Projecting Domestic Energy Use into the Future

Similar documents
Future Energy Scenarios: Call for Evidence initial summary of results

MicroCHP Updated market projections. Report, prepared by the Domestic CHP Section of the SBGI

BUSINESSEUROPE views on the review of the Energy Efficiency Directive

Microgeneration An Energy Revolution?

Loyalty penalties and the limits of competitive markets

Green Deal: the story so far Tokyo Green Deal Seminar 24 February 2014

RESIDENTIAL ENERGY Roadmap

Northumbria Research Link

Opportunity for low carbon LP Gas in rural heating to 2030

Too many technologies and not enough infrastructure: How do we reach sustainability?

VantagePoint Modelling Scenario Report

THE FUTURE IS HERE: New Homes, New Codes and Net Zero Living

A-level ECONOMICS 7136/1 7136/1. Paper 1 Markets and market failure. Specimen 2014 Morning Time allowed: 2 hours SPECIMEN MATERIAL

Analysis of a target for Resource Productivity

Energy [R]evolution: a Sustainable Belarus Energy Outlook

Belgium Energy efficiency report

EU consultation on the review of the Energy Performance of Buildings Directive

CLOSING THE CARBON GAP WWF S RECOMMENDATIONS FOR THE UK S EMISSIONS REDUCTION PLAN

The PRIMES Energy Model

Comparative Advantage and Benefits of Trade

REA response to DECC Consultation on the Renewable Heat Incentive Non-domestic scheme early tariff review

Beyond 40% House: Transforming the market for buildings. BMT aims

Energy Efficiency Obligations in the UK. John Mason Senior Manager of Customers Policy and Regulation

Industrial Energy Efficiency - Key Messages

Demand and Energy Forecasting Forum April 2017

Renewable Heat Incentive: proposals for a domestic scheme. Community Housing Cymru Group response

Incorporating Behavioural Responses within a Technology Optimization Energy Model

Energy Performance Certificate

What next for retail competition in energy?

Energy Performance Certificate (EPC)

Lights and Appliances

Year Population (millions) Number of households (millions) Household Size

Economy-wide Implications from U.S. Bioenergy Expansion

Manitoba Hydro 2016/17 & 2017/18 General Rate Application MIPUG/YATCHEW-1. Section: Various Page No.:

Welcome. Alex Haffner Energy Demand Manager. 20 th November 2018

AFFORDABLE AND CLEAN ENERGY

Scenarios of energy efficiency and CO 2 emissions reduction potential in the buildings sector in China to year 2050

In 2001, the American Gas Foundation released a major. fueling the future: An updated vision of our energy future

Barriers preventing the deployment of Small Wind Systems and the Economic Advantages

DEVELOPMENT OF LONG-TERM ENERGY SCENARIOS FOR THE CZECH REPUBLIC

Financing energy efficient community housing. Presentation to Financial Officers Forum NSW Federation of Housing Associations April 2016

The Promises and Challenges Facing Renewable Electric Power Generation

Are Low Carbon Policies Affordable?

MANGING THE FUTURE NETWORK IMPACT OF THE ELECTRIFICATION OF HEAT

Building Concepts for a mid-century energy-neutral society

Portugal Energy efficiency report

EUROCITIES position on clean energy for all Europeans package. May 2017

Energy Demand Model and energy efficiency improvements

Tackling Tariff Design. Making distribution network costs work for consumers

The Long-Term Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs

International Monitoring, Verification and Enforcement Conference

BP Energy Outlook 2035

Low Carbon Industrial Strategy: A vision

Edexcel Economics (A) A-level Theme 1: Introduction to Markets and Market Failure 1.4 Government Intervention

Biodiversity: Powering the Green Economy. 18 October 2011 Green Industries, Department of Trade and Industry

100 percent Renewable Energy Rotorua. Mike Collins Per Nielsen

Some highlights of the Victoria study include: A large untapped resource: The modelling results show strong growth in

The intelligent cooperation between consumption and generation at the heart of the Smart Grid.

