more than 1 mile apart Proximity weight Give a store a weighting of 1 if it was between 0 and 0.5 miles away Give a store a weighting of 0.5 if it was between 0.5 and 1 miles away Fascia weight Give an SPP (Poundworld or 99p store) a weighting of 1 Give a B&M, Bargain Buys, Home Bargains and Wilkinson a weighting of 0.5 Tesco and Asda - weighting of 0.5 Weights drawn from qualitative findings of revenue impact analysis cross-checked against survey evidence.. except for supermarkets, which were added on the basis of benchmarking

which then feeds in to the calculation of the national IPR Aggregate diversion ratio 10% from Poundland to 99p Stores and 21% from 99p Stores to Poundland Use variable margins and relative prices NB Aggregate DR takes account of proportion of overlap areas Aggregate price increase c. 1%-2% No problem! Really? Groceries found problems at 0.6% per local area

This approach has many problems Aggregate diversion ratio essentially made up Largely arbitrary fascia weights Largely arbitrary proximity weights Results impossible to interpret No attempt to calibrate results Whole number fascia counting is clear But how do we interpret the observation that 150 stores faced less than 1 competitor pre-merger and 292 postmerger? What is meant by a quarter of a competitor? Data available over on competitor set over time from revenue impact analysis Extensive entry means can see differences in aggregate diversions (using CMA approach) Could test impact of predictions on reality

particularly failing to deal with easy entry The whole approach is static IPR analysis gives price prediction based on no change in market structure When entry is easy, this approach makes no sense Entry question is different If, post-merger, the merging parties were to increase their prices, would rivals enter in response, to an extent that would offset the price increase? We used to explore this question. Apparently we don t any more. Why not? CMA doesn t recognise this adequately we expected that the expansion of competitors would reduce the aggregate diversion ratio between the Parties compared to the aggregate diversion ratio between Poundland and these expanding competitors (6.152) This is again a static analysis assumes entry plans are fixed but entry plans would not be static in response to any price change this would just create more profitable opportunities is this basically a Phase 1 approach?

5 x 100 does not equal 1 x 500 CMA appears to differentiate between the following situations 1. A 5% price increase in 100 locations 2. A 1% price increase in 500 locations This appears to be an SLC in 100 areas This appears to be fine blame the lawyers?

My preferred approach

A PCA approach is data-based way Would prices have gone up after the merger? 1. Cross-sectional PCA do areas of high concentration have worse performance? 2. Time series PCA do increases in average level of local concentration give rise to reduced performance (or vice versa) We did this CMA could have done this, but didn t of answering the merger question

Cross-sectional PCA Performance f Concentration Store characteristics Local area characteristics Proxied by gross margin (cf Groceries) and variable margin - can t use price as national pricing policies Various measures SPP, all VGM, VGM+, presence or absence Size, sales/sq ft., store type, age, time since refurbishment, recently opened Unemployment rate, average earnings, population density, % ethnic minority OLS approach plus IV using doughnut instruments, i.e. population just outside catchment (cf Groceries) argued correlated with concentration as in rivals catchments but not with margins no effect of concentration on margins

CMA criticisms not sensible in my view If PQRS is set nationally, then the gross and variable margins and ranges of products will not be determined at the local level so you can t do a PCA (Final Report, Appendix E) True if policy is identical everywhere (e.g. price) Not true if policy is differs but not due to competition but due to e.g. size Margins capture all other factors a la Groceries CMA does its own X-sectional PCA on other characteristics (gross margin, range, store refurbishments etc.) (Appendix F) CMA concludes there is no variation in the offer locally this is the conclusion of our PCA rejection of our approach seems strange Shouldn t include sales/sq ft. (Phase 1 Decision) Demographic controls largely insignificant (Phase 1 Decision) Endogeneity problem instruments used suffer from weak instruments (Phase 1 Decision) Fair enough, but CMA redid the analysis without it no difference So what? Sometimes instruments are weak, sometimes not, results don t change

and endogeneity concern irrelevant in the merger context Endogeneity issue: high margin areas (unobserved) attracts entry, distorts pure estimate of concentration effect Argued that need to control for this using instruments I disagree we should be trying to estimate the post-entry effect why are we assuming entry won t happen? IV approach OLS approach Measures effect of change in number of fascia absent entry Standard approach (e.g. Groceries) is to do this but this is the right question Measures combination of change in concentration and any offsetting entry and good instruments are rarely available

One relevant criticism remains Cost or demand factors mean that offer doesn t change locally today Might change to local flexing tomorrow? (NB Poundland approach unchanged in 25 years) National price level set at average level of competition could reduce offer across the board CMA approach bottom up analysis of costs of flexing (e.g. complexity, brand damage) CMA approach revenue diversion analysis

could deal with this using time series PCA Source: Companies House, data not available for 2002 There has been material change in the proportion of competed stores over the past 5 years see entry chart We only had data on competition from 99p Stores CMA had full competitor dataset Did this lead to any change in performance, here measured by margin?

CMA didn t try to explore this We accepted that there had been little change in Poundland s gross margins over time and also that since 2000, Poundland had faced increased competition (in terms of a greater number of local overlaps) from both SPP and VGM retailers. However, this analysis does not control for other factors that have also changed over this period. For example, Poundland has significantly expanded its network of stores and the sector has seen shifts in consumer behaviour. We considered that without controlling for these other factors, it was not possible to identify a relationship between gross margins and intensity of competition. Poundland has significantly expanded its network of stores The sector has seen shifts in consumer behaviour Why would this affect margins? Why can t you control for this? Why would this affect margins? What is a potential factor that exactly offsets the massive reduction in concentration? (As a matter of balance of probabilities.) This criticism affects the revenue impact analysis as well Counsel of despair?

Conclusion

Methodology and precedent troubling Aggregate diversion ratio approach is worrying Heavily assumption driven, no idea how to interpret the results, no attempt at calibration to reality Potentially relevant where you can t do a PCA (not the case) Like trying to do a Phase 1 approach in Phase 2? Rejection of PCA is worrying Approach to entry is terrifying Contradicts identical approach used in previous cases e.g. Groceries Internally inconsistent arguments within CMA report, which comes to the same conclusion on X-sectional PCA Endogeneity concern is not relevant with low barriers to entry Over 1,000 entries in 5 years still not enough for barriers to be low can we imagine a situation with lower barriers? Entire methodology assumes static concentration picture Choice not to write up awkward evidence? If so, why? even if outcome was correct

Frontier Economics Limited in Europe is a member of the Frontier Economics network, which consists of separate companies based in Europe (Brussels, Cologne, London and Madrid) and Australia (Melbourne & Sydney). The companies are independently owned, and legal commitments entered into by any one company do not impose any obligations on other companies in the network. All views expressed in this document are the views of Frontier Economics Limited.

FRONTIER ECONOMICS EUROPE LTD. BRUSSELS COLOGNE LONDON MADRID Frontier Economics Ltd, 71 High Holborn, London, WC1V 6DA Tel. +44 (0)20 7031 7000 Fax. +44 (0)20 7031 7001 www.frontier-economics.com