CHANGES IN THE RELATIONS OF PRODUCTION FACTORS IN AGRICULTURE (THE CASE OF POLAND)

Similar documents
Lowland cattle and sheep farms, under 100 hectares

Using Enterprise Budgets to Compute Crop Breakeven Prices Michael Langemeier, Associate Director, Center for Commercial Agriculture

EU milk margin index estimate up to 2018

SDA cattle and sheep farms, 120 hectares and over

Organic versus conventional farming, which performs better financially?

Farm Economics brief

THE DISTRIBUTION OF FARM PERFORMANCE: DRAFT TERMS OF REFERENCE

THE DEVELOPMENT OF COMPETITIVENESS OF CZECH AGRICULTURAL HOLDINGS

MODERNIZATION OF THE AGRICULTURAL SECTOR IN THE CONTEXT OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

1. Under 60k SO Farm Business Income ( per farm)

EU Milk Margin Estimate up to 2016

NEW MEMBER STATES AND CROSS COMPLIANCE: THE CASE OF POLAND

EU farm economics summary 2013

EU Milk Margin Estimate up to 2015

The Role of Agri-food Processor in the Food Economics 1

OVERVIEW OF AGRICULTURAL STATISTICS IN LITHUANIA Legislative and institutional settings

Information based on FADN data 2013

Farm Credit Canada Annual Report

EU Milk Margin Estimate up to 2013

In order to measure industry total factor productivity

LIVESTOCK PRODUCTION IN KAZAKHSTAN. SITUATION, PROBLEMS AND POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS

Determining the costs and revenues for dairy cattle

Producer price index 1998/99 to 2002/03 (July to June) / / / / /03 Year

MILK PRODUCTION COSTS in 2008 On Selected WISONSIN DAIRY FARMS

Statistical estimation of agricultural resource potential and opportunities for rural development in Russia based on Census

Teagasc National Farm Survey 2016 Results

Reflection on small scale farms and their sustainable development in Albania. Kristaq Kume National Coordinator of AnGR

2006 Iowa Farm Costs. and Returns File C1-10. Ag Decision Maker. Definition of Terms Used

Economic, Productive & Financial Performance Of Alberta Cow/Calf Operations

TENDENCIES ON THE POLISH TRACTOR MARKET. Jan Pawlak

EU Agricultural Economic Briefs

Operating subsidies (both direct payments and rural development except investment support) 8 March 2018

SELECTED EFFECTS OF FINANCING AGRICULTURE FROM A REGIONAL PERSPECTIVE

Dr Andrzej Zadura Agricultural Property Agency Poland

Sector: Agriculture. Keywords: Bulgaria, Sofia, Food Products and Agriculture, Agricultural sector. Abstract:

Report summarising farm business data compiled in The Prince s Farm Resilience Programme s Business Health Check tool 2017

Australian Beef Financial performance of beef farms, to

Coimisiún na Scrúduithe Stáit State Examinations Commission

Contract Hog Production: A Case Study of Financial Arrangements

TMD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 91 ASSESSING IMPACTS OF DECLINES IN THE WORLD PRICE OF TOBACCO ON CHINA, MALAWI, TURKEY, AND ZIMBABWE

Views of farmers and grass root level government officers on the present fertilizer subsidy programme in Sri Lanka

Wisconsin Agricultural Economics Outlook Forum

AgriProfit$ Economics and Competitiveness. The Economics of Sugar Beet Production in Alberta 2008

Appendix I Whole Farm Analysis Procedures and Measures

Allocation of costs in complex cropping and mixed farming systems

MILK PRODUCTION COSTS in 2009 on Selected WISONSIN DAIRY FARMS

Report on Minnesota Farm Finances. April, 2010

FOOD MARKET IN POLAND (current state and trends)

Economic, Productive & Financial Performance Of Alberta Cow/Calf Operations

Cash Flow and Enterprise Information - step two for your 2016 farm analysis

Efficiency and Productivity Growth in Ukrainian agriculture

Farm Viability. A Teagasc National Farm Survey Analysis. Hanrahan, K., Hennessy, T., Kinsella, A., Moran, B., and Thorne, F.