Energy Efficiency in Croatian Residential and Service Sector Analysis of Potentials, Barriers and Policy Instruments

EDEXCEL GCSE BUSINESS STUDIES REVISION CHECKLIST. Name:

Energy Billing and Metering. Response to consultation The need for an annual energy statement

Judith Ward Sustainability First. Enabling domestic demand-side flexibility : what issues still need to be tackled?

Top actions you can take to save money and make your home more efficient

Funding incentives for energy saving and micro-generation

Towards a Sustainable Energy Strategy for India

FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT IN UZBEKISTAN

Analysis of Balanced District Heating. Viborg District Heating

Top actions you can take to save money and make your home more efficient

CIBSE Building Simulation Group Compliance vs Performance A Tale of Two Cities Tom Spurrier, Hoare Lea 23 May 2017

Subject: Denmark's annual reporting under Article 24(1) of the Energy Efficiency Directive

Australia s Climate Policy Options: A Study of Policy Options for the Energy Networks Association Preliminary results

RE: ENA Submission on the Electricity Pricing Review

PACIFICORP: PRIVATE GENERATION RESOURCE ASSESSMENT FOR LONG TERM PLANNING

Renewable energy framework in Scotland. Response from The Royal Academy of Engineering to the Scottish Government

An ETI Perspective. The importance of local energy planning to the decarbonisation of heat

Gearing Up: Business Readiness for Climate Change

Meeting the Challenge of Climate Change

Portugal Energy efficiency report

For a more detailed discussion of energy consumption patterns and energy policy in Portugal see Lower Carbon Futures.

What works?: A systematic review of heat policy options relevant to the UK context

Scoping technology scenarios for a 100% Renewable Energy Rotorua

The role of built environment energy efficiency in a sustainable UK energy economy

Commission s proposal for a new Energy Efficiency Directive

Cyprus Energy efficiency report

UK Case Studies. 4 th July 2013 Steinkjer, Norway. Esther Dudek

Memo on the Renewable Energy and Climate Change Package

LNG The Roadmap. Martin Houston LNG Asia - Singapore - 14 th February 2017

Energy Technology Perspectives 2014 Harnessing Electricity s Potential

The Chartered Insurance Professional Designation.

Financial Support for Energy Efficiency in Buildings

DRIVING TRANSFORMATION TO ENERGY EFFICIENT BUILDINGS Policies and Actions: 2 nd Edition

Managing Technological Innovation

Energy Efficiency Priorities: Ukraine. Short, Medium and Long-term Measures

The UK Low. Transition Plan Plan An An introduction to our national strategy for. climate and energyfor climate and energy

Slovenia Energy efficiency report

Insight Report: Domestic Heat Pumps

Demand for Graduates: A review of the economic evidence. Libby Aston and Bahram Bekhradnia September 2003

Architecture in a Climate of Change

Eoin Ó Broin TD. Sinn Féin Spokesperson on Housing, Planning, and Local Government ACHIEVING ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN HOUSING

Issues and Trends in the Development and Transfer of Energy Efficiency Technologies: IEA Studies and Perspectives

Transcription:

PJ Mark Fessey Energy Resources Advisor: Andrew Lovett March 2005 Projecting Domestic Energy Use into the Future Putting changes in the demand for energy services and in energy efficiency together, total domestic energy use could either rise or fall in the future. According to government projections domestic energy demand by 2050 could increase slightly, stay at a similar level or decrease by as much as 30 40%, depending on what future scenario is used. There is certainly less tendency for growth than in the services or transport sectors. The projected future energy demand falls only in scenarios where policy and social changes give substantial weight to environmental goals. Predictions for future domestic energy demand from my own analysis of demand for energy services and improvements in efficiency can be seen in Chart 1. 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 Space Heating Water Heating Cooking Appliances and Light Total 0 1999 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 Year Chart 1. Predicted Domestic Energy Consumption 85% of domestic energy use is for space and water heating and I have made some confident assumptions about future demand for these energy services, mainly regarding thermal comfort levels reaching saturation in the near future and also an increase in the housing stock. There is little that can be done in the future to influence the demand for these energy services and also the domestic demand for electrical appliances and consumer goods. However, with regard energy efficiency in the domestic sector the future could take several different paths depending on the future economic and policy situation. This is what I will be focussing on in this report.

