The Effect of Educational, Health, Infrastructure Expenses on the Workforce Employment and Poverty

Similar documents
Economic growth and poverty reduction: the role of the agricultural sector in rural Indonesia ABSTRACT PAPER A03

The Effect of Human Capital, Labor, and Capital on Economic Growth in Barlingmascakeb

Rate of Return to Education and Institutional Labour Market Reform in Urban China

Analysis of Economic Transformation and Determination of Main Economic Sectors in the Future

ANALYSIS OF FACTORS AFFECTING THE IMPLEMENTATION OF COMPUTER-BASED ACCOUNTING INFORMATION SYSTEM ON SMALL AND MEDIUM ENTERPRISES

Reducing Spatial Inequality In Indonesia: Off-The-Job Training As A Special Treatment For Underdeveloped Regions

The Impact of Physical and Human Capital on the Economic Growth of Agricultural Sector in South Sumatera

THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION ON GDPPER CAPITA IN PROVINCES OF INDONESIA

Human Capital Investment and Its Role in Encouraging Inclusivity in East Java

The Relationship of Economic Growth with Human Development and Electricity Consumption in Indonesia

MODEL OF THE RELATIONSHIP OF COOPERATION BETWEEN LOCAL GOVERNMENT TO INCREASE SEAWEED EXPORTS

THE INFLUENCE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH TO POVERTY AND ITS RELATION TO THE PRO POOR IN INDONESIA

Empirical Analysis of the effect of Human Capital Generation on Economic Growth in India - a Panel Data approach

Agriculture Challenges: Decline of Farmers and Farmland Study from Indonesian Family Life Survey

Part II: Economic Growth. Part I: LRAS

Factors Affecting PDAM Water Demand of Household A Category in Purworejo Regency

DISSERTATION ABSTRACT. Essays on Economic Growth and Development: New Perspectives from Health, Education, and Wealth. Kei Hosoya

The impact of energy resources on social development in Russia

iafor The International Academic Forum

HUMAN RESOURCE: TO INCREASING INDONESIAN COMPETITIVENESS ON ASEAN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY

Asian Journal of Distance Education

ESTIMATING GENDER DIFFERENCES IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY: BIASES DUE TO OMISSION OF GENDER-INFLUENCED VARIABLES AND ENDOGENEITY OF REGRESSORS

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

BUILDING NEW TOURIST ATTRACTION: JOB CREATION OR JOB DESTRUCTION

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

THE IMPORT RESTRICTION OF HORTICULTURAL PRODUCT, DOMESTIC ACTIVITIES, PRICE LEVEL, AND THE WELFARE

THE IMPACT OF E-WOM, CONSUMER TRUST, AND CELEBRITY ENDORSEMENT TOWARD PURCHASE INTENTION IN RAVELOUX INSTAGRAM

Literature Review: Long-Run Economic Growth

THE DEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES OF CASHEW INDUSTRY IN KENDARI CITY, SOUTHEAST SULAWESI. Asriani *) ABSTRACT

How Agricultural Research Affects Urban Poverty in Developing Countries? The Case of China. Shenggen Fan Cheng Fang Xiaobo Zhang.

THE FACTORS THAT INFLUENCES THE NIGHT CULINARY TRADERS S REVENUE IN PEMATANGSIANTAR CITY (STUDY CASE: SIANTAR SQUARE)

International Journal of Advanced Engineering and Management Research Vol. 3 Issue 2; ISSN:

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence

Is Poverty a binding constraint on Agricultural Growth in Rural Malawi?

MODELLING THE WHEAT SECTOR IN SOUTH AFRICA

ANALYSIS OF FACTORS THAT AFFECT ENTREPRENEURSHIP INTEREST IN STUDENTS OF ACCOUNTING EDUCATION FACULTY OF ECONOMICS YOGYAKARTA STATE UNIVERSITY

Level of Sustainable Livelihood Approach at Central Agriculture City of Batu

PUBLIC GOODS PROVISION IN RURAL AREA: CASE FROM ZHEJIANGPROVINCE OF CHINA. Pan Weiguang 1 1. INTRODUCTION

Analysis of Factors That Affect Good Government Governance Implementation (Empirical Study on Government of Indragiri Hilir Regency)

PERSPECTIVE OF CATTLE POPULATION DEVELOPMENT IN WEST JAVA INDONESIA

Third Edition. Gregory C. Chow

Agricultural Demand Linkages and Growth Multiplier in Rural Indonesia

2010 JOURNAL OF THE ASFMRA

ANALYSIS OF FOOD CONSUMPTION PREFERENCES AND FOOD DEMAND IN CENTRAL JAVA, INDONESIA

Pengaruh Keberadaan Komite Pengawasan dan Tingkat Pengungkapan Sukarela pada Harga Saham di Indonesia

Renita Kawuryan Mochammad Al Musadieq Arik Prasetya Fakultas Ilmu Administrasi Universitas Brawijaya Malang

PROCEEDINGS ISBN:

THE LIST OF COURSES OF ECONOMIC DEPARTMENT

Rizal Rustam STATE POLYTECHNIC OF JEMBER, INDONESIA.

