Submission to inquiry into the retirement of coal fired power stations

Similar documents
Brown coal exit: A market mechanism for regulated closure of highly emissions intensive power stations

SUBMISSION TO THE HOUSE STANDING COMMITTEE ON ECONOMICS: INQUIRY INTO THE CLEAN ENERGY AMENDMENT BILLS 2012

Brown coal exit: a market mechanism for regulated closure of highly emissions intensive power stations

CONSULTATION ON THE OPERATION OF THE SAFEGUARD MECHANISM

Fact Sheet > ELECTRICITY PRICES THE FACTS. Electricity Prices > August 2010

Interim Emissions Reduction Targets for Victoria ( )

Queensland Renewable Energy Expert Panel Issues Paper

Thank you for the opportunity to make a formal submission responding to the All things considered options paper.

PROPOSAL OF INDEPENDENT POWER PRODUCERS OF NEW YORK, INC. FOR INTEGRATING CARBON PRICING INTO THE WHOLESALE ENERGY MARKET

Submission on Special Review Second Draft Report Australia s climate policy options

MINERALS COUNCIL OF AUSTRALIA

Submission to Independent Expert Panel on Interim Targets. May 2018

Australia s energy future in Asia

EFET Response to EC Consultation on. Structural Options to Strengthen the EU Emissions Trading System. 28 th February 2013

Working Paper No. 4. November 2018

About Energy UK. Introduction

The science of climate change

Coal power infrastructures, policy coherence and the EU: Evaluating lessons from current policies

Climate Café: Why is Australia's electricity system in such a mess?

Mr Craig Price Group Manager, Planning Australian Energy Market Operator GPO Box 2008 Melbourne VIC 3001

RESIDENTIAL ENERGY Roadmap

Re: Response to the Draft Energy White Paper

Climate Action Network-International submission to the AWG-LCA 1. mitigation actions. 21 February 2011

FOREWORD. Dear Reader

POLICY GUIDELINES by the Energy Community Secretariat

MINERALS COUNCIL OF AUSTRALIA

About Environment Victoria. Overview. 28 February, By

Climate Change Position Statement and 2020 Action Plan

Tracking progress to net zero emissions

June 14, Dear Minister McKenna:

04 April Public Governance, Performance and Accountability Act Dear Ms Alexander and Mr Thodey

Inquiry into solar feed-in pricing in Queensland

Emissions Trading, Renewable Energy Targets and the Way Ahead

Submission to the Victorian Competition and Efficiency Commission Feed in Tariff Inquiry

Congress, Congressional Research Service, , R41836, The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: Lessons Learned and Issues for Congress.

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL. The state of the European carbon market in (Text with EEA relevance)

Emissions Reduction Fund: Safeguard Mechanism Consultation Paper. submission

Modelling of Australia s National Energy Guarantee

How? Establish a global power sector carbon budget

Carbon Market Institute Business Roundtable. Tas Sakellaris Department of Climate Change and Energy Efficiency

RE: Enhancing Victoria s Economic Performance and Productivity Discussion Paper

EPA Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft: The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 Executive Summary April 20, 2009

The Fifth Assessment Report of the IPCC: Transformation pathways: technologies for climate change mitigation

Conventional delivery of services is being upended across industry sectors by technology and customer preferences.

Canada s Clean Fuel Standard The role of low carbon fuels in decarbonising transport: the emerging consensus from international initiatives

Research Projects as of March 27, 2018

25th March The Secretary Senate Standing Committee on Economics PO Box 6100 Parliament House CANBERRA ACT

Joint submission on the National Energy Guarantee: Commonwealth Elements

Emission reductions: Costs:

A workable roadmap for Australia s climate change policies

How developing countries can prosper in a rapidly decarbonising world

Joint Study Session on Carbon Reduction

European Commission DG Energy Unit B2: Wholesale markets, electricity & gas Office: DM24, 6th floor Rue De Mot 24 B 1049 Brussels/Belgium

REA Response to the BEIS committee Inquiry: Brexit negotiation priorities for energy and climate change policy

Royal Society response to Defra review of the UK Climate Change Programme

Energy Department Report on Electricity Markets and Reliability

Share of global GHG emissions. GHG emissions per capita. (tco

The impact of wind on electricity prices in the Australian National Electricity Market