Energy Efficiency In the past two decades domestic energy efficiency has improved at about 1% pa, which is better than in any other sector. Energy efficiency will certainly continue to improve as it has done historically. The rate of improvement will depend on: Innovation Reaction to energy prices Policy interventions to improve efficiency Britain is committed to a low carbon future, with a goal of cutting CO2 emissions 60% by 2050, and efficiency improvements are seen as vital to achieving these goals. The Energy Review (2002) found that energy efficiency improvements can assist the economy as well as achieve social, such as energy security, and environmental goals, all of which are major goals of sustainable development. There is huge technical potential for improved energy efficiency. However, only the proportion of this potential that can show itself to yield energy savings which more than pay for the extra investment cost will have any chance of implementation. In order to assess which energy saving technologies represent economically efficient options it is useful to compare the cost per tonne of carbon saved. Future changes are difficult to predict, but what is certain is that relative merits of the different technologies change over time, with costs falling with technological progress and market growth. Any analysis of this type will use 2 broad approaches: 1. Engineers must place technologies on a spectrum from infant, through emerging to mature. The main problem of looking at the future technologies in this way is that is that these engineering assessments rely on expert judgements, which may differ. 2. Historic relationships between cost reductions and cumulative production can be extrapolated. These learning curves have been seen across a wide range of technologies. Although there are many drivers of cost reduction, the learning curve shows that by far most cost reduction comes through production and market experience. The curve tends to be steeper in the early stages of technology development. More established products with a large market share will find the potential for cost reductions more difficult than newly emerged technologies. A further important thing to remember is that the market for some of these technologies will be global, and so the learning curve will be as a result of global production levels. There are many energy technologies that, after analysis of their economic potential, may be employed in the future, such as renewable energy, carbon sequestration and fuel switching in transport. Potential improvements in end use energy efficiency represent only one area of energy technology. For all sectors of end use, studies have shown that

there is a very significant economic potential for energy efficiency technologies to be employed. This potential energy saving amounts to approximately 30% of final energy demand, and a potential annual savings to the consumer of 12 billion. Domestic energy savings could be as much as 37%, which is a greater percentage saving than any other sector (although transport could potentially see a greater absolute saving as it currently has a higher energy demand). Just through engineering assessments, and without the need to employ the use of learning curves, studies such as the one above show with a high degree of confidence that end use efficiency technologies, such as for domestic, will decrease in cost through to at least 2020. The situation by 2050 is predicted to be similar, but with cost effectiveness more variable, as for individual technologies the lowest cost potential will progressively be deployed. These sort of bottom-up assessments of suggest that there is substantial scope for greater energy efficiency, and that a great deal is cost effective in its own right (before any thought is given to adding the value of emissions saved). There are two competing explanations as to why this potential is not being taken up: 1. That a variety of market failures or barriers mean that when making investment decisions economic agents (households in the case of domestic) are not operating rationally. Economic agents may be acting with imperfect knowledge, for example, they may be better informed on the capital costs of the technology than in the running costs. Also, tenancy agreements provide no incentive for the land lord, and very little incentive for the tenants, to invest in domestic energy efficient technology. The fact that the price of energy does not take into account the costs to the environment, i.e. externalities, can also be considered a market failure. Increased prices by means of a tax could correct this. Increased price of energy could also increase the demand for information. 2. That these economic agents are making entirely rational decisions, and the reason that they choose not to invest in energy efficiency is because there are hidden costs in doing so that have not been picked up by the bottom up assessments as described above. Some of these unforeseen costs may be to GDP, for example the opportunity cost of the time taken to acquire information, though this is less an issue to domestic households than it is to business. Other hidden costs may be to welfare, such as the inconvenience of having builders in you home. The extent to which either of these options is true is import as they have very different implications for policy. If the first view is accepted then policy interventions may be necessary to correct the market failures. If these interventions in the market, do not correct the problem of a lack of energy efficiency uptake by the consumers then it can be argued that government should act to regulate energy efficiency, and so enforce the uptake of technologies, which after all are cost effective. Policy interventions can also tackle to some degree the problem of hidden costs, for example if consumers are directed to investments that represent best practice.