Agricultural Productivity, Economic Growth, and Food Security

Market integration of fresh milk in dairy business area of Pamijahan District and Cisarua District, Bogor Regency - Indonesia

Eurasia: Economics & Business, 2(8), February 2018 DOI

Trend in Household Expenditures in Albania

TESTING ROBERT HALL S RANDOM WALK HYPOTHESIS OF PRIVATE CONSUMPTION FOR THE CASE OF ROMANIA

Analysis of Inputs use in Rice Farm Management at Sekotong, West Lombok, Indonesia

Impact of Government Expenditure, Human Capital and Regional Economic Development Performance on People Welfare in Bali Province, Indonesia

Analysis of Orange Commodity Role to Regional Development in Dairi Regency, Indonesia

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS

Department of Regional and Rural Development Planning, University of Sumatera Utara, North Sumatra, Indonesia

Implementation Of Information Technology Balanced Scorecard in An Agriculture Organisation

Hotel Industry Demand Curves

Analysis Of Micro And Small Industry Development In Indonesia

Structural Change in Indian Economy: Changing Composition of Growth

Regional Development and Inequality of Income Distribution

Structure Transformation of Indonesia Economic Year Period

Is There an Environmental Kuznets Curve: Empirical Evidence in a Cross-section Country Data

THE WAY FORWARD OF REGIONAL FOOD SECURITY ATTAINMENT THROUGH MAXIMIZING LAND UTILIZATION IN THE RESIDENCE AREA OF SEASONAL MIGRANT

Are Household Nonfarm Enterprises Structural Transformation?

Analysis of Agricultural Sector as a Leading Sector in the Regency of Timor Tengah Utara

The relationship between innovation and economic growth in emerging economies

THE IMPACT OF CELEBRITY ENDORSEMENT ON BRAND IMAGE AND CONSUMER REPURCHASE INTENTION OF OPPO SMARTPHONE IN SURABAYA

THE INFLUENCE OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE ON INDUSTRIAL SECTOR (A Study at Batam Indonesia Free Zone Authority, Periods of )

Chapter 2 The Basics of Supply and Demand

BEHAVIORAL ANALYSIS OF NON-DURABLE CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES: A CASE STUDY OF WAH CANTT

Determination of the Parameters That Effect the Residential Electrical Consumption of Turkey

Structure changes, the contribution of sectors, income per capita Indonesia in

ANALYSIS OF INDONESIA S PEPPER IN THE SUPPLY AND DEMAND

CHAPTER 1. PRELIMINARIES

Effect of Human Development Index Fund on Economic Growth Through a Special Autonomy

JST Journal of Saintech Transfer

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.

THE INFLUENCE OF CELEBRITY ENDORSEMENT AND CONSUMER TRUST TOWARD PURCHASE INTENTION IN DOTIC DONUT INSTAGRAM IN MALANG.

A regional model for labour demand in Romania

The Economic Impact of Wind Power Development

The determinant effect of industry sub-sectors on the gross regional domestic product in Maluku

Water Policy and Poverty Reduction in Rural Area: A Comparative Economywide Analysis for Morocco and Tunisia

Agriculture Import Liberalization and Household Welfare in Sri Lanka

Economic Growth, Employment and Poverty Reduction: Evidence and Lessons

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Environmental Sciences 28 (2015 )

Paying Attention to Environmental, Social and Economic Sustainability; Indonesian Food and Fuel Case Study

Simulation Of Household Economic Policy To Improve Small-Scale Fisherman s Income, Using Rural Rice-Fish Development Program In Donggala, Indonesia

Logit-Normal Spatial Model for Small Area Estimation: Case Study of Poverty in Bengkulu

Dynamic Simulation Model to Analyze Some Factors that Influence the Growths of Agricultural SMEs and the Impact on GDP in East Java

IMPACT OF RICE PURCHASING POLICY ON WELFARE OF BOTH PRODUCERS AND CONSUMERS IN INDONESIA

Economy Growth and Oil Import Requirement in Indonesia

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute

ECONOMIC GROWTH AT REGIONAL LEVEL AND INNOVATION: IS THERE ANY LINK?

Prateek Sangal Senior Economics Major 10/03/03 Testing the Relationship of Education to Income

Prospects for the sectoral transformation of the rural economy in Tanzania

WORK INTENSIFICATION, DISCRETION, AND THE DECLINE IN WELL-BEING AT WORK.

Transcription:

International Journal of Administrative Science & Organization, September 2013 Volume 20, Number 3 ISSN 0854-3844, Accredited by DIKTI Kemendiknas RI No : 64a/DIKTI/Kep/2010 The Effect of Educational, Health, Infrastructure Expenses on the Workforce Employment and Poverty NIKEN SULISTYOWATI Faculty of Economy, Universitas Jayabaya, Jakarta nikensulistyowati@yahoo.com Abstract. The research aims to analyze the influence and impact of educational, health, and infrastructure expenses on the employment of workforce (from agricultural, industrial, services sectors) and poverty in Central Java. The model was built by using an econometric approach in the form of a system of simultaneous equation model consisting of six blocks (human capital, inputs, outputs, revenues, expenditures and social welfare) with 33 equations (24 structural equations and 9 identity equation). The method of estimation model uses Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS). The simulation results show that the policies of increasing expenses on education, health, and infrastructure with the same value result in the increased employment of workforce in all sectors and reduced poverty. Among these policies, the increased health expenses have the most significant influence on the increase of workforce employment in services sector and reduce poverty. While the policy of increasing expenses on infrastructure has the greatest effect on the increase of workforce employment in industrial and agricultural sectors. Keywords: education, health, infrastructure, workforce Abstrak. Penelitian ini bertujuan untuk menganalisis pengaruh dan dampak pengeluaran pendidikan, kesehatan dan infrastruktur terhadap penyerapan tenaga kerja sektoral (pertanian, industri, jasa) dan kemiskinan di Jawa Tengah. Model dibangun dengan menggunakan pendekatan ekonometrika dalam bentuk sistem persamaan simultan (simultaneous equation model), terdiri dari 6 blok (human capital, input, output, penerimaan, pengeluaran dan kesejahteraan masyarakat) dengan 33 persamaan (24 persamaan struktural dan 9 persamaan identitas). Metode pendugaan model menggunakan Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS). Hasil simulasi menunjukkan bahwa kebijakan peningkatan pengeluaran pendidikan, kesehatan dan infrasruktur dengan nilai yang sama menyebabkan peningkatan penyerapan tenaga kerja semua sektor dan mengurangi kemiskinan. Di antara ketiga kebijakan tersebut, peningkatan pengeluaran kesehatan paling besar pengaruhnya dalam meningkatkan penyerapan tenaga kerja jasa dan mengurangi kemiskinan. Sedangkan kebijakan peningkatan pengeluaran infrasruktur paling besar pengaruhnya dalam meningkatkan penyerapan tenaga kerja industri dan penyerapan tenaga kerja pertanian. Kata kunci: infrastruktur, kesehatan, pendidikan, tenaga kerja INTRODUCTION The recent concept of development is improving, marked by the inclusion of public welfare aspect, in addition to economic aspect (the growth of GDP per capita). Public welfare cannot be separated from the fulfillment of human basic needs, i.e. the increase of the quality of education and health or the quality of Human Resources. Poverty is one of the low qualities of human resources, hence reducing the number of poor people is a must for the goals of today s development. Underdevelopment and poverty exist partly because people do not have modern knowledge, skills and attitude. Poor education and health can cause people unable to work optimally and affect the level of income (Schultz, 1961). Poor people have low income, thus cannot meet their basic needs properly, and later results in a declining work productivity and income. If this takes place in some generations, it is called the vicious circle of poverty, as illustrated in figure 1 below. Poverty is negatively and significantly correlated to the family s decision to send the children to school. The need of schooling is an effective way to reduce the phenomenon Poor Health and Education Low savings and consumption rate (poverty) Low productivity Low level of income Figure 1. The Vicious Circle of Poverty Source: Kasliwal.1995; Capello, 2007 of child labor in Ghana (Canagarajah and Coulombe, 1997). Such is also common in Indonesia, where poverty is the main reason for the kids to get out of school. According Suryahadi et al. (2005) approximately 95% of children in Indonesia are out of the basic education. The contributing factor is the lack of a fee by 50-80%, helping the elderly by 8-17% and the rest is for other reasons. There is a tendency that the need to work to help parents is due more to the severity of poverty. Poverty cannot be separated from the high number of unemployed population. The increase of population