Teagasc National Farm Survey 2014 Results

2011 STATE FFA FARM BUSINESS MANAGEMENT TEST PART 2. Financial Statements (FINPACK Balance Sheets found in the resource information)

Københavns Universitet

eprofit Monitor Analysis Tillage Farms 2016 Crops Environment & Land Use Programme

ASIA AND PACIFIC COMMISSION ON AGRICULTURAL STATISTICS

INDUSTRIAL HEMP SEED PRODUCTION COSTS AND RETURNS IN ALBERTA, 2015

A data portrait of smallholder farmers

EVOLUTION OF SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC SITUATION IN POLISH AGRICULTURE SINCE THE ACCESSION TO THE EUROPEAN UNION

Accounting for Agriculture

PROBLEMS OF WORLD AGRICULTURE

MEASURING SCOPE EFFICIENCY FOR CROP AND BEEF FARMS. M. R. Langemeier 1 and R. D. Jones 1

EFFECTIVENESS OF FIXED ASSETS IN AGRICULTURE OF SELECTED NEW MEMBER STATES IN EUROPEAN UNION.

Azerbaijan Farm Policy Analysis Training workshop

Agrosynergie Groupement Européen d Intérêt Economique

MILK PRODUCTION COSTS in 2000 on Selected WISCONSIN DAIRY FARMS

MARIA MAGDALENA GRZELAK. Income of Private Farms at the Turn of System Transition and European Integration

MILK PRODUCTION COSTS in 1998 on Selected WISCONSIN DAIRY FARMS

2004 Michigan Dairy Farm Business Analysis Summary. Eric Wittenberg Christopher Wolf. Staff Paper September 2005

Marcin Adamski, Jolanta Sobierajewska, Marek Zieliński

POLAND Agriculture Policies and programmes to achieve food security and sustainable agriculture

AgriProfit$ Economics and Competitiveness. The Economics of Sugar Beet Production in Alberta 2007

The East Asian Economic Crisis: It's not All Bad News

Lesson IV: Economic Flows and Stocks

AgriProfit$ The Economics of Sugar Beet Production in Alberta. AGDEX 171/821-5 January, 2013

Executive summary. Greening with jobs WORLD EMPLOYMENT SOCIAL OUTLOOK

2009 Michigan Dairy Farm Business Analysis Summary. Eric Wittenberg And Christopher Wolf. Staff Paper December, 2010

ECONOMICS OF SHRIMP FARMING

USING PRODUCTION COSTS AND BREAKEVEN LEVELS TO DETERMINE INCOME POSSIBILITIES

Economic Situation in Agriculture and Challenges of Crop Farming Development

Economic Review. South African Agriculture. of the DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE, FORESTRY AND FISHERIES

SUMMARY objective evaluation relevance financial effectiveness

PLENARY PANEL 1. A brief on the. African Union Commodities Strategy and Industrialization

Annual Summary Data Kentucky Beef Farms

THE NEED OF STATE INTERVENTION IN REDUCING PRICE DISPARITY BETWEEN AGRICULTURAL AND INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTS PURCHASED BY AGRICULTURAL PRODUCERS

Trends in Russian Agriculture and Rural Energy

THE BENEFITS OF FINANCIAL BENCHMARKING TO FARMERS IN THE UNITED STATES

GREAT LAKES REGION 1979

The African Smallholder Farmer s Perspective. Silas D. Hungwe President, Zimbabwe Farmers Union

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profi t Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Crop Enterprises

b) Variable resources: Some resources like seed, fertilizer, labour, etc vary with the level of output. These are variable resources.

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

Report on Minnesota Farm Finances. August, 2009

Current Risk Factors and Some Aspects of Prospective Development of Agro-Industrial Complex Potential in Tatarstan: Financial, Investment, Innovative

MILK PRODUCTION COSTS in 2001 on Selected WISCONSIN DAIRY FARMS

Farm Income Review 2012

Agricultural reform in Uzbekistan

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

Agriculture in Hungary, 2010 (Agricultural census) Preliminary data (1) (Based on processing 12.5% of questionnaires.)

Transcription:

CHANGES IN THE RELATIONS OF PRODUCTION FACTORS IN AGRICULTURE (THE CASE OF POLAND) Dariusz KUSZ Rzeszow University of Technology, Faculty of Management, Rzeszów al. Powstańców Warszawy 10, 35-959 Rzeszów, Poland, Phone: +48 17 865 11 20, Fax: + 48 17 862 81 93, E- mail: dkusz@prz.edu.pl Corresponding author: dkusz@prz.edu.pl Abstract Observed trends in the changes in relations between the production factors and the level of price of agricultural products cause in the long term the necessity to adopt new production technologies. In the situation of fast growth of the labour cost in relation to other production costs there is necessity to adopt labor-saving technology in order to improve the capital labour relation. It results in substitution of more expensive labour by less expensive capital. The aim of this study is to analyze the changes in relation of production factors in agriculture on the example of Poland. It has been stated that in agriculture in Poland, the loss of land used for agriculture and decapitalization of fixed assets in the absence of outflow of the agricultural population to non-agricultural departments are observed. The result is a deterioration in the relationship between labor resources and the resources of land and capital. Key words: capital, efficiency of production factors, labor, land, relationships between factors of production INTRODUCTION The organization of production processes in agriculture is based on the appropriate binding together the individual factors of production (land, labor and capital). The connection method of production factors in certain production processes is defined as technique of production. Each farmer in the manufacture of products has to choose the appropriate manufacturing techniques. Mutual relations of production factors depend mainly on the relative prices of factors of production and performance. Behaving rationally manufacturer tries to always use the factors of production to a greater extent that are relatively cheaper (compared with their productivity), and reduce the consumption of these, which are expensive. Factors of production can replace each other, so they are substitutable provided that there is a certain (often very large number of production techniques). If there is only one production techniques, substitution of production factors is impossible [7]. In a market economy the correct allocation of factors of production (in terms of their relationship and their level) is the basis for effective management. Analysis of the world's agricultural diversity indicates the existence of some general regularities, based on which the proportions of the factors of production are arranged, determining the level and structure of agricultural production costs. In each country there are in a particular historical moment some resources of production factors, which determine their supply and prices. This in turn affects the way the management of enterprises by the choice of the optimal production techniques. Pricing system makes the combination of factors of production in each country and in all circumstances different. With the abundance of land and scarcity of capital ratio of cost of land to capital is that it pays off to combine large areas of land with a relatively small amount of capital. Production remains at low levels of capital intensity. But where there is a large abundance of technical resources (capital), their price is relatively low. Because of that, the share of capital in the production process will be greater [5, 9]. In the case of agriculture, there are two important types of relationships: (i) between labor and capital inputs and land resources; (ii) between the resources of land and capital and labor resources. The first type of 179

relationship is used to measure the so-called the intensity of agricultural production. The second type of relationship is in turn the meter of equipping labor with land and other production means, particularly technical. The aim of this study is to analyze the changes in relation of production factors in agriculture on the example of Poland. MATERIALS AND METHODS The empirical material were statistical data from the Central Statistical Office of Poland for the years 1995-2013, and data from the European Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) for the years 2004-2012. The paper presents the basic relationship between the three factors of production: land, labor and capital. Changes in the efficiency of production factors of production resources involved were shown against the background of these relations. Gross agricultural output 3, intermediate consumption 4, gross value of fixed assets, net value of fixed assets were expressed in constant prices of 2011, making adjustments based on inflation. RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS The management of the production potential in agriculture is based on existing opportunities for combination of and substitution of factors of production. The phenomenon of substitution of factors of production creates many possibilities of their combination, depending on the socioeconomic and technical nature. Particularly important for the relationship of factors of 3 Gross agricultural output includes: crop output, i.e., raw (not processed) products of plant origin (harvests for a given year); animal output, i.e., production of animals for slaughter, raw (not processed) products of animal origin as well as the increase in farm animal stocks (livestock - the basic and working herd) which include: cattle, pigs, sheep, horses and poultry. 4 Intermediate consumption includes the value of agricultural products from own production, agricultural products utilised for production purposes as well as the purchase of materials (including fuels), energy, outside services (external processing, agricultural, veterinary, insemination and transport services, current repairs, telecommunications services, commissions paid for banking services), financial intermediation services indirectly measured (FISIM), costs of business travels (excluding data regarding private farms) and other costs (e.g. insurance, rentals and leasing). The valuation of materials used in production was performed using annual average purchase prices. 180 production are their prices, especially rising labor costs compared to other factors of production [8]. In conditions of rapid growth in labor costs compared to other factors of production it becomes necessary to implement labor-saving technology resulting in an increase in the capital-labor relations. The result is a substitution of increasingly expensive inputs of labor by relatively cheaper capital. However, the problem of substitution of factors of production in agriculture is complicated. In this case, substitution of production factors is loaded by the factor of the land. Agricultural production is described by the three-factor production function, rather than the two-factor as in other fields. Hence the efficiency and cost of materials is limited by the efficiency of the factor of the land. Land as a factor of production is characterized by a lack of mobility, which among other things implies inefficient, by Pareto, allocation of production factors. In addition, land factor due to natural reasons has a naturally limited opportunity to stimulate productivity. Production potential of agriculture depends on the level of equipping with the factors of production. Land resources in Poland in the analyzed period decreased from 17.9 million hectares to 14.6 million hectares, an change of 18.5% (Figure 1). The decline in the agricultural area is an inevitable process, resulting from an increase in the competitiveness of land use between both agricultural and non-agricultural use as. Agricultural and economic analysis on the countries of medium and highly developed market economy indicate the prevalence of these trends. The high rate of loss of agricultural land means a new economy of land resource utilization. The consequence of this is the new shape of the production processes in agriculture, which is to increase the intensification of effort per unit area of agricultural land, with all the consequences, such as negative externalities, including environmental. This process can be observed in agriculture in Poland, the decrease in the area of agricultural land has increased the production intensity reflected in an increase in the intermediate consumption per unit of

