Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Similar documents
No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

Part II: Economic Growth. Part I: LRAS

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

Learning objectives. The Science of Macroeconomics slide 1. Important issues in macroeconomics

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

BA5101 ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS MBA/IYear/ I Semester 2 Marks Questions & Answers

Lecture 20 Phillips Curve Price Stickiness. Noah Williams

Introduction [to Recent Developments in the Theory of Involuntary Unemployment]

Agenda. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis, Part 3. Disequilibrium in the AD-AS model

PIER Working Paper

Business Cycle Theory Revised: March 25, 2009

Lecture 18 The Keynesian Model. Noah Williams

Chapter 1 The Science of Macroeconomics

Estimation of a DSGE Model Lawrence J. Christiano

Central European University Department of Economics. 2. Lecturer Attila Ratfai (Part 2 of the course is taught by Alessia Campolmi)

LESSON 9. Economic Fluctuations: Balancing Aggregate Demand and Supply

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

On Macroeconomic Theories and Modeist

Lecture 11: Real Business Cycles

Cambridge University Press Modeling Monetary Economies, Second Edition - Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman Excerpt More information.

Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality

Copyright 2017 by the UBC Real Estate Division

real rigidities The definition of real rigidities Real rigidities and business cycles

Chapter 1: Ten Principles of Economics Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY ANALYSIS

Interest and the Length of

Monetary Business Cycle Models: Imperfect Information

1 TEN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS

DISSERTATION ABSTRACT. Essays on Economic Growth and Development: New Perspectives from Health, Education, and Wealth. Kei Hosoya

Chapter 9 Shocks. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 145

An Experimental Comparison of Posted Prices with Single-Buyer and Multi-Buyer Prices

Trend inflation, inflation targets and inflation expectations

TEACHING MICRO AND MACRO AS SEPARATE COURSES

Intermediate Microeconomics INTRODUCTION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

ECO-401 Economics Online Quiz 5

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

Discussion of: Structural Models of Inflation Dynamics. By Lawrence J. Christiano

Wallingford Public Schools - HIGH SCHOOL COURSE OUTLINE

Specific Learning Goals/Benchmarks and Student Assessment. AP Macroeconomics

Dynamics of Price Adjustments: Evidence from Micro Level data for Chile

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

September 2006 REAL RIGIDITIES * David Romer University of California, Berkeley

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2015 series 9708 ECONOMICS

Behavioral Macroeconomics. Emi Nakamura Columbia University

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2010 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011

These examples suggest that he and I have had professional disputes. It generated a lot of interest. Meltzer and I were dubious but could not

DOWNLOAD PDF JOB SEARCH IN A DYNAMIC ECONOMY

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

Reply to the Referees John J. Seater 15 April 2008

Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money

Ryan Oprea. Economics 176

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

Economics Lecture notes- Semester 1:

Advanced Macroeconomic Theory I: Syllabus


Classical Macroeconomic Theory and Economic Growth

Chapter 2--Observing and Explaining the Economy

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory, 01/07/2003. A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

Applied Economics Journal Vol. 21 No. 2 (December 2014): Copyright 2014 Center for Applied Economics Research ISSN

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

E ciency Wages. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

2 THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

MACROECONOMICS. N. Gregory Mankiw. The Science of Macroeconomics 8/2/2011. In this chapter, you will learn: Important issues in macroeconomics

Curriculum Vitae. Andrew G. Atkeson

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

Chapter 1: Ten Principles of Economics Principles of Economics, 4 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

New Zealand Economics Competition

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

CORRICULUM VITAE. (December, 2017) NAME: Kenneth Burdett. NATIONALITY: British

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

FIFTH EDITION B BARRON'S. Walter J.Wessels. BUSINESS REVIEW BOOKS Economics

The Interchange Fee Mysteries Commentary on Evans and Schmalensee

Fixed and flexible prices

Section 1 Guided Reading and Practice: Basic Economic Concepts

ECON 2100 (Summer 2014 Sections 08 & 09) Exam #1D

Neoclassical economics (1890s 1930s)

Chapter 1. Preliminaries. Introduction. What is math? History? Music? What is ECONOMICS? What is MICROECONOMICS? Chapter 1 2

Chapter 26 Answers to Short-Answer, Essays, and Problems

Price Rigidity and Wage Rigidity: Market Failure or Market Efficiency

Productivity or Signaling?