Getting to Zero. Climate Action Points

Opening Statement to Joint Committee on Climate Action. Mark Griffin, Secretary General, Department of Communications, Climate Action and Environment

GHG emissions per capita. (tco 2. e/cap) Source: UNDP, data for 2015 Source: World Bank Indicators, data for 2012 Source: IEA, data for 2013

A UK Perspective on Carbon Markets

PATHWAYS TO DEEP DECARBONISATION IN 2050:

PATHWAYS TO DEEP DECARBONISATION IN 2050:

POLICY BRIEF. The Lieberman-Warner America's Climate Security Act: A Preliminary Assessment of Potential Economic Impacts

CLIMATE CHANGE AT SOUTH32. Our response to climate change is strategic and globally aligned.

Input from GasNaturally to the Talanoa Dialogue

Input from GasNaturally to the Talanoa Dialogue

Environment and Climate Change

NAGA Strategic Plan

Executive Summary. Study Context

A Global Platform for Accelerating Coal Efficiency

Engineering, Economics and Regulation of the Electric Power Sector TERM PAPERS

The National Generators Forum (NGF) welcomes the opportunity to provide the following submission to the Garnaut Climate Change Review.

Australian Aluminium Council submission to Senate Select Committee on Climate Policy

Insurance against Catastrophic climate change: How much will climate change mitigation policies cost Australia?

Some highlights of the Victoria study include: A large untapped resource: The modelling results show strong growth in

Western Australia electricity price trends

U.S. Legislation to Address Climate Change: The Lieberman/McCain Climate Stewardship Act. Tim Profeta November 16, 2004

Michael Thorpe Managing Director Infrastructure and Utilities

OUR PURPOSE RESEARCH THAT MATTERS

Electricity Market Design Principles

Informal meeting of the Energy Ministers April 2018, Sofia. Discussion Session I speedy RESults for Europe s decarbonization

Enel Perspectives on Energy Transition Walking the path towards a decarbonised economy

Demand and Energy Forecasting Forum April 2017

Planning for California s 2030 Emissions Reduction Goal Partnership for Market Readiness Workshop San José, Costa Rica Mary Jane Coombs California

Building the Foundations for a Low Pollution, Clean Energy Economy

On the wrong track. Policy Brief. The case for abandoning the promised $7 billion subsidies to Australia s dirtiest coalfired power stations

POLICIES FOR BETTER BUILDINGS

The Australian Industry Group

AUSTRALIA. Submission under the Cancun Agreements February 2011

Universities as a living laboratory for community mitigation, adaptation and education: The University of Melbourne example

CHAIRMAN S SUMMARY. Renewable Energy: a Route to Decarbonisation in Peril?

OPERATING ENVIRONMENT

RISK MANAGING EUROPEAN POWER SECTOR DECARBONISATION: POLAND CASE STUDY

Easing into carbon trading Republic of Korea s Emissions Target Management Scheme

Collaborative EPRI Analysis of CO 2 Price Impacts on Western Power Markets:

The cost of renewable energy:

Renewable Energy Target Scheme Exposure Draft Legislation

Power Perspectives 2030

Transcription:

8 November 2016 Frank Jotzo Commonwealth of Australia, The Senate Environment and Communications References Committee Associate Professor The Australian National University Deputy Director, Crawford School of Public Policy Director, Centre for Climate Economics and Policy Canberra ACT 0200 Australia Submission to inquiry into the retirement of coal fired power stations I welcome the opportunity to share insights from our analysis on retirement of coal-fired power stations. This submission focuses on policy mechanisms to encourage the retirement of coal-fired power stations from the National Electricity Market, including measures to support structural adjustment in the affected regions, and the potential role of federal government. The submission draws on recent and ongoing research that I have led or been involved in, in particular earlier work on deep decarbonisation (with ClimateWorks Australia, as part of a global collaboration); a proposal for a mechanism for exit of brown coal fired power stations (with Mr Salim Mazouz); and a new research project on coal transitions (with Prof John Wiseman, and as part of an international consortium). A brief summary of this submission: 1. Replacing coal-fired power with carbon-free alternatives is essential to help decarbonize the economy. Australia s ageing coal fired power fleet can be replaced by a predominantly renewable power supply. 2. Policy mechanisms at the federal level are needed to facilitate a timely transition, to promote investor confidence, and to minimize economic and social disruption in the transition. A price on carbon emissions is the best primary policy instrument, eg in the form of emissions trading or as a baseline-and-credit scheme in the power sector. 3. To achieve orderly transition in the power sector, additional policies to facilitate exit of high emissions power stations may be needed. These may include a market mechanism for closure, regulated closure with flexibility, and industry compacts. Funding to support structural adjustment in affected regions can ease the transition. 4. Research is needed to fully understand the options available to Australia and to inform policy processes. Attachments: Submission text Jotzo, F. and Mazouz, S. (2015), Brown coal exit: a market mechanism for regulated closure of highly emissions intensive power stations. Economic Analysis and Policy 48: 71-81. Coal Transitions project summary Sincerely, Frank Jotzo CRAWFORD SCHOOL OF PUBLIC POLICY