122 International Journal of Administrative Science & Organization, September 2013 Volume 20, Number 3 is not balanced with the provision of jobs, causing unemployment rate to rise. On a national scale, Nanga (2006) states that unemployment has an indirect effect in increasing poverty. Unemployment positively gives an impact to the increase of income inequality that enhances poverty. Meanwhile, according to Hartati (2012) unemployment has a direct effect in multiplying poverty. Central Java was a notably strategic province, since it lies between two major provinces, namely West Java and East Java. From an economic standpoint it is supposed to be beneficial for business development. Nevertheless, ironically, the favorable position is not supported by better public welfare. One of the fundamental problems of economic development in Central Java is a high rate of poverty. Compared with national poverty data, the percentage of poverty in Central Java is still relatively high. According to the data of Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS), the poverty in Central Java in 2011 was amounted to 5,256 thousand people or 16.21%, that was above the national poverty rate of 12.49% (BPS, 2012). The BPS data in 2008 showed that poverty is most prevalent in the population with educational level of Junior High School (SMP) or below, i.e. amounting to 92.8%. Meanwhile, residents who have Senior High School (SMA) education or above have less contribution to poverty, amounting to 7.19% (BPS, 2009). This situation suggests that the poverty rate can be due to a low level of public education. Today, the standard of Human Development Index (HDI) becomes very important to measure the achievement of development goals. Local government through its budget policy (particularly education, health, and infrastructure expenses) is expected to help people in improving the quality of human resources (human capital), increase productivity and ultimately reduce poverty (Sulistyowati, 2011). According to Duff (1997), the government has a role and duty to achieve justice (equity objective) which includes poverty eradication, reduction of income inequality, welfare, equality of access, compliance with clothing, food, housing, health, and education. Through this role, the government is expected to help the poor get out of the trap of the vicious circle of poverty. Based on the background, the researcher is interested in analyzing the influence and impact of educational, health, and infrastructure expenses on the employment of workforce and poverty in Central Java. The purpose of the study is to analyze factors affecting employment (in agricultural, industrial, and services sectors) and poverty and the effect of increased education, health, and infrastructure expenses on the employment of workforce and poverty in Central Java. According to Saariluoma (2005), human resources is one of the major variables in economic growth, in addition to several other variables such as technology, social and economic conditions of the people, security, and natural resources. In Endogenous growth models, human capital formation is included in the production function. Economy will achieve a high growth due to the increase of investment in human capital. This theory describes the influence of educational level on the growth. The results of the empirical study states that there is a significant influence of human capital on the production. Human capital is believed to be an important factor in the process of economic growth. Endogenous growth theorists argue on the assumption of constant returns to capital, and perceive knowledge as a capital. Compared with other forms of capital, theoretically it is uncommon to assume that knowledge has a diminishing returns unit. Even, the continuously increasing knowledge and technological innovation thus far make some economists argue that there is increasing knowledge returns. Then the endogenous growth model with the assumption of constant returns to capital becomes a more promising description in long-term economic growth. Similarly, human factors can develop, following the development of science and technology. Advances in science and technology become an important growth factor (Mankiw, 2003). According to Mankiw (2003), the differences in income per capita are due to: differences in factors of production, such as the quantity of physical capital and human capital, and differences in the usage efficiency of production factors. There is a positive correlation between capital accumulation factors (including HR) and the efficiency of production. Countries with a high level of physical and human capital are likely to use the factors of production efficiently. One hypothesis is that efficient economy may encourage capital accumulation. Resources and incentives to stay in school will accumulate a larger human capital, so that the economy can function properly. Endogenous growth theory was pioneered by Romer (1986) who argue that economic growth is influenced by the level of human capital through technological advances, with the aggregate production function as follows: Y = F (A, K, L, H), where: A is technological advances, K is physical capital, H is human resources (accumulation of education and training), and L is workforce. This is also confirmed by Lucas (1988) who argues that in addition to physical capital, human capital accumulation is crucial for economic growth. On the other hand, Solow (1998) argues that capital only includes supplies plant and economic equipment; thus it is reasonable to assume diminishing returns. Investment in physical capital and workforce cannot be fully implemented independently (internalized) by investor. The existence of externalities can create increasing returns to scale, thus repairing the assumption of constant returns to scale used by the neoclassical model. RESEARCH METHODS This research uses positivistic paradigm by employing quantitative approach. The data used is pooled data, i.e. a combination of time series data in 2004-2007 and cross section (35 districts/ities in Central Java). The models were created by using econometric approach in the form of a system of simultaneous equations, consisting of 33 equations (24 structural equations and 9 identity equations). The models are divided into 6 blocks,

SULISTYOWATI, THE EFFECT OF EDUCATIONAL, HEALTH, INFRASTRUCTURE 123 namely: 1) human capital block, 2) input block (physical capital and sector workforce employment), 3) output block (GDP), 4) government revenue block, 5) regional expenses block (educational, health and infrastructure expenses), and 6) poverty block. The parameter estimation method uses a two stage least square (2SLS). The advantage of using 2SLS is among others offering consistent and efficient model (Koutsoyiannis, 1977). The estimation is performed by using the program of Statistical Analysis System/ Econometric Time Series (SAS/ETS) version 9.2 and the procedure of linear systems (SYSLIN). To test whether the explanatory variables jointly explain the diversity of the endogenous variables in each equation, the F statistical test is used, with a significance level ( ) of 1%. Meanwhile, to test whether each explanatory variable is individually influential or not to the endogenous variables in each equation, the statistical test t is used, with a significance level ( ) of 10%. The validation of estimation models uses the proportion of bias (UM) and Theil s Inequality coeficient (U Theil) with SIMNLIN procedures (Pindyck and Rubinfeld, 1991). This research employs a historical simulation (ex-post simulation) that consists of a range of possibilities for the following policies: (1) an increase in educational expenses by 20 billion rupiahs, (2) an increase in health expenses by 20 billion rupiahs, and (3) an increase in infrastructure expenses by 20 billion rupiahs. The research hypothesis states that government policies for education, health and infrastructure are expected to increase sector workforce employment and reduce poverty in Central Java. From the hypothesis an outline of research model framework is made as described in figure 2 below. Figure 2 illustrates that the increase on education and health expenses can improve the quality of human resources (human capital). On the other hand, infrastructure expenses can increase physical capital. Endogenous growth theory states that the increase on workforce, physical capital, and the quality of human resources (human capital) can increase the regional output (GDP). The increase in GDP can increase the workforce employment and may ultimately reduce unemployment and poverty. Besides, the increase in GDP can also boost government revenue. Increased government revenue leads to an increase in government expenses for education, health and infrastructure sectors. Increased government expenses budget will be a stimulus for various sectors to increase GDP, and so on; all variables mutually interact with each other in a system of simultaneous equations. Health expenses Educational expenses Infrastructur e expenses Human Capital Phisical Capital GDP Sector workforce employment Government revenue unemployment Poverty Figure 2. The Framework of Research Model RESULT AND DISCUSSION Results of equation parameter estimation of agricultural workforce employment have a coefficient of determination (R2) of 79.59%. Agricultural workforce employment is significantly influenced by the explanatory variables simultaneously (F statistic) with a value of 85.80. The results showed that agricultural workforce employment is significantly influenced by District/ Minimum Wage, agricultural GDP, workforce, district/ dummy and previous year s agricultural workforce employment, with the sign in accordance with the hypothesis. Further, the equation parameter estimation of agricultural workforce employment can be seen in the following Table 1. The minimum wage of district/ity (UMK) has a negative sign towards the agricultural workforce employment. Seen from the elasticity, the effect of UMK changes on the increase of the agricultural workforce employment in short term was unresponsive (inelastic), but in the long term it was responsive (elastic). In the short term any increase in UMK by 10% led to reduced demand for farm labor at 9.47%. While in the long term any increase in UMK by 10% led to the reduction of agricultural sector employment by 16.65%. This can happen due to the low quality of agricultural human resources, thus very susceptible to the termination of employment (PHK) as a result of an increase in UMK, as proposed by Ramos (1970). The increase in agricultural GDP has a significant and positive effect in improving agricultural workforce employment with a relatively small magnitude, both in the short and long terms. In the short term, any increase in agricultural GDP by 10% will increase agricultural employment by 1.75%. This is similar to the research conducted by Nanga (2006). Increased workforce also has positive and significant effect in increasing agricultural employment. In the short and long term, agricultural workforce employment has an inelastic response towards the total work force. This result is in line with research conducted by Rindayati (2007). In the short term, any increase in the work force by 10% will increase the agricultural workforce employment by 3.41 %. The minimum wage of district/ity (UMK) has a negative sign towards the agricultural workforce employment. Seen from the elasticity, the effect of UMK changes on the increase of the agricultural workforce employment in short term was unresponsive (inelastic), but in the long term it was responsive (elastic). In the short term any increase in UMK by 10% led to reduced demand for farm labor at 9.47%. While in the long term any increase in UMK by 10% led to the reduction of agricultural sector employment by 16.65%. This can happen due to the low quality of agricultural human resources, thus very susceptible to the termination of employment (PHK) as a result of an increase in UMK, as proposed by Ramos (1970). The increase in agricultural GDP has a significant and positive effect in improving agricultural workforce