In reality both of views will have some validity. The evidence suggests that the reasons for the non-uptake of energy efficient technologies may be more to do with 1 than 2. Many of the hidden costs appear relatively insignificant when compared to the potential financial returns of energy efficiency investments. A study by the National Audit Office (1998, cited in the Energy Review 2002) found domestic energy efficiency improvements to be cost-effective even taking into account some possible hidden costs such as implementation and management costs. Even if hidden costs do exist then studies show that the costs of carbon reduction by energy efficiency measures are still lower than the costs of saving carbon at the supply end. As shown above there is a great deal of technological potential that is cost effective and will become more so in the future. Furthermore, this potential is not fixed. In the past 30 years innovation has increased the potential at about the same rate that cost effective measures have been adopted. As a result the current cost effective potential has remained largely unchanged. As we move further into a knowledge economy the pace of innovation may increase to a rate faster than experienced over the past 30 years, and as a result the cost effective potential may actually increase (assuming the rate of uptake of cost effective measures remains the same). In the domestic sector the slow turnover of buildings will mean that there is a relatively slow uptake of cost effective energy efficiency measures, and as a result the cost effective potential should grow larger in the future. Most of the future innovations in energy efficiency technology in the domestic end-use sector, will rely on improvements in materials technology, design and control. These will include new construction techniques, micro-chp, heat pumps, superinsulating windows, high efficiency appliances, smart systems for lighting, as well as design improvements to make better use of passive solar energy. There may also be social and institutional changes in the future that affect the uptake of energy efficiency measures. The current regulatory arrangements by which energy is supplied discourage potentially beneficial long-term contracts between energy suppliers and domestic customers. This current inertia can be seen as a market failure that prevents the customer from making the most rational economic decision. In the future liberalised energy markets may be a driver of innovation. The potential for further cutting supply costs will diminish (especially if the government intervenes to internalise environmental externalities), and so suppliers may compete, not on who can supply energy at the lowest price, but on commercial innovations and who can supply the wider package of products. The result may be that commercial energy suppliers see the benefits in technological energy saving innovations and so actively encourage it. For example there may be important potential linkages between micro CHP, new metering technology and energy services marketing. Micro-CHP, which involves a gas powered household CHP unit, is an example of an energy saving technology, which is close to reaching technological maturity, and due to economic and environmental drivers, may become widespread in the future. It may appear cost effective, but like with many technologies it will find it hard to break into the current energy market, which can be described as an uneven playing field. This is where government agencies may need to intervene with economic instruments to

tackle market failures and also policies to reduce hidden costs, although in a more liberalised energy market as described above this would not be necessary. There are inherent uncertainties surrounding future innovation and increased cost effectiveness of technology. In these circumstances it is vital that government policy does not attempt to pick winners, but instead creates a framework where the market provides the appropriate incentives for innovation and development, and so allocates resources efficiently. The use of price signals must always remain of foremost importance (and they should be improved to reflect cost of carbon), but other government policy action such as information campaigns, target setting and minimum standards will also be necessary. Bibliography Performance and Innovation Unit (PIU), 2002. The Energy Review Energy Efficiency Office, 1990. Energy Use and Energy Efficiency in the UK Domestic Sector up to the year 2000. Future CHP Technology and Economic Review, 2003. www.microchap.info DTI, 2002. Energy Consumption in the UK DTI.gov.uk DTI, 2003. Our Energy- Creating a Low Carbon Future.