utilized agricultural area (Figure 9). Economic development of any country is associated with changes in the level and structure of employment. Reaction of agriculture to economic development is facilitated by structural changes (especially the concentration processes occurring in agriculture) and the outflow of the agricultural population to non-agricultural sectors. Analyzing the labor force in agriculture in Poland, we can see that despite the economic development of the country there has not been a significant outflow of population employed in agriculture to non-agricultural departments, and even since the year 2010 the number of people employed in agriculture has increased (Figure 1). Relationship of the number of people working in agriculture per 100 ha (Figure 2) and the percentage of people working in agriculture in total employment (in the years 2005 to 2013, this ratio at the level of 16-17%) also remained at a high level. This situation may be related to the inability to move away from agriculture resulting from high unemployment persisting in the national economy (Figure 3). In addition, it may be due to the nature of farms in Poland, where family farms, spatially small, with excess of labor are predominant. Fig. 1. The number of people employed in agriculture and the agricultural area in Poland in the years 1995-2013 Fig. 2. Number of persons engaged in agriculture per 100 ha of agricultural land in Poland in the years 1995-2013 181

Fig. 3. The unemployment rate in Poland in the years 1995-2013 [%] The level of agricultural equipment in fixed assets determines the degree of agriculture technisation. The real value of the gross and net assets in agriculture in Poland in the analyzed period of time was reduced (Figure 4). Similarly, the value of fixed assets per employee and per 1 ha of agricultural land decreased. However, in 2013 this trend was halted and technical equipping of land and work has increased compared to 2012 (Figure 5-8). Cited statistics include all farms in Poland, but do not show the state of differentiation of Polish agriculture. Generally it is manifested in the existence of many small, vulnerable households having a social character, with marginal contacts with the market and the relatively small number of larger farms producing for the market (Table 1). In small farms, representing the vast majority there is a lack of investment capacity and the process of depreciation of fixed asset is present. Investment capabilities are held by greater farms with potential for development. The changes that occur in the group of commodities farms can be observed by analyzing the data obtained from the Polish FADN (Farm Accountancy Data Network). The observed relationship between the factors of production tend to be different than those observed in agriculture in Poland. Labor input per unit area of agricultural land decreased, and labor resources and land equipment in total assets and fixed assets increased (Table 2). While analyzing the relationship of selected non-current assets (buildings and machinery) to the land resources and effort, the ratio of machines than buildings increased to a greater extent (Table 2). This situation 182 indicates that changes in the structure of fixed assets in the advantage of mobile assets over nonmobile. Investments in mobile assets, compared to non-mobile fixed assets, are characterized by a greater degree of reversibility due to the higher degree of liquidity of these assets and a market for used machines [3]. Therefore, the flexibility of agricultural holdings increased. It is worth to pay attention to a relationship, despite the decline in the value of the gross and net assets per 1 ha of agricultural land, the level of intermediate consumption increased (expenditure of current assets, such as: yieldforming agents, fertilizers, pesticides) on agricultural area (Figure 9). It is related to the need to implement technical progress in agriculture [6], especially biological, but also is related to the availability of technical and biological agents not only in a substantive sense, but also because of their price decrease [7]. The need to implement biological and chemical technology is also associated with the loss of agricultural land in Poland and the desire to increase the productivity of the land. The observed trend of increasing expenditures related to the current assets while reducing fixed assets may also be associated with a desire to improve the structure of capital employed in curbing capital assets (generating fixed costs, which is characterized by a lack of mobility, irreversibility or less flexibility) in favor of the current assets. Furthermore, it can also be a reflection of the structural changes in agriculture in Poland, consisting of a slow decrease in the share of smallest-area households (Table 1).