124 International Journal of Administrative Science & Organization, September 2013 Volume 20, Number 3 Table 1. The Result of Equation Parameter Estimation of Agricultural Workforce Employment Variable Estimation parameter Prob >[t] Intersep 171732.1 0.0251 Minimum Wage of district / Agricultural GDP Short term Elasticity Long term elasticity -599595 0.0427-0.947-1.665 35.92333 0.0071 0.175 0.308 Workforce 0.119270 0.0009 0.341 0.600 District / Dummy -49767.9 0.0015 Time trend 2510.102 0.5336 Agricultural employment lag 0.431454 0.0001 Fhit = 85.80 Prob.F = 0.0001 Dw = 1.610385 R 2 = 0.79592 employment with a relatively small magnitude, both in the short and long terms. In the short term, any increase in agricultural GDP by 10% will increase agricultural employment by 1.75%. This is similar to the research conducted by Nanga (2006). Increased workforce also has positive and significant effect in increasing agricultural employment. In the short and long term, agricultural workforce employment has an inelastic response towards the total work force. This result is in line with research conducted by Rindayati (2007). In the short term, any increase in the work force by 10% will increase the agricultural workforce employment by 3.41 %. District/ dummy has a negative and significant sign towards agricultural workforce employment. This indicates that agricultural employment are more prevalent in the district (which is identical to the agricultural area) compared to the ity. Considering the low quality of workforce in agricultural sector, the government has an obligation to improve the quality of farmers through a range of counseling and training on technologies that can improve the productivity of farmers. The estimation result of equation parameter on industrial workforce employment has a coefficient of determination (R2) of 66.418%. Industrial employment is significantly affected by the explanatory variables, jointly indicated by the F statistic with the value of 52.61. The results showed that the industrial workforce employment is significantly influenced by industrial GDP, workforce, time trend, and previous year s industrial workforce employment, with a sign in accordance with the hypothesis. The complete result of equation parameter estimation on industrial workforce employment can be seen in table 2. As is the case with the agricultural sector, the increase in industrial GDP has a positive effect in increasing the industrial workforce employment. In the short and longterms, the industrial employment has an inelastic response to industrial GDP. Every 10% increase of industrial GDP Table 2. The Estimation Result of Equation Parameter on Industrial Workforce Employment Variable Estimation parameter Prob >[t] Intersep -4443.41 0.7341 Industrial GDP Short term Elasticity Long term elasticity 11.38713 0.0001 0.158 0.266 Workforce 0.095784 0.0001 0.433 0.728 District / Dummy -14761.8 0.1755 Time trend 4356.659 0.1097 Industrial employment lag 0.405330 0.0001 Fhit = 52.61 Prob.F = 0.0001 Dw = 1.408899 R 2 = 0.66418 will increase industrial employment by 1.58%, lower than the agricultural sector. The increase in workforce will increase the industrial employment that is inelastic both in the short and long terms. In the short-term, the increase in workforce by 10% will increase the industrial employment by 4.33%. Compared to agriculture, industrial employment is more responsive to the increase in workforce. It can be interpreted that the increase in a more educated workforce will better encourage the increase in industrial than agricultural employment. The estimation result of equation parameter on service workforce employment has a coefficient of determination (R2) of 86.7%. the service employment is significantly affected by the explanatory variables, jointly indicated by the F statistic with the value of 174.34. The results showed that the service workforce employment is significantly affected by the services GDP, workforce, district/ dummy, and previous year s service employment with a sign in accordance with the results of the hypothesis. The complete detail on the estimation result of equation parameter on service workforce employment can be seen in the following table 3. Table 3. The Estimation Result of Equation Parameter on Service Workforce Employment Variable Estimation parameter Prob >[t] Intersep -52304.5 0.0001 Service GDP Short term Elasticity Long term elasticity 9.256525 0.0001 0.086 0.098 Workforce 0.350446 0.0001 1.028 1.171 District / Dummy 65901.58 0.0001 Time trend 517.2909 0.8217 Service employment lag 0.121977 0.0054 Fhit = 174.34 Prob.F = 0.0001 Dw = 0.967161 R 2 = 0.86762