Economics is the study of how society manages and allocates its scarce resources. Scarcity refers to society s limited number of resources

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results *

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing

The Principles and Practice of Economics

A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

The History of Expectations in Macroeconomics

Sponsored Search Markets

ECONOMICS 103. Dr. Emma Hutchinson, Fall 2017

THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

Managing Aggregate Liquidity: The Role of a Central Bank Digital Currency

Derived copy of The Building Blocks of Keynesian Analysis *

Principles of Macroeconomics, 11e - TB1 (Case/Fair/Oster) Chapter 2 The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

Transcription:

ECONOMIC POLICY PAPER 16-02 JANUARY 2016 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Many economists believe that prices are sticky they adjust slowly. This stickiness, they suggest, means that changes in the money supply have an impact on the real economy, inducing changes in investment, employment, output and consumption, an effect that can be exploited by policymakers. In this essay, we argue that price stickiness doesn t necessarily generate an exploitable policy option. We describe a model in which money is neutral (that is, growth or reduction in money supply doesn t impact real economic activity) even in a context of sluggish price adjustment. Are Prices Sticky and Does It Matter? Even if prices are slow to adjust, this doesn t necessarily mean that monetary policy can be used to stimulate or slow economic activity Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Introduction Here are two venerable questions in macroeconomic theory and policy analysis: Are prices sticky? Does it matter? By sticky prices, we mean the observation that some sellers set prices in nominal terms that do not adjust quickly in response to changes in the aggregate price level or to changes in economic conditions more generally. Some macroeconomics as taught in the classroom and used in practice makes the assumption that nominal prices are sticky and then proceeds to derive policy implications. In this essay, we want to challenge the idea that these policy implications are necessarily correct (even if prices are sticky). Classical macroeconomics embodied the idea that money is neutral that is, increasing or decreasing the quantity of money in an economy has no impact on real economic activity such as investment, production, consumption or hiring. If money is neutral, it is not clear what monetary policy can do. 1 Some economists dispute classical neutrality. They argue that nominal prices are sticky, at least in the short run, and that this 1

has significant consequences for the real economy. 2 The exact consequences depend on details, but many models of this school of thought have this effect: If buyers have more money and sellers keep their prices the same, the former will demand more goods and services and the latter (by assumption) will supply them. This generates an increase in investment, employment, output and consumption. The counterargument is that putting more cash in people s hands is like adding a zero to every bill; that is, a one-dollar bill becomes a 10-dollar bill, a 10 becomes a 100 and so on. Some economists say that this ought not have a real impact, any more than changing the way temperature is measured from Fahrenheit to Celsius would it s just units! Many economists point out, however, that sticky prices are what we observe empirically and, indeed, there is an element of truth in their argument (see Klenow and Malin 2010 for a survey of empirical work). Then we might ask, why do some sellers set prices in nominal terms that do not adjust in response to changes in economic conditions? This seems to fly in the face of elementary economic theory. Shouldn t every seller have a unique target relative price, depending on real factors, so that when the aggregate price level increases due to an increase in the money supply, every seller necessarily adjusts his or her nominal price by the same amount? In many popular macro models, including those used by most policymakers, prices are sticky by assumption, in the sense that there are either restrictions on how often they can change, following Taylor (1980) or Calvo (1983), or there are real resource costs to changing them, following Rotemberg (1982) or Mankiw (1985). It is true in principle that a cost is incurred in changing a price the so-called menu cost even if this cost is merely a piece of chalk. A notable feature of these models, though, is that at their core they require a cost only for price changes, but ignore all other potential transaction costs such as changing one s quantity, password, clothes or mind. Or they simply impose by decree that a seller can adjust price only at a few points in time determined by pure chance. Stickiness as a result, not assumption Here we describe a theory that generates price stickiness as a result, not an assumption, even if sellers can change price whenever they like at no cost. But in strong contrast with theories assuming sticky prices, this theory implies that money is neutral, so a central bank cannot engineer a boom or end a slump simply by printing currency. Our main goal in describing this theory is not, however, simply to establish that prices are sticky or that money is neutral. Rather, our point is that the observation of sluggish price adjustment does not logically imply that money 2