300000,0 250000,0 200000,0 150000,0 100000,0 50000,0 0,0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 gross value of fixed assets net value of fixed assets Fig. 4. The gross and net value of the assets in agriculture in Poland in the years 1995-2013 [million PLN] - fixed prices in 2011 160000,0 140000,0 120000,0 100000,0 80000,0 60000,0 40000,0 20000,0 0,0 R² = 0,9007 Fig. 5. The gross value of fixed assets per worker in agriculture in Poland in the years 1995-2013 [PLN] - fixed prices in 2011 Fig. 6. The net value of fixed assets per worker in agriculture in Poland in the years 1995-2013 [PLN] - fixed prices in 2011 183

16000,0 14000,0 12000,0 10000,0 8000,0 6000,0 4000,0 2000,0 0,0 R² = 0,9186 Fig. 7. The gross value of fixed assets per 1 ha AL in agriculture in Poland in the years 1995-2013 [PLN/1 ha AL] - fixed prices in 2011 Fig. 8. The net value of fixed assets per 1 ha AL in agriculture in Poland in the years 1995-2013 [PLN/1 ha AL] - fixed prices in 2011 Table1. Number of farms of the area exceeding 1 ha in Poland in the period 2002-2013 (in thousands) Year Total Farm size clusters 1 5 5 20 20 50 >50 2002 Number 1,951.7 1,146.3 692.8 95.5 17.1 % 100 58.7 35.5 4.9 0.9 2010 Number 1,480.2 790.0 569.4 96.6 24.3 % 100 53.37 38.47 6.53 1.64 2013 Number 1,391.1 732.5 526.3 102,9 29,3 % 100 52.66 37.83 7.40 2.11 Table 2. Relations of production factors in farms engaged in agricultural accounting according to the rules of the FADN Year Parameter 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Total labor input 11.19 10.31 10.09 9.60 9.12 9.23 9.09 9.23 9.18 AWU*/100 ha AL. Total assets EUR/1 ha AL 4325.75 4073.33 4298.15 4861.65 5296.74 7281.92 7901.35 8048.26 8292.78 Total assets EUR/total 38661.36 39513.56 42588.57 50632.95 58056.98 78901.76 86914.88 87173.84 90309.83 labor AWU* Toatl fixed EUR/1 ha AL 3674.19 3428.31 3565.40 4017.89 4377.68 6518.57 7003.63 7061.08 7246.55 Total fixed EUR/total 32838.07 33256.50 35328.00 41845.45 47983.24 70630.59 77039.88 76481.40 78916.18 labor AWU* Buildings EUR/1 ha AL 1681.25 1713.16 1722.84 1812.22 1957.75 1681.43 1783.06 1770.21 1786.52 Buildings EUR/total labor 15026.14 16618.64 17070.86 18873.86 21458.66 18218.82 19613.69 19173.84 19455.49 AWU* Machinery EUR/1 ha AL 991.99 969.89 975.09 1054.94 1209.33 1066.99 1106.33 1151.74 1206.21 Machinery EUR/total labor AWU* 8865.91 9408.47 9661.71 10986.93 13255.31 11561.18 12169.64 12475.00 13135.84 * AWU annual work unit full time person equivalent Source: own calculations based on statistical data FADN http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/rica/database/database_en.cfm 184

Fig. 9. The intensity of agricultural production - the value of intermediate consumption per 1 ha AL [PLN/ha] - fixed prices in 2011 Attention should be paid to the differences observed in the mutual relations of production factors between agricultural holdings under Polish FADN and the total of farms. They result from structural defects of agriculture in Poland, particularly related to high agrarian dispersion. As a result, it is difficult to achieve proper relations of production factors. The pace of concentration in agriculture influences the ability to improve the relations between labor and capital expenses and land resources and between resources of land and capital and labor resources. Activation of this process requires a selection of appropriate instruments in support of concentration in agriculture, particularly the possibility of increasing off-farm employment. However, this depends on the level of economic development of the country, especially the absorbency of the labor market. Changes in the relationship between the factors of production should also be considered in the context of changes in the effectiveness of individual factors of production. 6500 6000 5500 5000 4500 4000 3500 3000 R² = 0,8089 1995199619971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010201120122013 Fig. 10. Productivity of land in Poland [gross agricultural output minus payments PLN/1 ha AL] - fixed prices in 2011 185