SULISTYOWATI, THE EFFECT OF EDUCATIONAL, HEALTH, INFRASTRUCTURE 125 Similar to agricultural and industrial sectors, the increase in services GDP has a significant and positive influence to the increase in service workforce employment. In the short and long-term, services employment has an inelastic response to changes in services GDP. In the short term, the increase in services GDP by 10% can improve service workforce employment by 0.86%, lower than the agricultural and industrial sectors. Increased workforce has a significant and positive effect on services workforce employment. In contrast to the agricultural and industrial sectors, services employment in the short and long term has an elastic response to changes in workforce. In the short term, any increase in workforce by 10% will increase the services employment by 10.28%, while in the long term any increase in workforce by 10% will increase services employment by 11.71%. District/ dummy has a positive and significant sign towards the services workforce employment. This suggests that services employment are widely available in urban than rural areas. This condition is different from the agricultural and industrial sectors that employ more workforce from rural areas. The estimation result of poverty equation parameter indicates the coefficient of determination (R2) of 88.8%. Poverty is significantly influenced by the explanatory variables, jointly indicated by the F statistic with the value of 128.5. The estimation result of the parameter indicates that poverty is significantly influenced by household expenditure per capita, income distribution, poverty line, population number, the share of agricultural workforce, district/ dummy, time trend, and previous year s poverty with the sign consistent with the hypothesis. Further details on the estimation result of poverty equation parameter can be seen in table 4 below. In terms of elasticity magnitude, the increase in the household expenditure per capita has the greatest Table 4. The Estimation Result of Poverty Equation Parameter Variable Estimation parameter Prob >[t] Intersep -25106.1 0.7262 Household expenditure per capita Short term Elasticity Long term elasticity -3.433E8 0.0001-1.595-2.361 Gini Index 342415.2 0.0716 0.422 0.625 Poverty line 2499804 0.0001 1.147 1.699 Population number The share of agricultural workforce District / dummy 0.173885 0.0001 0.826 1.223 877.5121 0.0094 0.158 0.233 109214.9 0.0001 Time trend -19791.3 0.0001 Poverty Lag 0.324639 0.0001 Fhit = 128.50 Prob.F = 0.0001 Dw = 1.37782 R 2 = 0.88773 magnitude in reducing poverty. Poverty has an elastic response to the household expenditure per capita, both in short and long terms. In the short term, any increase in household expenditure by 10% will reduce poverty by 15.95%. This may imply that the increase in the household expenditure per capita will lead to reduced poverty. It is quite logical considering the household expenditure is a function of household income. Income inequality (Gini index) has a significant and positive effect on poverty, with a relatively small magnitude (inelastic). In the short term, any reduction in the Gini index by 10% will reduce poverty by 4.22%. These result is in line with research conducted by Nanga (2006). Increased poverty line was responsive in increasing poverty, both in short and long terms. In the short-term, any increase in the poverty line of 10% will increase poverty by 11.47%. In the long term, any increase in the poverty line by 10% will increase poverty by 16.99%. The poverty line that is too low will make the poverty number seem small, although in reality it is not. It can be used by the rulers (government) to claim their success in reducing poverty. The increase of population number has a significant and positive effect on the increasing poverty in Central Java. Although in the short term poverty is not responsive to the population number, in the long run it will be responsive. In the short term, any increase in the population number of ten 10% will increase poverty by 8.26%. In the long term, any increase in the population number of ten 10% will increase poverty by 12.23%. These conditions suggests that the increase in the population number in Central Java is still a burden for the development. Considering its important role for the success of regional/central development, the improvement of human resources then must get serious treatment from both regional/central governments. Based on the elasticity, the share of agricultural workforce has a positive effect in increasing the number of poor people, despite having a relatively small magnitude. In the short term, any increase in the share of agricultural workforce of 10% will increase poverty by 1.63%. Compared to the industrial and services sectors, the agricultural sector has the lowest level of workforce productivity. The low productivity of agricultural workforce has an impact on the low income and welfare of farmers. Such result supports the research by Pradhan et al. (2000), affirming that agriculture is a sector that has the highest poverty rate than other sectors. The first simulation, the increase in educational expenses of twenty billion rupiahs will result in the following effects (table 5). Table 5 shows that an increase in educational expenses does not directly influence the increase of GDP, all sectors employment, and the reduction of unemployment and poverty. Increased workforce employm ent is mostly enjoyed respectively by industrial sectors of 2.56%, services sector of 0.85% and agricultural sector of 0.67%. Overall, the increase in educational expenses by 20 billion rupiahs, led to the increase of workforce employment from 452,779 people to 458,268 people (a