is nonneutral. Nor does it imply that we need to focus predominately on macro models that incorporate menu costs or related devices. 3 In two recent papers, Head et al. (2012) and Liu et al. (2014), we propose simple models with the following features. Due to frictions in credit, including lack of commitment and imperfect monitoring or record keeping, buyers sometimes need to use money. (This part of the theory is based on Lagos and Wright 2005. 4 ) For the market in which buyers and sellers trade, we borrow the classic model of frictional good markets developed by Burdett and Judd (1983). That model, based on search frictions, delivers price dispersion and has proved useful in many other applications, including the large literature on labor markets following Burdett and Mortensen (1998). 5 To understand the Burdett-Judd model, it helps to first review the earliest search models, where buyers sampled sellers sequentially until they found one selling at a price below the highest price buyers were willing to pay. Burdett and Judd modify Diamond s (1971) classic search model, which, problematically, had no price dispersion. 6 Burdett and Judd s one (ostensibly minimal) change to the Diamond model is this: Rather than sampling prices one at a time, as Diamond had it, buyers in the Burdett-Judd model have a positive probability of sampling two or more prices at the same time. If all sellers set the same price, a buyer is indifferent to choosing one over another and must use some tie-breaking rule to pick. This, of course, gives an individual seller a huge incentive to shave his or her price to get the sale. In fact, Burdett and Judd find that, in the model s equilibrium, all sellers charge different prices: price dispersion. When Burdett-Judd pricing is embedded into a monetary model, sellers post prices in dollars, since this is how buyers are paying. At any date, there is a range of posted prices for which sellers will get the same profit. While the model pins down the distribution of prices, it does not set the price for any individual seller. Why not? A low price generates less profit per sale, but makes up for that low profit generation through sales volume, because a sale is more likely from any buyer who samples a low price. If the money supply increases, the equilibrium price distribution shifts up, but this new distribution can overlap with the previous range of prices. This means that some (but not all) sellers must change their prices. If an individual seller s price falls outside the range of prices that sellers will charge after the increase of money supply, it must adjust; but if it is still in the range of new prices, it may not. 3

Now, recall the question posed earlier: Shouldn t every seller have a target real price and, therefore, when the money supply increases, shouldn t every seller adjust his or her nominal price by the same amount? The answer is no. Sellers do not have a unique target price. The model s equilibrium requires a distribution of prices, all of which yield the same profit. If sellers do not change their price when money supply increases, they indeed earn less profit per unit, but again they make it up on the volume. Hence, sellers can change prices infrequently in the face of continuous movements in economic conditions, even though they are allowed to change whenever they like at no cost. But the crucial point is this: Policy cannot exploit this price stickiness because the distribution of relative prices is pinned down uniquely. The level of the money supply and the aggregate price level are irrelevant it is simply a choice of units. This is classical neutrality. Conclusion Our point is that money is not necessarily nonneutral just because prices are sticky. Moreover, a calibrated version of the model can match quite well the empirical behavior of price changes. These points are not widely known (or accepted, by those who are aware of them). Ball and Mankiw (1994), to provide a view representative of a wide segment of the economics profession, say: Sticky prices provide the most natural explanation of monetary nonneutrality since so many prices are, in fact, sticky. They add, moreover, that based on microeconomic evidence, we believe that sluggish price adjustment is the best explanation for monetary nonneutrality, and as a matter of logic, nominal stickiness requires a cost of nominal adjustment. 7 We interpret these claims by Ball and Mankiw to contain three points related, respectively, to empirics, theory and policy, and our responses to the claims encapsulate our argument regarding monetary neutrality, or lack thereof. Their first claim is that price stickiness is a fact. We agree. Their second claim is that price stickiness implies as a matter of logic the existence of some technological constraints to price adjustment. The theory outlined above proves this wrong by displaying equilibria that match not only the broad observation of stickiness, but the detailed empirical findings, with no such constraints. Their third claim is that stickiness implies that money is not neutral and that this justifies certain policy prescriptions. This is again proved wrong. The theory we ve just discussed is consistent with the relevant observations, but money is neutral. Thus, sticky prices do not constitute definitive evidence that money is nonneutral or that particular policy recommendations are warranted. 4