Commonwealth of Australia The Senate Environment and Communications References Committee Submission to inquiry into the retirement of coal fired power stations Frank Jotzo, Crawford School of Public Policy, The Australian National University 8 November 2016 1. Opportunities for low-carbon transition in Australia s power sector Replacing coal-fired power with carbon-free alternatives is one of Australia s most important options to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, and it can be done predominantly through renewable power. Australia s electricity sector is dominated by coal fired power, on the whole using relatively old and inefficient plants. As a result, the emissions intensity of Australia s electricity supply is very high in international comparison. 1 This presents a significant opportunity to reduce Australia s carbon footprint. Australia s power station fleet is ageing and will need to be replaced over coming decades. The abundance of renewable energy resources in Australia readily allows the transition to a power system built on renewable energy, with electricity storage to manage variability and potentially some use of natural gas (possibly with carbon capture and storage). Deep decarbonisation pathways Achieving a low-emissions economy requires a low-carbon or zero-carbon electricity system. As shown in the Deep Decarbonisation Pathways Project, other pillars of decarbonisation are electrification of transport and energy use in buildings and industry, with greater energy efficiency, as well as emissions savings in industry and agriculture and carbon sequestration on the land (Denis, Jotzo et al 2014) 2. Various analyses have shown the viability of an electricity system based on renewables in Australia. Modelling prepared by the CSIRO for the Australian Deep Decarbonisation Pathways report 3 shows a scenario where electricity supply transitions to renewables during the 2020s and 2030s and is carbon-free by 2050, while electricity demand increases substantially to accommodate electrification and economic growth (Figure 1). The energy mix in coming decades under a low-emissions trajectory is subject to assumptions about technological development and the evolution of technology costs, however there is high confidence that some form of renewables would be the mainstay of a cost-effective low-carbon system in Australia. The overall average costs of power supply in this scenario increase over time relative to today s wholesale prices. However the increase is compensated for by greatly improved energy efficiency. Electricity costs as a share of national income decline over time even with rapid decarbonisation. 1 In 2014, Australia s electricity generators emitted on average 735 grams of carbon dioxide per kilowatt-hour of electricity, compared to 681 gco2/kwh in China, and between 400-500 gco2/kwh in 2 Denis, A., Jotzo, F., Ferraro, S., Jones, A., Kautto, N., Kelly, R., Skarbek, A. and Thwaites, J. (2014), Pathways to deep decarbonisation in 2050: how Australia can prosper in a low carbon world, ClimateWorks/ANU. 3 Graham, P. and Hatfield-Dodds, S. (2014), Electricity sector, in Pathways to deep decarbonisation in 2050: how Australia can prosper in a low carbon world Technical Report, ClimateWorks/ANU. 2

Coal phase-out In this scenario, black coal fired electricity is largely phased out by the early 2030s, while the more emissions intensive brown coal fired plants are all closed by 2020. The very rapid phase-out of coal (and in particular brown coal) fired plants is because the deep decarbonisation scenario is compatible with the Climate Change Authority s two-degree carbon budget for Australia. This requires emissions not only to be reduced by a certain percentage at a certain date (eg to meet emissions reductions targets at 2030) but to limit cumulative emissions over time. Therefore early emissions savings are as important as those occurring later on. Overall national emissions in the deep decarbonisation scenario are reduced to net zero by 2050, with the help of significant amounts of land-based carbon sequestration. Figure 1: Australia s electricity supply in the deep decarbonisation scenario Source: Graham and Hatfield-Dodds 2014. 3