126 International Journal of Administrative Science & Organization, September 2013 Volume 20, Number 3 Table 5. The Simulation Result of the Increased Government Expenses for Education by 20 Billion Rupiahs towards Workforce Employment and Poverty Endogenous Variable (unit) Basic value Simulation Value GDP (billion IDR/year) 4248.1 4556 7.25 Agricultural workforce Industrial workforce 170549 171690 0.67 113944 116865 2.56 Services workforce 168286 169713 0.85 Total workforce employment 452779 458268 1.21 Change (%) Unemployment 32662.5 27173.2-16.81 Poverty 102503 81716.6-20.28 1.21% increase). The result suggests that an increase in educational expenses was more lucrative for industrial and services sectors in urban areas than agricultural sector in rural areas. If the government aims to reduce poverty, the regional government should increase the budget allocation for education in rural areas. The improved economic performance due to an increase in educational expenses resulted in the increase of public welfare. It is characterized by the declining unemployment number, from 32,662 people into 27,173 people, reduced by 16.81% and the number of poor people fell from 102,503 people into 81,716 people, reduced by 20.28%. The results of this study suggest the importance of government intervention in improving public welfare through allocating the effective educational budget in order to improve the quality of life and well-being of society. The second simulation, the increase in government expenses for Health of twenty billion rupiahs will result in the following (table 6). In Table 6 it appears that the increase in health expenses Table 6. The Simulation Result of the Increased Government Expenses for Health by 20 Billion Rupiahs towards Workforce Employment and Poverty has no direct effect in increasing the GDP and all sectors employment, as well as reducing unemployment and poverty. The increase in GDP caused the company to increase its production capacity and increase the number of new jobs to boost workforce employment. This policy is most beneficial for the industrial sector since when viewed from the percentage of changes, it causes the greatest industrial workforce employment, absorbing 113,944 people than previously only 117,656 people, up by 3.26 %. The service sector followed, then, rising 1.09 %, shadowed by the agricultural sector that rose by 0.82%. Overall, the increase of health expenses by twenty billion rupiahs led to the increased workforce employment from 452,779 people to 459,718 people, or up by 1.53%. In line with the first simulation, the increase in health expenses is also much more profitable for industrial and services sectors (non-agricultural sector) as compared to agricultural sector. The result also supports the notion that compared with the non-agricultural sectors, the agricultural sector was the least benefited from the success of development. The improved economic performance resulted in the increased well-being of society, as can be seen from several indicators, i.e. the declining unemployment number from 32,663 unemployed people into 25,724 people, reduced by 21.24% and a decrease in the number of the poor from 102,503 people into 74,554 people, reduced by 27.27%. The third simulation, the increase in expenses for infrastructure of twenty billion rupiahs will result in the following effects (table 7). Table 7 states that an increase in infrastructure expenses was indirectly influential in increasing the output (GDP). The increase in output causes increased employment, thus resulted in increased workforce absorption. The result suggests that the industrial sector was the most benefited in workforce employment, from 113,944 people to 118,111 people, or up by 3.66%; followed by the agricultural sector, experiencing an increase of 1.57%, shadowed by services sector, with an increase of 0.76%. In terms of workforce employment, different from the educational and health expenses, the increased Table 7. The Simulation Result of the Increased Government Expenses for Infrastructure by 20 Billion Rupiahs towards Workforce Employment and Poverty Endogenous Variable (unit) Basic value Simulation Value Change (%) Endogenous Variable (unit) Basic value Simulation Value Change (%) GDP (billion IDR/year) 4248.1 4639.8 9.22 Agricultural workforce Industrial workforce 170549 171947 0.82 113944 117656 3.26 Services workforce 168286 170115 1.09 Total workforce employment 452779 459718 1.53 Unemployment 32662.5 25724-21.24 Poverty 102503 74554.3-27.27 GDP (billion IDR/year) 4248.1 4631.6 9.03 Agricultural workforce Industrial workforce 170549 173229 1.57 113944 118111 3.66 Services workforce 168286 169558 0.76 Total workforce employment 452779 460898 1.79 Unemployment 32662.5 24544.1-24.86 Poverty 102503 80848.2-21.13