Endnotes 1 To state this notion with simple math: Suppose the economy starts in an equilibrium with money supply M, nominal price level P and real allocation (consumption, investment, employment and so on) X. Then change M to M. There is now an equilibrium with price level P, in which M /P =M/P and X is unchanged. Hence, the change in M has no effect on anything real. 2 Stated mathematically: When M changes to M, it is not possible for P to change to P at least in the short run. Therefore M/P will not stay the same, and that has real consequences for X. 3 Our argument is somewhat analogous to that made by Robert Lucas in his famous 1972 paper. He describes a model consistent with the empirical observation that there is a positive correlation between the aggregate price level (or money supply) and output (or employment), but policymakers in this model cannot systematically exploit the relationship: Increasing inflation by printing money at a faster rate will not increase average output or employment. Similarly, we argue that one can design a model consistent with observations concerning nominal price adjustment, but it is not possible for policymakers to systematically exploit this. 4 See Lagos et al. (2015) for a recent survey of the literature on monetary economic theory. 5 See Mortensen and Pissarides (1999) for a survey of this literature. 6 In Diamond s model, firms post prices, taken as given the prices of others, and then buyers search as described above. This model doesn t generate price dispersion problematic for a theory depending on buyers and sellers searching for one another. This finding set off a wave of research to generate endogenous price dispersion. 7 Somewhat similarly, Golosov and Lucas (2003) say that menu costs are really there: The fact that many individual goods prices remain fixed for weeks or months in the face of continuously changing demand and supply conditions testifies conclusively to the existence of a fixed cost of repricing. Our point here is not to pick on any particular individuals, but to provide some representative views in the profession. References Ball, L., and N. Mankiw. 1994. A Sticky-Price Manifesto. Working Paper 4677. National Bureau of Economic Research. Burdett, K., and K. Judd. 1983. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Econometrica 51, 955-69. Burdett, K., and D. Mortensen. 1998. Wage Differentials, Employer Size, and Unemployment. International Economic Review 39, 257-73. Calvo, G. 1983. Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383-98. Diamond, P. 1971. A Model of Price Adjustment. Journal of Economic Theory 2, 156-68. Golosov, M., and R. Lucas. 2003. Menu Costs and Phillips Curves. Working Paper 10187. National Bureau of Economic Research. Head, A., L. Liu, G. Menzio and R. Wright. 2012. Sticky Prices: A New Monetarist Approach. Journal of European Economic Association 10, 939-73. Klenow, P., and B. Malin. 2010. Microeconomic Evidence on Price-Setting. In Handbook of Monetary Economics, B. Friedman and M. Woodford, eds. Lagos, R., G. Rocheteau and R. Wright. 2015. Liquidity: A New Monetarist Perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, forthcoming. Lagos, R., and R. Wright. 2005. A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis. Journal of Political Economy 113, 463-84. 5

Liu, L., L. Wang and R. Wright. 2014. Costly Credit and Sticky Prices. mimeo. Lucas, R. 1972. Expectations and the Neutrality of Money. Journal of Economic Theory 4, 103-24. Mankiw, N. 1985. Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeconomic Model. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 529-38. Mortensen, D., and C. Pissarides. 1999. New Developments in Models of Search in the Labor Market. Handbook of Labor Economics, O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds. Rotemberg, J. 1982. Sticky Prices in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 90, 1187-1211. Taylor, J. 1980. Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88, 1-23. Economic Policy Papers are based on policy-oriented research produced by Minneapolis Fed staff and consultants. The papers are an occasional series for a general audience. The views expressed here are those of the authors, not necessarily those of others in the Federal Reserve System. Endnotes 1 To state this notion with simple math: Suppose the economy starts in an equilibrium with money supply M, nominal price level P and real allocation (consumption, investment, employment and so on) X. Then change M to M. There is now an equilibrium with price level P, in which M /P =M/P and X is unchanged. Hence, the change in M has no effect on anything real. 2 Stated mathematically: When M changes to M, it is not possible for P to change to P at least in the short run. Therefore M/P will not stay the same, and that has real consequences for X. 3 Our argument is somewhat analogous to that made by Robert Lucas in his famous 1972 paper. He describes a model consistent with the empirical observation that there is a positive correlation between the aggregate price level (or money supply) and output (or employment), but policymakers in this model cannot systematically exploit the relationship: Increasing inflation by printing money at a faster rate will not increase average output or employment. Similarly, we argue that one can design a model consistent with observations concerning nominal price adjustment, but it is not possible for policymakers to systematically exploit this. 4 See Lagos et al. (2015) for a recent survey of the literature on monetary economic theory. 5 See Mortensen and Pissarides (1999) for a survey of this literature. 6 In Diamond s model, firms post prices, taken as given the prices of others, and then buyers search as described above. This model doesn t generate price dispersion problematic for a theory depending on buyers and sellers searching for one another. This finding set off a wave of research to generate endogenous price dispersion. 7 Somewhat similarly, Golosov and Lucas (2003) say that menu costs are really there: The fact that many individual goods prices remain fixed for weeks or months in the face of continuously changing demand and sup 6