Fig. 11. Productivity of gross value of fixed assets in Poland [gross agricultural output minus payments PLN/gross value of fixed assets PLN] - fixed prices in 2011 Fig. 12. Productivity of net value of fixed assets PLN in Poland [gross agricultural output minus payments PLN/ net value of fixed assets PLN] - fixed prices in 2011 Fig.13. Labor productivity in agriculture in Poland [gross agricultural output minus payments PLN/per one employee] - fixed prices in 2011 In Poland, as presented above, the loss of the land used for agriculture occurs and the value of the assets at the disposal of the farmers was reduced, and in the case of the labor force decline was not observed. Gross agricultural output minus the amount of payments made under direct payments schemes was used to assess the effectiveness of the factors of 186

production. The analysis shows that increased land productivity (Figure 10) and the effective use of gross fixed capital formation (Figure 11) and net fixed capital formation (Figure 12). In the case of labor since the Polish accession to the European Union in 2004, there has been a downward trend, after the accession, this trend has been slightly reversed (Figure 13). However, to improve the work efficiency, issues related to the possibility of migration from agriculture will be the most important. In broad terms, the mechanism of loss of employed in agriculture is described by the model of D.W. Jorgenson [2] and A.C. Kelly, J.G. Williamson and R.J. Cheetham [4. Better known is the theory of mechanism of loss of employment in agriculture based on "labor push - labor pull." Pushing the labor force from agriculture occurs due to improvements in agricultural technology combined with Engel's law release resources from agriculture ("labor push"), and improvements in industrial technology attract labor out of agriculture ("labor pull") [1]. CONCLUSIONS The relationship between the factors of production affect the effectiveness of the factors of production on the one hand, on the other hand indicate the directions of changes in agriculture. The study allows us to formulate the following conclusions: -In agriculture in Poland, the loss of land used for agriculture and decapitalization of fixed assets in the absence of outflow of the agricultural population to non-agricultural departments are observed. The result is a deterioration in the relationship between labor resources and the resources of land and capital. To improve these relationships, it is important to stimulate agrarian changes in agriculture especially concentration processes, the implementation of technical progress resulting in pushing labor from agriculture. At the same time forces must also act to allow to pull labor from agriculture, and these are mainly related to the country's economic development, especially the development of the labor market in non-agricultural sectors. -Comparing the relationship of factors of production in agriculture in Poland to the same relationship in farms covered by FADN accounting difference in relationships is noticeable. The farms covered by Polish FADN positive changes are observed. The reason for such differences is the polarization of farms in Poland. There is a large group of small farms, economically weak and relatively small group of farms that are larger, economically stronger, investing, modernizing its production workshop. -Changes in the relations of production factors cause changes in the efficiency of individual stocks. The research shows that productivity of land and the performance of fixed assets in agriculture increased. For labor efficiency a downward trend was mitigated. REFERENCES [1]Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., Poschke, M., 2011, Structural change out of agriculture: Labor push versus labor pull. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 127-158. [2]Jorgenson, D.W., 1961, The Development of a Dual Economy. Economic Journal, Vol. 71, 309-334. [3]Kataria, K., Curtiss, J., Balmann, A., 2012, Drivers of Agricultural Physical Capital Development. Theoretical Framework and Hypotheses. Factor Markets. Working Paper, No. 18. [4]Kelley, A.C., Williamson, J.G., Cheetham, R.J., 1972, Dualistic Economics Development: Theory and History. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [5]Klepacki, B., Żak, A., 2013, Agrarian transformations in the territory of Poland before and after integration into the European Union. Journal of Agribusiness and Rural Development, No. 4 (30), 95-113. [6]Kusz, D., 2014, Modernization of Agriculture vs Sustainable Agriculture Scientific Papers. Series "Management, Economic Engineering in Agriculture and Rural Development", Vol. 14 Issue 1, 171-178. [7]Rembisz, W., 2008, Mikro- i makroekonomiczne podstawy równowagi wzrostu w sektorze rolnospożywczym. Vizja PRESS&IT, Warsaw (in Polish). [8]Runowski, H., Ziętara, W., 2011, Future role of agriculture in multifunctional development of rural areas. APSTRACT: Applied Studies in Agribusiness and Commerce, Vol. 5, Numbers 1 2, 29-38. [9]Yamaoka, R., 1969, The modernisation of agriculture at the present stage. The Kyoto University Economic Review, No. 39(1), 1-21. 187

188