SULISTYOWATI, THE EFFECT OF EDUCATIONAL, HEALTH, INFRASTRUCTURE 127 infrastructure expenses was most profitable respectively for industrial, agricultural and, services sectors. The improved economic performance due to increased infrastructure expenses was implicated to increased public welfare. It can be seen from several indicators, i.e. reduced unemployment from 32,663 people into 24,544 people, declined by 24.86% and declined poverty from 102,503 people into 80,848 people, reduced by 21.13%. The aforementioned three policy simulation results conclude that similar absolute value, and the increase in health expenses give the best result in increasing GDP, and services workforce employment, as well as reducing poverty. While the increase in infrastructure expenses gives the best result in improving the industrial and agricultural workforce employment and reduce unemployment. The required economic growth is one, capable not only to increase output, but at the same time can also reduce unemployment and poverty. The results of this study indicate that the policy of increasing educational, health and infrastructure expenses, in addition to increasing the output can also increase all sector workforce employment and reduce poverty in Central Java. CONCLUSION Agricultural workforce employment is significantly influenced by District/ Minimum Wage, agricultural GDP, workforce, district/ dummy and previous year s agricultural employment. The increase in agricultural GDP by 10% will increase agricultural workforce employment by 1.75 %. Industrial workforce employment is significantly affected by industrial GDP, workforce, and previous year s industrial employment. The increase in industrial GDP by 10% will increase industrial workforce employment by 1.58%, lower than the agricultural sector. Services workforce employment is significantly affected by services GDP, workforce, district/ dummy, and previous year s services employment. The increase in services GDP by 10% will improve services workforce employment by 0.86%, lower than the agricultural and industrial sectors. Poverty is significantly influenced by household expenditure per capita, income distribution, poverty line, population number, the share of agricultural workforce, district/ dummy, time trend and previous year s poverty. Increased household expenditure per capita of 10% will reduce poverty by 15.95%. The simulation results of educational, health and infrastructure expense policies with similar nominal value showed an increase in GDP, and all sector workforce employment, as well as a reduction of poverty. The increased health expenses has the most significant contribution to the increased GDP, services workforce employment and the reduced poverty. While the policy of increasing infrastructure expenses most significantly improves industrial and agricultural workforce employment, and reduces unemployment. Policies to increase educational and health expenses give the greatest effect on the workforce employment, most widely enjoyed by respectively sectors of industry, services and agriculture. While the policy of increasing infrastructure expenses most significantly affects the workforce employment in respectively sectors of industry, agriculture and services. Poverty needs to be reduced by a variety of programs that can improve people s productivity and income. The implication of policy for addressing poverty is to improve the quality of human resources by opening access to education and training as much as possible for the community, so that they are able to manage the existing natural resources, increase their productivity, improve their economic welfare and expand employment opportunities, as well as control the population number. For subsequent research, it is recommended to conduct treatment differentiation (disaggregation) on districts and ities to determine the effect of policies for the two areas, and to include all aspects of Human Development Index as part of the assessment of development performance, in addition to forecasting through historical simulation. REFERENCES Canagarajah, S. and Coulombe, H. 1997. Child Labor and Schooling in Ghana.Policy Research Working Paper 1844. Washington D.C :The World Bank. Capello, R. 2007. Regional Economics. New York: Routledge Taylor and Francis Group. Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS). 2009. Jawa Tengah dalam Angka. BPS Provinsi Jawa Tengah and BAPPEDA Provinsi Jawa Tengah, Semarang. Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS). 2012. Jawa Tengah dalam Angka. BPS Provinsi Jawa Tengah and BAPPEDA Provinsi Jawa Tengah, Semarang. Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS). 2012. Data dan Informasi Kemiskinan Kabupaten/Kotamadya 2011. BPS Provinsi Jawa Tengah, Semarang. Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS). 2012. Indeks Pembangunan Manusia, Keterkaitan antara IPM, IPG dan IGD. BPS Provinsi Jawa Tengah, Semarang. Duff, L. 1997.The Economics of Governments and Markets. New York :Longman. Hartati, E.S. 2012. Dampak Kompisisi Belanja Pemerintah terhadap Pertumbuhan Ekonomi, Kesempatan Kerja, dan Tingkat Kemiskinan. Doctoral Dissertation. Sekolah Pascasarjana, Institut Pertanian Bogor, Bogor. Kasliwal, P. 1995. Development Economics. Ohio: South Western College Publishing. Koutsoyiannis, A. 1977. Theory of Econometrics: An Introductory Exposition of Econometric Methods. London: MacMillan Press Ltd. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1988. On the Mechanics of Economic Development. Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22, Number 1 (July). Nanga, M. 2006. Dampak Transfer Fiskal terhadap Kemiskinan di Indonesia: Suatu Analisis Simulation Kebijakan. Doctoral Dissertation. Sekolah Pascasarjana, Institut Pertanian Bogor, Bogor. Mankiw, N.G. 2003. Macroeconomics. Fifth Edition. New York: Worth Publishers.

128 International Journal of Administrative Science & Organization, September 2013 Volume 20, Number 3 Pindyck, R.S. and D.L. Rubinfield. 1991. Econometric Model and Economic Forecast. Singapore: McGraw- Hill International Edition. Pradhan, M., A. Suryahadi, S. Sumarto and L. Pritchett. 2000. Measurements of Poverty in Indonesia: 1996, 1999 and Beyond. Policy Research Working Paper 2438.The World Bank, Washington D.C. Ramos.J.R.1970.A Survey of Agricultural Economic Literature. USA: University of Minnesota Press. Rindayati, W. 2008. Dampak Desentralisasi Fiskal terhadap Kemiskinan dan Ketahanan Pangan di Wilayah Provinsi Jawa Barat. Doctoral Dissertation. Sekolah Pascasarjana, Institut Pertanian Bogor, Bogor. Romer, P.M. 1986. Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth. Journal of Political Economy, Vol.94, No.5 (October). Saariluoma, P. 2005. The Challenges and Opportunities of Human Technology. Journal of Human Technology, Vol.1, No. 1 (April). Schultz, T.W. 1961. Investment in Human Capital. The American Economic Review, Vol.1, No.2 (March). Sulistyowati, N. 2011. Dampak Investasi Sumberdaya Manusia terhadap Perekonomian dan Kesejahteraan Masyarakat di Jawa Tengah. Doctoral Dissertation. Sekolah Pascasarjana, Institut Pertanian Bogor, Bogor. Suryahadi, A., Priyambada and S. Sumarto. 2005. Poverty, School and Work: Children during the Economic Crisis in Indonesia. Development and Change, Vol. 36, No.2 (March). Solow, Robert M. 1998. Work and Welfare. New Jersey : Princeton University Press.