2. Policy mechanisms to drive a low carbon transition Policy mechanisms at the federal level are needed to facilitate a timely transition, to promote investor confidence, and to minimize economic and social disruption in the transition. Australia s energy sector has been exposed to significant investment uncertainty due to pervasive policy uncertainty and climate policy reversals for over a decade. Such uncertainty has detrimental effects on the investment climate and potentially on the cost effectiveness of investment (Jotzo, Jordan and Fabian 2012) 4. For an effective and efficient low-carbon transition, stable and predictable policy settings are needed. Carbon pricing The consensus in the global economics literature and policy analysis is that a price on carbon emissions is the best primary policy instrument to achieve this, coupled with ancillary policy approaches such as standards and regulation, and state support for R&D. Carbon pricing can take different forms, eg a carbon tax, economy-wide emissions trading, or more sector-focussed approaches. A growing number of countries, now including China, are implementing broad-based emissions trading schemes. Baseline-and-credit In the recent Australian policy debate, a baseline-and-credit scheme (or emissions intensity scheme ) in the power sector has been mooted. 5 Such a scheme would create a price on carbon in the power supply sector. Government would set a baseline (benchmark) emissions intensity for the power sector which declines over time; generators operating above the benchmark would need to cover their excess emissions by purchasing credits from those generators that operate below the benchmark. The effectiveness of such a scheme depends on the stringency of the policy settings, in particular how quickly the baseline declines and whether emissions credits from other mechanisms can be used in the power sector. A stand-alone baseline-and-credit scheme could be effective in the power sector, provided government underpins the scheme with significant ambition. However it is less economically efficient than an economy-wide carbon price, for example as it may arise from comprehensive emissions trading. This is because emissions reductions would be achieved at different marginal cost in different sectors of the economy: relatively cheap emissions reductions opportunities go unused in one part of the economy, while relatively expensive options are implemented in another. These considerations for costeffectiveness should be considered in light of overall effectiveness. Specifically, a baseline-and-credit scheme for the power sector does not create the same price signal on the demand side as on the supply side, because carbon price pass-through to consumers is suppressed. This means losing incentives for energy efficiency, unless other complementary policy instruments are applied on the demand side. 4 Jotzo, F., Jordan, T. and Fabian, N. (2012), Policy Uncertainty about Australia s Carbon Price: Expert Survey Results and Implications for Investment, Australian Economic Review 45(4): 395 409. 5 Wood, T. and Blowers, D. (2016), Climate phoenix: A sustainable Australian climate policy, Grattan Institute; Climate Change Authority (2016), Towards A Climate Policy Toolkit. 4

3. Policy mechanisms to facilitate orderly exit of high emitting power stations To achieve orderly transition in the power sector, additional policies to facilitate exit of high emissions power stations may be needed. These may include a market mechanisms for closure, regulated closure with flexibility, and compacts with industry. There are two reasons why policies geared two support the exit of high emissions intensive power stations may be needed. Firstly, driving the transition through a price instrument alone may stretch the political bounds of a baseline-and-credits scheme, as high prices mean large transfers between different types of electricity generators. An economy-wide ETS meanwhile may operate at lower prices than would be required to effect early phase-out of coal fired power. Secondly, without additional policy mechanisms there is no provision for power station exit to occur in an orderly, predictable manner. Just as observed in the recent cases of the closure of the Northern power station in South Australia and the announced closure of the Hazelwood station in Victoria, closures of entire stations would likely occur suddenly, typically at the point when major refurbishment becomes necessary. Sudden exit without system-wide coordination can be suboptimal from a system-wide perspective as it may not provide sufficient time to deploy alternative generating capacity. It also foregoes options to structure closures in a manner that minimizes social adjustment costs, for example by way of pooled redundancies across several plants. Market mechanism for closure A market mechanism for closure of emissions intensive power stations was proposed by Jotzo and Mazouz at the end of 2015 (see attachment), to significant interest in Australian energy industry and policy circles. 6 Under such a mechanism, plants would bid competitively over the payment they require for closure, the regulator chooses the most cost effective bid, and payment for closure is made by the remaining power stations, for example in proportion to their carbon dioxide emissions. Government would need to regulate or legislate to implement the levy on the remaining generators. The remaining power providers would, on average, recoup the payments through higher capacity utilization and to an extent through higher wholesale prices. The mechanism could overcome adverse incentive effects for plants to stay in operation in anticipation of payment for closure and solve the political difficulties and problems of information asymmetry that plague direct government payments for closure and direct regulation for exit. A market mechanism with industry funding would also provide a direct source of funding for structural adjustment packages, and for high-level site rehabilitation. Figure 2: A market mechanism for coal fired power plant closure simplified representation 6 Jotzo, F. and Mazouz, S. (2015), Brown coal exit: a market mechanism for regulated closure of highly emissions intensive power stations. Economic Analysis and Policy 48: 71-81. 5

Regulated closure Orderly exit could also be achieved through regulated closure, for example by placing a cap on operational lifetimes of existing plants, as proposed by the Climate Institute 7 ; or by imposing a maximum allowable emissions intensity at generator level, with this level declining over time. Such a scheme would force the exit of individual generators according to a timetable determined by government or a regulating agency. The lack of flexibility however would increase costs relative to a market solution, as a hard age limit or emissions intensity limit may not result in the cost-effective sequence of closures. Regulated closures could potentially be combined with flexibility options such as trading of operation rights between generators. Regulated closure in itself would not provide a source of funding for structural adjustment. Industry compacts In some other countries, notably Germany, orderly phase-out of industries including coal mining and steel production was achieved through negotiated agreements between industry and governments. Such arrangements may or may not involve taxpayer funded industry assistance. They do require active involvement by governments to help coordinate businesses while avoiding collusive behaviour. Industry compacts can provide high levels of predictability as closures can be agreed according to a timetable. They allow significant extent of collaboration between businesses, for example through pooled redundancies and re-deployment of younger workers to plants that remain operational. These upsides need to be weighed against potential excess costs to the economy and the risk of creating excess rents to participants. Structural adjustment funding Funding to support structural adjustment in affected regions can ease the transition. Structural adjustment funds could be established from within the electricity industry, and used to support regional infrastructure, start-up businesses, retraining and worker mobility. A principle to adhere to in allocating structural adjustment funding is that this should be reserved for activities and investments that go beyond the existing obligations of the owners and operators of power stations, such as retrenchment payments and site rehabilitation. A levy on generators remaining on the grid to support structural adjustment around plants that leave the system would amount to only relatively minor imposts on the power industry as a whole, and on electricity consumers. In the example given in Jotzo/Mazouz, a fund of $400m to $1b might result in retail electricity price increases in the order of 1-2%, limited to one year. An industry-financed fund for structural adjustment resulting from coal fired power station exit could be created irrespective of the particular mechanism used to facilitate closure. Indeed it could be established irrespective of whether a closure mechanism is established. 7 The Climate Institute (2015), A switch in time: Enabling the electricity sector's transition to net zero emissions. 6

4. Coal Transitions research The extent research on options to facilitate closure of coal-fired power stations in Australia has been relatively limited, and concentrated on policy mechanisms at the macro scale. Additional research is needed to fully understand the options and provide input to policy. Areas for improved understanding include how policy mechanisms for power station closure would interact with other policy mechanisms, such as baseline-and-credit or the renewable energy target; how predictability of exit can be achieved without unduly compromising cost effectiveness, including the potential role for industry compacts; what options exist to provide effective support for structural adjustment, and how to raise funds for structural adjustment ideally without relying on public budgets. Analysis of experiences with industrial transitions in other countries, including past and present coal industry transitions, will help in assessing suitable options for Australia. Lessons can also be drawn from past industrial and resource transitions in Australia. My current research work includes the role of Chief Investigator for the Australian contribution to a new international project on Coal Transitions (see attachment). On issues of particular interest to the Committee, including transition of coal fired power in the Latrobe Valley, the research work is jointly led by Prof John Wiseman of the University of Melbourne and myself. This international research project, led by IDDRI and Climate Strategies and in partnership with research teams from China, India, South Africa, Poland and Germany aims to: promote deeper understanding amongst relevant national and international stakeholders of the implications of global climate mitigation activities for the future of coal production and consumption; support societally acceptable transition away from coal, to marry coal phase out with economic renewal and a just transition in key countries; promote knowledge and acceptance of new narratives on the future of coal, enabling conditions, and concrete steps for national coal phase out strategies; promote exchange, learning and more coordination on transition policies at the international level. We will be happy to appraise the members of the Committee and their colleagues on insights that will come from the research. 7